Seminar 3 - Solutions
Seminar 3 - Solutions
Seminar 3 - Solutions
()
) (
q1 ,q2
q1
q1 ,q2
q2
) = 100 3q 2q
1
) = 100 2q 4q
1
=0
=0
Thus:
100 4q1 = 0
q1 = 25
1
And:
( )
( )
25 2q2 = 0 = 50 4q2
q2 = 12.5
= 1875
(d) Suppose now that a new management assumed control of the firm and decide to
decompose the monopoly plant into two plants, where plant 1 sells in market 1 only and
plant 2 sells in market 2 only. Calculate the profit maximising level of output sold in each
plant;
Each plant operates as a separate entity such that:
( ) (
)
( q ) = (100 q ) q q
2
2
= 100q2 2q12
Thus:
q1 ,q2
q1
q1 ,q2
q2
) = 100 3q = 0
1
) = 100 4q
=0
q1 = 100 3
q2 = 25
(e) Calculate the sum of profits in the two plants;
( )
( )
1 q = 100q 1.5 q
( )
( )
2 q2 = 100q2 2 q2
( )
( )
100
100
= 100
1.5
= 1666.67
3
3
( ) ( )
= 100 25 2 25 = 1250
( )
( )
VH
VL
Demand
nH
nH + nL
Figure 1
Figure 1 illustrates an aggregate demand composed of the two groups of consumers, where
each group shares a common valuation for the product:
(b) Find the profit-maximising price set by Apple, considering all possible parameter values
of (n H , n L , V H , V L ). Assume that production is costless.
The monopoly has two options: (i) setting a high price, p = V H ; or (ii) setting a low price,
p = V L . Figure 1 reveals that the profit levels (i.e. revenue, since production is costless) are
given by:
p =V H
= n HV H
And:
p =V L
= (n H + n L )V H
Comparing the two profit levels yields the monopolys profit maximizing price. Hence:
H
V
m
p =
V L
If
nH + nL
VH >
H
n
Otherwise
L
V
Thus, the monopoly sets a high price if either there are relatively many (few) high (low)
valuation consumers (i.e. nH is large or nL is small) and / or high (low) valuation consumers
are willing to pay a relatively high (low) price (VH is high or VL is small).
3. A monopoly faces a demand function given by p = q and has a unit production cost
of c > 0. Suppose the government imposes a specific tax of $t per unit on each unit of
output sold to consumers:
(a) Show that this tax imposition would raise the price paid by consumers by less than t;
(b) How would your answer to (a) change if the market demand curve was given by p = q
(a) Show that this tax imposition would raise the price paid by consumers by less than t;
Total revenue is given by:
TR = pq = q q
TR = q q 2
Marginal revenue is thus:
MR
TR
= 2 q
q
MR = 2 q = c + t
ct
qt =
2
Thus:
pt = qt
ct
pt =
2
pt =
+c+t
2
such that:
p t 1
= <1
t 2
5
Hence, as illustrated in Figure 2, an increase in t raises the monopoly price by less than t:
pt
p
c+t
MCt
MC
MR
0
q1
q0
AR
Figure 2
(b) How would your answer to (a) change if the market demand curve was given by p = q ?
This is the case of a constant-elasticity demand curve. To be sure:
dp
q
= q 1 =
dq
q
dp q
q
= q 1 =
dq p
q
dq p
1
=
dp q
p
q
p q
=
q p
Recall:
()
TR = p q q
MR
dTR dp
=
q+ p
dq
dq
dp q
1
1
MR = p 1+
= p 1+ = p 1 1
dq p
E
MR = p 1
MR = p 1 = c + t = MC
p=
c+t
1
Thus:
p
1
=
t 1
Thus, price will increase by more (resp. less) than the increase in the tax if < 1 (resp.
> 1 ).
pt
p
c+t
c
MCt
MC
AR
MR
q1 q0
Figure 3
4. A monopoly faces demand from two individuals for its output. The demand function of
individual 1 is given by q1d = 24 p1 and the demand function of individual 2 is given by
q2d = 24 2 p2 . Assume that the monopoly has a unit production cost of c = 6. Investigate
the potential benefit to the monopolist of setting a two-part tariff [Hint: See Oi (1971)].
A linear two-part tariff is a scheme under which demanders pay a fixed fee for the right to
consume the good and a uniform price for each unit consumed. The prototype case, first
studied by Oi (1971) is an amusement park (Disneyland?) that sets a basic entry fee coupled
with a stated marginal price for each amusement used.1 Mathematically, such a scheme can
be represented by a tariff under which a demander must pay T ( q ) to purchase q units of the
good where:
T ( q ) = a + pq
Interestingly, Disneyland once used a two-part tariff but abandoned it because the costs of administering the
payment scheme for individuals rises became too high. Like other amusement arks, Disney moved to a singleadmissions price policy (which still provided them with ample opportunities for price discrimination, especially
with the multiple parks at Disney World).
