Asphalt Eia Neshap Final 02-2003 PDF
Asphalt Eia Neshap Final 02-2003 PDF
Asphalt Eia Neshap Final 02-2003 PDF
Final Report
EPA-452/R-03-005
February 2003
Prepared for:
Linda Chappell
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards
Innovative Strategies and Economics Group
Research Triangle Park, NC 27711
Prepared by:
Katherine B. Heller
Ju-Chen Yang
Brooks M. Depro
Research Triangle Institute
Health, Social, and Economics Research
Research Triangle Park, NC 27709
Section Page
1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1-1
iv
4.2.2 Producer Characterization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-2
4.2.3 Consumer Characterization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-3
4.2.4 Baseline and With-Regulation Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-4
4.3 Baseline Data Set . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-4
4.4 Supply and Demand Elasticities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-6
4.5 Economic Impact Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-10
4.5.1 National Market- Level Impacts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-10
4.5.2 National Industry-Level Impacts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-11
4.6 Impact on Refineries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-16
4.7 New Source Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-17
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . R-1
v
LIST OF FIGURES
Number Page
vi
LIST OF TABLES
Number Page
4-1 Types and Sources of Asphalt Roofing and Processing Facility Data . . . . . . . . 4-7
4-2 Market-Level Impacts: 1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-12
4-3 Industry-Level Impacts: 1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-13
4-4 Distributional Impacts Across Facilities: 1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-14
4-5 Distribution of Social Costs: 1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-15
4-6 Companies Owning Affected Asphalt Facilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-16
4-7 Cost-to-Sales Ratios for Small and Large Companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4-17
vii
5-2 Summary Statistics for SBREFA Screening Analysis: 1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5-4
5-3 Summary of Small Business Impacts: 1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5-5
viii
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
The Environmental Protection Agency’s (EPA’s) Office of Air Quality Planning and
Standards (OAQPS) is developing a National Emission Standard for Hazardous Air
Pollutants (NESHAP) under Section 112 of the Clean Air Act (CAA) Amendments of 1990
to limit air emissions from the production and processing of asphalt roofing products. This
document analyzes the economic impacts of the final rule on the asphalt industry and its
customers.
EPA has identified 123 facilities owned by 34 companies that may be subject to the
standards because they produce asphalt roofing products. In addition, nine refineries owned
by seven companies may be subject to the rule because they produce and sell blown asphalt.
The identified facilities produce one or more of five asphalt roofing products:
Based on its analysis of baseline facility operations, EPA estimates that only nine
asphalt roofing facilities will incur incremental costs associated with installing and operating
emissions control equipment. These nine roofing manufacturers, together with one
additional roofing manufacturer and all nine refineries, will also incur costs to perform
monitoring, recordkeeping, and reporting activities associated with the rule.
Because only a small subset of the industry is projected to incur costs due to the
regulation, overall costs of the rule are estimated to be small. As shown in Table ES-1, total
capital costs are $2.7 million, and total annual emissions control costs are less than $1.5
ES-1
million. The median value for capital costs incurred is approximately $47,000, and the
median total annual emission control costs incurred is approximately $14,000. Monitoring,
recordkeeping, and reporting requirements are estimated to average $16,800 per year per
affected facility.
Notes: Total Annualized Emission Control Costs = Annualized Capital Costs + O&M Costs
Average Annual MRR Cost = (Year 1 Total Annual Cost + Year 2 Total Annual Cost + Year
3 Total Annual Cost)/3
Total Annual Cost = Total Annualized Emission Control Costs + Monitoring, Recordkeeping,
and Reporting Costs
Totals may not add due to rounding.
Source: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2002 National Costs and Environmental
Impacts for the Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing NESHAP.”
The EPA conducted a market analysis to detemine the potential impacts of the
regulation for the asphalt roofing industry and consumers and producers in this market.
Because projected costs are relatively low, and because only a small subset of the market is
directly affected, price and quantity impacts of the final rule are very small. Prices are
projected to change by only a few cents, representing hundredths of a percent of baseline
prices that range from $161 per ton to $895 per ton. Similarly, market quantities are
ES-2
projected to decline by less than 0.01 percent. (See Section 4.6 for a detailed discussion of
the Agency’s EIA results.)
