06 Crime As Pollution
06 Crime As Pollution
06 Crime As Pollution
Introduction1
Noise pollution and industrial pollution are well-known phenomena. The
more technical term for such pollution is ‘externalities’. In both instances,
the producer of the pollution creates a social cost that is borne by
others. Unwilling recipients, such as residents on a noisy airport flight-
path or downstream recipients of water pollution, bear the cost. For some
types of pollution, such as greenhouse gases dispersed in the atmosphere,
society as a whole bears the cost of the emissions.
That crime can also be examined as a form of pollution is the subject of
this chapter. It is proposed that various agents, whether manufacturers
of frequently stolen products, or owners and managers of premises that
are crime prone because of poor design or policies, can produce costly
criminal opportunities for which other parts of society bear the cost. In
furthering the study of ‘crime as pollution’ (Roman and Farrell 2002), this
chapter discusses the nature and definition of externalities, and seeks a
preliminary mapping of how the notion of pollution applies to different
types of crime. Crime reduction that utilized rewards and market-based
incentives as proposed herein would be adopting a radically different
philosophy to ‘traditional’ punitive approaches to crime control and crim-
inal justice. The chapter also undertakes a preliminary examination of
control instruments that have been developed in environmental economics.
A range of instruments have been proposed for climate control, and these
are examined for possible lessons for crime reduction.
With regard to the implementation of crime-reduction efforts based
around an understanding of crime as pollution, the possibility of an
Enhanced Crime Doctrine is considered. It is adapted from the existing
Enhanced Injury Doctrine applied to the motor vehicle industry whereby,
since it is highly predictable that many traffic crashes will occur, vehicle
manufacturers are accountable for safety standards to reduce any addi-
tional (enhanced) injury. Since aggregate levels of crime can be predicted
with reasonable accuracy for many crime types, it is argued that it should
legally behove crime polluters to recognize this and adopt anti-crime
136 Graham Farrell and John Roman
cost is shared around the world, as the gases diffuse in the Earth’s atmo-
sphere. In an effort to address this, the Kyoto Protocol to the United
Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change is currently a contro-
versial effort to introduce international regulation (see, for example,
Barrett and Stavins 2002). Since February 2005, the Kyoto Protocol has
legally obliged industrialized nations to reduce worldwide emissions of
greenhouse gases to 5 per cent below their 1990 levels by 2012.
Such agencies include the Environment Agency in the United Kingdom and
the Environmental Protection Agency in the United States.3 Efforts to restrict
potentially damaging products are widespread. Toys with parts on which
children could choke are banned. Imports from a source country without
the same level of regulation are closely checked and, if necessary, rejected.
A Consumer Product Safety Commission exists to oversee the development
and enforcement of control instruments to tackle these externalities.
Crime as pollution
Many of the categories of pollution discussed so far are defined as crimes
in certain circumstances. It might, therefore, be concluded that the rela-
tionship between crime and externalities has been fully charted and its
implications realized. However, this would be a wrong conclusion. Most of
the activities discussed above (air and noise pollution, fire safety and
consumer product safety) were only legally proscribed after they were
recognized as externalities. In contrast, the focus here relates to behaviours
that are already legally proscribed as crime but where the role of externali-
ties goes largely unrecognized. There is a fundamental difference between
the notion of ‘crime as pollution’ and that of ‘pollution as crime’.
The simplest examples of crime pollution are probably those with close
parallels in the consumer safety examples discussed above. Products that
are poorly made in such a way as to effectively encourage crime are the
easiest to fathom. Cars with door locks that can be opened by a bent coat
hanger (an accusation often levelled at the 1970s Ford Cortina) could be
said to encourage crime. A more recent example is afforded by mobile
phones. The rapid growth of mobile phones in the 1990s led to a mini-
crime wave of robbery and theft resulting in ‘CRIME U.K.’ according to
the Daily Mirror newspaper and ‘Panic on the Streets’ (BBC 2002). The
phones were highly portable, highly valuable and easily stolen items that
made, to use the terminology of Routine Activity Theory, particularly suit-
able targets. Robbery and theft increased not because the youth population
suddenly became more deprived, less well off or less educated, but because
a very good criminal opportunity presented itself. However, it is possible
that this criminal opportunity did instigate many new criminal careers.