Thus, a is the fixed fee and p is the marginal price to be paid. The monopolists goal is to
chose a and p to maximise profits, given the demand for this product. Note that the average
price paid by any demander is given by:
p=
T (q) a
= +p
q
q
Thus, the tariff is inversely related to q and is thus only feasible when those who pay low
prices (i.e. those for whom q is large) are unable to resell the good to those who must pay
high average prices (i.e. those for who q is small).
One approach for establishing the parameters of the linear tariff would be for the firm
to set the marginal price, p, equal to MC and then to set the fixed fee, a, so as to extract the
maximum consumer surplus from a given set of buyers [Oi (1971)]. One might imagine
buyers being arrayed according to their willingness to pay. The choice of p = MC would then
maximise consumer surplus for this group, and a could be set equal to the surplus enjoyed by
the least eager buyer. This buyer would then be indifferent about buying the good, but all the
other (i.e. more eager) buyers would experience net gains from the purchase.
This feasible tariff might not, however, be the most profitable. Consider the effects on
profits of a small increase in p above MC. This would result in no net change in the profits
earned from the least willing buyer. Quantity demanded would drop slightly at the margin
where p = MC, and some of what had previously been consumer surplus (and therefore part
of the fixed fee, a) would be converted into variable profits because now p > MC. For all
other demanders, profits would be increased by the price rise. Although each will pay a bit
less in fixed charges, profits per unit purchased will rise to a greater extent.2 IN some cases it
is possible to make an explicit calculation of the optimal two-part tariff but, in general,
optimal schedules will depend on a variety of contingencies.
In terms of the example, an Oi Tariff requires the monopolist to set p1 = p2 = 6 = MC
such that q1 = 18 and q2 = 12 . With this marginal price, demander 2 (i.e. the less eager of the
two) obtains consumer surplus of CS2 = 0.5 (12 6 ) = 36 , which is the maximal entry fee
that might be charged without causing demander 2 to leave the market - see Figure 4.
Consequently, the two-part tariff in this case would be:
T ( qi ) = 36 + 6qi
If the monopolist opted for this pricing scheme, then its profits would be:
= TR TC = T ( q1 ) + T ( q2 ) AC ( q1 + q2 )
= 72
This follows because qi ( MC ) > q1 ( MC ) where qi ( MC ) is the quantity demanded when p = MC for all
except the least willing purchaser (i.e. purchaser 1). Hence, the gain in profits from an increase in p above MC
[i.e. pqi ( MC ) ] exceeds the loss in profits from a smaller fixed fee [i.e. pq1 ( MC ) ].
2
p1
p2
q1 = 24 - p1
q2 = 24 - 2p2
24
12
CS1= 162
CS2 = 36
18
24
q1 0
MC
12
24
q2
Figure 4
Note that this is a lower profit than the monopolist could obtain from third-degree price
discrimination. In that case, p1 = 15, q1 = 9, p2 = 9, q2 = 6, = 99 . Moreover, it is less,
than the profit it could obtain setting a single price. In that case, the monopolist would cease
serving market 2 since it can maximise profits by setting p = 15 such that
q1 = 9, q2 = 0, = 81 - see Figure 5:
10
p1
p2
q1= 24 - p1
q2 = 24 - 2p2
24
15
12
9
MC
MR1
9 12
AR1
24
MR2
q1 0
12
AR2
24
q2
The optimal two-part tariff in this situation can be computed by noting that that total profits
with such a tariff are:
= 2a + ( p MC ) ( q1 + q2 )
where the entry fee, a, must equal the consumer surplus of the least eager demander (i.e.
demander 2). Thus:
= 2a + ( p MC ) ( q1 + q2 )
= 2 0.5 (12 p ) q2 + ( p 6 ) ( q1 + q2 )
= 2 0.5 (12 p ) ( 24 2 p ) + ( p 6 ) ( 24 p ) + ( 24 2 p )
= (12 p ) ( 24 2 p ) + ( p 6 ) ( 48 3p )
= 288 24 p 24 p + 2 p 2 + 48 p 3p 2 288 + 18 p
= 18 p p 2
11
Thus:
d
= 18 2 p = 0
dp
p = 9
p = 9
)( 24 2 p ) = 0.5 (12 9 )( 24 18 ) = 9 .
and
The optimal
T ( q ) = 9 + 9q
With this tariff, q1 = 15, q2 = 6 and = 2a + ( p MC ) ( q1 + q2 ) = 2 ( 9 ) + ( 9 6 ) (15 + 6 ) = 81 .
p1
p2
q1= 24 - p1
q2 = 24 - 2p2
24
12
9
MC
MR1
12 15
AR1
24
MR2
q1 0
12
AR2
24
q2
The monopolist might opt for this pricing scheme if it were under political pressure to have a
uniform pricing policy that did not price demander 2 out of the market. The two-part tariff
permits a degree of differential pricing [i.e. p1 = ( 9 15 ) + 9 = 9.60 , p2 = ( 9 6 ) + 9 = 10.5 ] but
appears fair because all buyers face the same schedule.
12
Reference
Oi, W. Y. (1971). A Disneyland Dilemma: Two-Part Tariffs for a Mickey Mouse Monopoly. The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 85(1), pp. 77-96.
13