Although market impacts are very small, EPA recognized that impacts on individual
facilities or companies might be significant. To assess this, EPA examined changes in
profitability of facility asphalt operations and of companies owning asphalt roofing facilities
or blown asphalt-producing refineries. EPA’s analysis shows that impacts, even on facilities
incurring compliance costs, are relatively small. Industrywide, output is only projected to
fall by approximately 258 tons per year of asphalt roofing products. Industrywide profits are
projected to fall by roughly $233,000. Facilities incurring compliance costs may experience
a decline in profit of approximately $570,000. Industrywide, the gains in profitability at
facilities that do not incur compliance costs partially offset this loss. No facilities are
projected to close.
EPA has identified seven companies owning nine refineries that may be affected by
the rule. Due to the magnitude of impacts anticipated (these firms are anticipated to incur
monitoring, reporting, and recordkeeping costs only), the EPA did not conduct a market
analysis for affected refineries. Instead, the EPA assumed that affected firms must bear the
full cost of the regulation and will not be able to pass along costs to consumers (method
referred to as full cost absorption). In reality, this assumption will result in the maximum
estimate of impacts to refineries as these firms may be able to pass a portion of these costs
along to consumers. The approach used to analyze impacts to refineries is a comparison of
the estimated annual costs of the regulation to annual sale revenues of affected firms
(referred to as cost-to-sales ratios). Costs for these firms range from 0.0004 to 0.119 percent
of annual sales. Thus, EPA expects impacts on refineries to be generally very small.
ES-3
costs are projected to increase by $49,000. Profits at small businesses are projected to
increase by $45,000 or 0.03 percent. No facilities owned by small businesses are projected
to close, and no changes in employment are projected at facilities owned by small
businesses.
Overall, EPA projects that the costs and economic impacts of the Asphalt Roofing
and Processing NESHAP will be relatively small. Only approximately 19 refineries and
roofing manufacturers are estimated to incur compliance costs. The relatively small
reductions in output and profit will be concentrated at those 19 facilities, while many other
asphalt roofing manufacturers are projected to experience small increases in output and
profits. No facilities are projected to close and essentially no net change in industry
employment is projected. New sources are required to comply with the standards at start-up;
average total annualized emission control costs for a new facility are projected to be
approximately $419,000. EPA’s analysis projects that these costs will not be sufficient to
delay the opening of new asphalt plants.
ES-4
SECTION 1
INTRODUCTION
The Environmental Protection Agency’s (EPA’s) Office of Air Quality Planning and
Standards (OAQPS) is developing a National Emission Standard for Hazardous Air
Pollutants (NESHAP) under Section 112 of the Clean Air Act (CAA) Amendments of 1990
to limit air emissions from the production and processing of asphalt roofing products. This
document analyzes the economic impacts of the final NESHAP on the asphalt industry and
its customers.
Asphalt roofing products fall under North American Industry Classification System
(NAICS) Code 324122, Asphalt Shingle and Coating Materials Manufacturing, as well as the
U.S. Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) 2952, Asphalt Felts and Coatings. According to
the 1997 Economic Census of Manufacturing, 248 establishments owned by 149 companies
manufactured products categorized in NAICS 324122 (U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of the Census, 1999) in 1997. During this year, these firms employed
13,316 workers and shipped products valued at $4.9 billion (U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of the Census, 1997). EPA has identified 123 facilities owned by 34 companies that
may be subject to the final standards because they produce asphalt roofing products. In
addition, nine refineries owned by seven companies may be subject to the rule because they
produce and sell blown asphalt. The identified facilities produce one or more of five asphalt
roofing products:
1-1
model that produces consistent estimates of impacts on facilities, companies, markets, and
economic welfare.
Section 2 provides a profile of the industry. Section 3 describes the regulation and its
costs. Section 4 presents the economic impact analysis methodology and results. Section 5
focuses on small business impacts. Appendix A describes the economic impact analysis
model in greater detail, and Appendix B discusses how social costs are measured.