Violent crime and disorder can be viewed as pollution in many instances.
Assaults, robberies and disorder in and around bars and nightclubs are
arguably externalities caused by profit-seeking alcohol manufacturers,
retailers (and even, perhaps, local governments who receive taxation).
Perhaps a case could even be made that alcohol manufacturers hold some
liability for domestic violence. Alcohol is certainly commonly understood
to be present in many instances. Of course, alcohol is frequently used as an
142 Graham Farrell and John Roman
excuse for domestic violence but most commentators would deny that it can
justifiably be cited as a cause. However, if the alcohol industry as a whole
were taxed and the resources poured into services for victims/survivors of
domestic violence, it is likely that many commentators would view this as
an advance on the current situation, and would not require any reduction
in the culpability of a violent offender. This is only raised here as a possi-
bility that warrants further discussion. The intention here is to raise the
possibility that, since alcohol is a commonly cited factor in domestic
violence (if not an excuse), then the industry which is the primary benefi-
ciary might, in some fashion, be made to return some of its profits to the
victims who incur a major cost which few would hold to be unrelated.
Child pornography, and hence perhaps child sexual abuse, are arguably
facilitated by the Internet. The Internet and e-mail facilitate the adver-
tising, exchange and purchase of illegal pornography (and other illegal
products and services) of various types. It has also been suggested that the
Internet facilitates the illegal sex trade as well as the illegal drugs trade and
other forms of crime and organized crime. Perhaps Internet Service
Providers (ISPs), who benefit financially from subscriptions, could be
considered as crime polluters. If their service promotes illegal activities, a
case could be made that they should be held responsible. At the very least,
it could be argued that ISPs should be more formally encouraged to
rapidly develop monitoring and tracing technologies that deter and detect.
While there may be some public pressure on major ISPs to do so (so that
many have password protection to reduce the possibility of minors
accessing certain types of site), it is likely that legislation that recognizes e-
crimes as pollution caused by the Internet and by ISPs (as those who profit),
will accelerate this process. Perhaps the process could be incentivized so
that ‘safe’ ISPs benefit from their improved software and practices.
A tentative and preliminary list of crime types, possible polluters, and
possible solutions is presented in Table 8.1. It is extremely preliminary, and
at this stage represents more of an attempt to brainstorm the issue than to
develop a comprehensive list. It is certainly not intended to be exhaustive
but, rather, to set the ball rolling. It is also recognized that some of the
elements it contains may, upon closer examination, prove to be erroneous
or to require significant revision. This is normal in the development of a
concept that is likely to require many iterations of revision.
How is crime pollution recognized? The first step in examining a crime
type appears to be the identification of possible polluters. Often, but not
necessarily always, there is a link via the question of ‘Who benefits?’
directly or indirectly from this type of crime. The identification of possible
control mechanisms is a next step. Whether or not control mechanisms can
incorporate market incentives, which should be more efficient than tradi-
tional command-and-control techniques, is a different question. Some
combination of approaches seems the most likely possibility – that is, stick
and carrot in combination to produce maximum effect.
Crime as pollution 143
Robbery/ Wounding
mugging (serious and slight)
Security expenditure 0 2
Insurance administration 40 -
Property stolen or damaged 310 -
Emotional and physical impact on victims 2,400 12,000
Lost output 420 2,000
Victim Services 6 6
Health services 190 1,200
Criminal Justice System (incl. police) 1,400 2,700
Total average cost 4,700 18,000
Total UK cost 2,000,000,000 15,600,000,000
This doctrine suggests that, even though some crashes may be caused by
(‘with or without the fault of’) the victims, the manufacturers know that
crashes will occur and are obliged to minimize damage. The same principle
should arguably apply to consumer goods, since manufacturers know that
some of them will be stolen. Therefore, regardless of whether theft occurs
‘with or without the fault of the victim’, manufacturers should have a
responsibility to design products in ways that minimize risk and the resul-
tant cost of crime. An Enhanced Crime Doctrine would be the appropriate
148 Graham Farrell and John Roman
Yet crime pollution is more widespread than solely via consumer products.