1-2
SECTION 2
INDUSTRY PROFILE
This section provides information to support the EIA of a final NESHAP on asphalt
roofing and processes. Asphalt roofing products fall under NAICS 324122 Asphalt Shingle
and Coating Materials Manufacturing. According to the 1997 Economic Census of
Manufacturing, 248 establishments owned by 149 companies produced products that are
categorized in NAICS 324122 (U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1999)
in 1997. In this same year, these firms employed 13,316 workers and shipped products
valued at $4.9 billion (U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1997).
Asphalts are desired in roofing products primarily for their waterproofing properties.
They are used as saturants and coatings for shingle and roll goods, as mopping asphalts in
membrane roofing, and as roof coatings. The various products classified under the Asphalt
Shingle and Coating Materials Manufacturing Industry (NAICS 324122) are listed in
Table 2-1. Asphalt roof coatings and mopping asphalts, which are melted and used in
applying built-up roofing, will not be covered by this NESHAP rule; therefore, they are not
included in this section except where economic data include these products and more
disaggregated data are unavailable. The rule primarily affects the production of asphalt-
saturated felt, roll roofing, shingles, and modified bitumen membranes.
Asphalt shingles are widely used because they are one of the least expensive roofing
options (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant, 1991). Asphalt shingles represent approximately
52 percent of the value of shipments of the entire asphalt shingle and coating materials
manufacturing industry (NAICS 324122). Other significant findings of this section are that
the asphalt shingle and coating materials manufacturing industry is unconcentrated, and that
foreign trade represents an insignificant fraction of the activity in the U.S. asphalt roofing
product market.
2-1
Table 2-1. Types of Products in Asphalt Shingle and Coating Materials Manufacturing
Industry (NAICS 324122)
8-Digit
Product NAICS Code
Roofing asphalts and pitches, coatings, and cements (NAICS 3241221)
Roofing asphalt 324122 1 1
Fibrated and nonfibrated asphaltic roofing coatings 324122 1 2
Other roofing asphalts and pitches, coatings, and cements 324122 1 3
Prepared asphalt and tar roofing and siding products, including saturated felts
and boards for nonbuilding use (NAICS 3241222)
Asphalt smooth-surfaced roll roofing and cap sheets, organic and fiberglass 324122 2 1
base
Asphalt mineral-surfaced roll roofing and cap sheets, organic and fiberglass 324122 2 2
base
Asphalt strip shingles, organic base (excluding laminated), all weights 324122 2 3
Asphalt strip shingles, inorganic base (excluding laminated), 215 to 235 lb- 324122 2 4
sales square
Asphalt strip shingles, inorganic base (excluding laminated), all other 324122 2 5
weights
Laminated or multilayered asphalt strip shingles and individual shingles 324122 2 6
Other prepared asphalt and tar products for roofing and siding 324122 2 7
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1999. 1997 Economic Census: Manufacturing
Industry Series—Asphalt Shingle and Coating Materials Manufacturing. EC97M-3241C.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. <http://www.census.gov/prod/ec97/97m3241c.pdf>.
2-2
market-level data on prices and quantities and discusses trends and projections for the
industry.
The asphalt roofing products affected by the NESHAP include blow asphalt, surfaced
and smooth roll roofing, fiberglass and organic (felt-based) shingles, and modified bitumen
membranes. With the exception of modified bitumen membranes, most asphalt roofing
products are produced in a similar manner. The production process typically involves six
stages, and asphalt is the primary input. The production process and the associated costs of
production are the focus of this section.
As noted above, the asphalt roofing products potentially affected by the rule are
blown asphalt, asphalt shingles (fiberglass or organic shingles), roll roofing (asphalt felts),
and modified bitumen roofing (MBR).
Asphalt felts are used as inner roof coverings and serve as protectants and sealants.
They are suited for this use because they are water repellent, able to tolerate temperature
fluctuations, and resistant to breakdown and decay caused by exposure to the elements
(Hillstrom and Ruby, 1994).