It would also apply to bars and clubs with high rates of assaults, disorder
and other crimes. Such crimes are similarly predictable, and so the appro-
priate enhanced crime doctrine would be along the lines of:
Barrett and Stavins synthesize the information from the various proposals
for climate control. They identify four key factors which are presented here
as they contain lessons for any possible crime reduction enterprise along
these lines. It is concluded that the most successful instruments will have:
While this is a gross simplification of the Barrett and Stavins work, the
intent here is to unashamedly steal lessons that may inform the development
of crime reduction.4 Moderate short-term goals are necessary because
Crime as pollution 151
everything cannot change at once. There will be little support for immediate
extensive change. This is also why the second factor, that is, provision for
later expansion, is also critical. Assuming that crime-pollution-reduction
instruments are considered, their development would need to be cautious
at first. The low-hanging fruit of crime types and legislation that will
encounter little political opposition would be approached at first (that is,
crime reduction probably shouldn’t start with the gun control lobby in the
USA). Crime types where existing measures are akin to anti-pollution
measures should be identified and developed. Many of these exist already;
efforts to promote safe building designs for residences and businesses, as
well as secure car parks, have become increasingly widespread. The UK’s
Secured Car Parks Scheme has, after a decade, grown into the Safer
Parking Scheme, continuing as an initiative of the Association of Chief
Police Officers (British Parking Association 2005). Secured By Design
(ACPO Crime Prevention Initiatives Limited, 2005) already seeks to apply
security standards and the principles of designing-out-crime to residential
and business premises and areas as well as schools, railway stations,
caravan parks, children’s play areas, and sheltered accommodation. Such
efforts have shown to be effective in at least one evaluation of anti-residential
burglary initiatives (Armitage 2000). Extending such efforts to incorporate
a more extensive pollution approach, perhaps initially with market incen-
tives at the fore (more carrot than stick, at least at first) would seem
appropriate. This fits well with Barrett and Stavins’s third factor cited
above; that is, the incorporation of market mechanisms where possible as
well as incentives to encourage participation and compliance.
It is also possible that other aspects of knowledge relating to crime anal-
ysis might be fruitfully integrated into the approaches used in climate
control. It is known that crime clusters along various dimensions. Crime is
disproportionately committed by prolific repeat offenders, disproportion-
ately experienced by repeatedly victimized targets (whether persons, places
or other targets), and crime is concentrated geographically into hotspots.
Accommodating such knowledge into instruments in ways that focus them
upon these crime clusters is a possibility that should be considered if it
does not occur as a natural part of the process.
Conclusion
This chapter has continued work begun in Roman and Farrell (2002).
That study noted how crime is an instance where market failure is
common. Many agents in society (such as manufacturers and businesses)
have little or no economic incentive to act in ways that reduce crime risks
for others. They may, rather, save production costs or business costs in
ways that, whether inadvertently or not, serve to effectively increase the
risk of crime to others. Hence the normal market mechanism, which often
serves to protect consumers, frequently fails when it comes to crime. The
result is that crime costs to society are immensely greater than if the crim-
inal opportunities had been stemmed at source.
Crime reduction seeking to tackle externalities must do so in ways that
do not otherwise hinder the market. Crime reduction should not, for
example, increase the costs of businesses in ways that make them less prof-
itable. It is useful to reiterate the statement from Roman and Farrell about
the need for caution in developing crime reduction measures based on this
approach:
crime – that is, those agents who generate criminal opportunities or facili-
tate crime in various ways that often go unrecognized. The further
exploration of the nature of crime-types as forms of pollution, the drafting
of appropriate legislation and the introduction of experimental trials of
various market incentives, may be the appropriate next steps.
Bibliography
ACPO (Association of Chief Police Officers of England and Wales) Crime Preven-
tion Initiatives Limited. 2005. ‘Secured By Design’ at http://www.
securedbydesign.com/ (accessed March 2005).
Aldy, Joseph E., Orszag, Peter R. and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2001), ‘Climate Change:
An Agenda for Global Collective Action’, Prepared for the conference on The
Timing of Climate Change Policies, Pew Center on Global Climate Change,
Washington, DC.
Armitage, R. (2000) ‘An Evaluation of Secured By Design Housing within West
Yorkshire’, Policing and Reducing Crime Unit Briefing Note 7/00, London:
Home Office.
BBC News (2002) ‘Panic on the Streets’ BBC News online, 21 February 2002,
http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/uk/1833953.stm
Barrett, S. (2001a) ‘International Cooperation for Sale’, European Economic
Review 45(10), 1835–50.
Barrett, S. (2001b) ‘Towards a Better Climate Treaty’, Policy Matters, 01–29,
November, Washington, DC: AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies.
Barrett, S. (2003) Environment and Statecraft: The Strategy of Environmental
Treaty-Making, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Barrett, S. and Stavins, R. (2002) ‘Increasing participation and compliance in inter-
national climate change agreements’ International Environmental Agreements:
Politics, Law and Economics 3(2003): 349–76.
Benedick, R.E. (2001) ‘Striking a New Deal on Climate Change’, Issues in Science
and Technology 18(1), 71–6.
Bradford, D.F. (2001) ‘Succeeding Kyoto: A No-Cap but Trade Approach to GHG
Control. Version 02a’, Princeton University and NYU School of Law, September 5.
Brand, S. and Price, R. (2000) The Economic and Social Costs of Crime, Home
Office Research Study 217, London: Home Office (http://www.homeoffice.
gov.uk/rds/pdfs/hors217.pdf)
British Parking Association (2005) ‘What is the Safer Parking Scheme (SPS)?’ and
‘Is the SPS the same as the Secured Car Parks Scheme?’ (http://www.british-
parking.co.uk/pages/secure/secure1.htm) (accessed March 2005).
Cohen, M.A. (2000) ‘Measuring the Costs and Benefits of Crime and Justice’,
Measurement and Analysis of Crime and Justice, Vol. 4 of Criminal Justice
2000, Washington DC: National Institute of Justice.
Cohen, M.A., Rust, R.T., Steen, S. and Tidd, S.T. (2004) ‘Willingness-to-pay for
crime control programs’, Criminology 42(1), 89–109.
Cooper, R. (1998) ‘Toward a Real Treaty on Global Warming’, Foreign Affairs
77(2), 66–79.
Cooper, R. (2001) ‘The Kyoto Protocol: A Flawed Concept’, Environmental Law
Reporter, 31 (December), 11, 484–92.
154 Graham Farrell and John Roman
Cullen, Francis T., Maakestad, William J. and Cavender, Gray (1987) Corporate
Crime Under Attack: The Ford Pinto Case and Beyond. Cincinnati: Anderson
Publishing.
Ekblom, P (2005) ‘The “Polluter-Pays” Principle and Crime Reduction’, unpub-
lished manuscript, Home Office Central Intelligence Hub, London: Home Office.
Felson, M., Belanger, M.E., Bichler, C.D., Bruzinski, C.D., Campbell, G.S., Friecol,
C.L., Grofik, K.C., Mazur, I.S., Regan, A.B., Sweeney, P.J., Ullman, A.L. and
Williams, L.Q. (1996) ‘Redesigning Hell: Preventing Crime and Disorder at the
Port Authority Bus Terminal’, in R.V. Clarke (ed.), ‘Preventing Mass Transit
Crime’, Crime Prevention Studies, 6, 5–92.