Both surfaced and smooth roll roofing are outer roof coverings commonly used for
low-cost housing and utility buildings in place of asphalt shingles. They are purchased in
rolls that are 36 to 38 feet long and approximately 36 inches wide, thereby simplifying the
roof application process (Scharff, 1996).
Asphalt shingles have different characteristics depending on whether their base mat is
organic felt or glass-fiber. Organic felts are produced from paper fibers, rags, wood, or a
combination of the three, while glass-fiber base mats are manufactured from inorganic, thin
glass fibers. If the base is organic, the shingle has the lowest possible American Society
Testing and Materials (ASTM) fire-resistant rating, referred to as a Class C rating. The
organic-based shingle is also considered to be flexible, even in cold weather. The fiberglass
shingle has the highest fire-resistance rating (Class A), which means roofing is able to
tolerate severe exposure to fire originated from sources outside the building (Scharff, 1996).
Unlike the organic-base shingles, these are quite inflexible in cold weather.
2-3
measuring about 12 inches in width and 36 inches in length. The three-tab shingle is the
most common strip shingle. The three-tab shingle gives the appearance of three separate
shingles and is stronger and easier to apply. Interlocking shingles come in various shapes
and with different locking devices, which provide not only a mechanic interlock but also
resistance to strong winds (Scharff, 1996). As for large individual shingles, they are
generally rectangular or hexagonal in shape (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant, 1991).
Modified bitumen membranes have a number of uses. They can be applied as the
primary material for new roofs, as a cover for existing roofs, and as cap sheets in built-up
roofing (BUR) applications (Scharff, 1996). For each of these applications, styrene-
butadiene-styrene (SBS)-based membranes are installed using hot asphalt, a torch, cold
process adhesives, or self-adhesives. Atactic polypropylene (APP)-based membranes are
usually installed with a torch or cold process adhesives. Both SBS- and APP-based
membranes are purchased in rolls and are usually applied in multiple layers (Kroschwitz and
Howe-Grant, 1991). Advantages of modified bitumen membranes over other roofing
materials are their versatility in both steep and low-slope roofing applications and their
puncture resistance, durability, and weatherability.
Asphalt is the primary material input to the production of asphalt roofing products. It
is made of saturants, asphaltenes, and resins. The properties that make asphalt suitable for
roofing are its softness, flexibility, and strength. Asphalt has the ability to expand and
contract with the application surface. This is because asphalt contains saturants, which are
light oils that make it soft and flexible. On the other hand, asphaltenes (high molecular
weight cyclic aromatic compounds containing nitrogen, oxygen, and/or sulfur in their
molecular structure [Phoenix Chemical Corporation, 2001]) provide asphalt body, rigidity,
and strength while resins bond the saturants and asphaltenes and give asphalt its resilience
(Scharff, 1996).
The quality of the asphalt depends on the source of the crude oil used in its
production. A crude oil with a high flash point is desired, because combustion and
vaporization of such light oils are most probable at higher flash points. Lower flash points
result in a harder asphalt flux that is better suited for paving applications than for roofing
(Hillstrom and Ruby, 1994).
2-4
2.1.3 Asphalt Blowing
Prior to initiating the operations necessary for producing asphalt roofing products, the
asphalt is prepared through a process called “blowing.” Asphalt is blown or oxidized to
increase its softening temperature and its consistency, or penetration value, so that it will not
flow off the roof in hot weather (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant, 1991). The blowing process,
which involves the oxidation of asphalt flux by bubbling air through it when it is in liquid
form, results in an exothermic reaction that requires cooling. Oxidation may take place over
a time period spanning from 1 to 10 hours, depending on the desired characteristics of the
roofing asphalt. The softening point and penetration rate of asphalt depend on how long it is
allowed to oxidize (MRI, 1995). In addition, the presence of catalysts affects the rate of
oxidation because catalysts speed up this process. After oxidation occurs, the asphalt is
ready to enter into the asphalt roofing production process.
Figure 2-1 illustrates the emissions sources of the blowing process, which are the
asphalt flux storage tanks and the blowing stills (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant, 1991). Both
particulate matter (PM) and volatile organic compounds (VOCs) are emitted from these
sources. The oxidation of asphalt may also contribute to the emission of hazardous air
pollutants (HAPs) if catalysts are present during oxidation.