Greenbaum, J. (2005) ‘McDonald’s Hot Coffee Lawsuit and Beyond: The Tort
Reform Myth Machine’ Common Dreams News Centre, 22 January 2005
(http://www.commondreams.org/views05/0122–11.htm)
Hahn, R.W. (1998) The Economics and Politics of Climate Change, Washington,
DC: American Enterprise Institute Press.
McKibbin, W.J and Wilcoxen, P.J. (1997) ‘A Better Way to Slow Global Climate
Change’, Brookings Policy Brief, No. 17, Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
McKibbin, W.J and Wilcoxen, P.J. (2000) ‘Moving Beyond Kyoto’, Brookings
Policy Brief, No. 66. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Nordhaus, W.D. (1998) ‘Is the Kyoto Protocol a Dead Duck? Are There Any Live
Ducks Around? Comparison of Alternative Global Tradeable Emissions
Regimes’, Working Paper, Department of Economics, Yale University, New
Haven, CT, July 31.
Portney, P. and Stavins, R. (2000) Public Policies for Environmental Protection,
Washington DC: Resources For the Future Press.
Roman, J. and Farrell, G. (2002)’Cost–benefit analysis for crime prevention:
Opportunity costs, routine savings, and crime externalities’, in N. Tilley (ed.)
‘Evaluation for Crime Prevention’, Crime Prevention Studies, 14, 53–92.
Schelling, T.C. (1997) ‘The Cost of Combating Global Warming: Facing the Trade-
offs’, Foreign Affairs 76(6), 8–14.
Schelling, T.C. (1998) Costs and Benefits of Greenhouse Gas Reduction. Wash-
ington, DC: AEI Press.
Schelling, T.C. (2002) ‘What Makes Greenhouse Sense? Time to Rethink the Kyoto
Protocol’, Foreign Affairs 81(3), 2–9.
Schmalensee, R. (1998) ‘Greenhouse Policy Architecture and Institutions’, in
William D. Nordhaus (ed.) Economics and Policy Issues in Climate Change (pp.
137–58), Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.
Stephens, John L. and Stephens (2000) ‘Can Trial Lawyers Really Help Make Cars
Safer?’ FindLaw at http://library.lp.findlaw.com/articles/file/00586/004776/
title/Subject/topic/Torts/%20Personal%20Injury_Motor%20Vehicle%20Accidents
/filename/tortspersonalinjury_2_6256
Stewart, R.B. and Wiener, J.B. (2001) ‘Reconstructing Climate Policy: The Paths
Ahead’, Policy Matters, 01–23.,Washington, DC: AEI-Brookings Joint Center
for Regulatory Studies. August.
Whelan, Paul W. (1999) ‘Enhanced Injuries and the Restatement of Tort Thirds’
FindLaw at http://library.lp.findlaw.com/articles/file/00665/006761/title/Subject/
topic/Transportation_Motor%20Vehicles/filename/transportation_2_6384
Victor, D.G. (2001) ‘International Agreements and the Struggle to Tame Carbon’,
July 4. (cited in Barrett and Stavins 2003).
Crime as pollution 155
Notes
1 Acknowledgements: Earlier versions of this work were presented to the
American Society of Criminology in Denver, November 2003, and to the
Midlands branch of the British Society of Criminology, at the Galleries of
Justice, in Nottingham on 31 March 2004. We thank Kate Moss for the latter
of those two opportunities.
2 Even this case is more complex than many people believe from the poorly
informed anecdotes – see Greenbaum (2005).
3 The UK’s Environment Agency is at http://www.environment-agency.gov.uk.
The US EPA is at http://www.epa.gov
4 We apologise to Barrett and Stavins for the brevity of coverage of their exten-
sive review, as well as for any possible misrepresentation incurred in its transfer
to this context. It is our worry that the brevity of this section does not
adequately convey the respect that their work warrants.