After asphalt is prepared through the blowing process, it is used in the production of
asphalt-saturated felt, surfaced and smooth roll roofing, fiberglass and organic (felt-based)
shingles, and modified bitumen membranes. For each of these products, with the exception
of modified bitumen membranes, production typically consists of the following six primary
operations:
& felt saturation: using asphalt with a low softening point to saturate either
organic or fiberglass felts/mats;
& coating: applying coating/modified asphalt and a mineral stabilizer on the
felts/mats;
& mineral surfacing: applying mineral surfacings to the bottom of the felts/mats;
& cooling and drying: using water-cooling and air-drying procedures to bring the
product to ambient temperatures;
2-5
Figure 2-1. Flow Diagram of the Asphalt Blowing Process
Source: Midwest Research Institute (MRI). 1995. AP-42, 5th Edition, Volume 1, Chapter 11 Mineral Products
Industry. Prepared for U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Air Quality Planning and
Standards. Cary, NC: Midwest Research Institute.
2-6
& product finishing: formatting the designated asphalt roofing products; and
& packaging.
The specific production process for each of the asphalt roofing products is the focus of the
remainder of this section.
Surfaced and smooth rolls can be produced using either organic felt or a fiberglass
mat as the base or substrate. Figure 2-2 illustrates the typical production process for surfaced
or smooth rolls that use organic felt as the substrate (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant, 1991).
The first stage in the production process is asphalt saturation of felt. If a fiberglass mat is the
substrate, however, then the felt saturation step is excluded. After this step is completed,
either the saturated felt or fiberglass mat passes into the coater. The coater applies a filled
asphalt coating, which is prepared by mixing coating asphalt or modified asphalt and a
mineral stabilizer in approximately equal proportions. The coater releases the filled coating
onto the top of the felt or mat. Squeeze rollers then apply filled coating to the bottom of the
felt or mat and distribute it evenly to form a thick base coating onto which surfacing
materials will adhere.
2-7
Figure 2-2. Flow Diagram of the Organic Shingle and Roll Manufacturing Production
Process
Source: Midwest Research Institute (MRI). 1995. AP-42, 5th Edition, Volume 1, Chapter 11 Mineral Products
Industry. Prepared for U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Air Quality Planning and
Standards. Cary, NC: Midwest Research Institute.
2-8
If surfaced rolls are being manufactured, the asphalt sheet produced by the coater
passes through the granule applicator next. Smooth roll production excludes this step.
During the granule application stage, surfacing material is applied by dispensing granules
onto the hot, coated surface of the asphalt sheet. Sand, talc, or mica is also applied to the
sheet as it passes through the press roll, which forces the granules into the coating
(Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant, 1991).
Following the application of surfacing material for surfaced roll production, or the
coating stage for smooth roll production, the asphalt sheet passes through the final
production stages. The sheet is first cooled rapidly on water-cooled rolls and/or by using
water sprays. Then, if surfaced rolls are being produced, the sheet passes through air
pressure-operated press rolls used to embed the granules firmly into the coating. Asphalt
sheets for both surfaced and smooth roll production are then air dried. A strip of asphalt
adhesive is applied next, the purpose of which is to seal the loose edge of the roofing after it
is installed. These processes are facilitated by a finish looper, which allows continuous
movement of the sheet as it passes through each of these final production stages. It also
serves to further cool and dry the sheet. The final stage of roll roofing production is the
formation of the rolls. This takes place by passing the roofing sheet through a winder, where
rolls are formed.
Figure 2-2 illustrates the emission points of this production process. The asphalt
storage tanks, blowing stills, saturators, coater-mixer tanks, and coaters emit both PM and
VOCs. Adhesive applicators are also sources of trace quantities of PM and VOCs. PM is
emitted by surfacing operations and materials handling as well (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant,
1991).
2.1.4.3 Shingles
Organic felt and fiberglass mat-based shingle manufacturing involves the same
production processes as surfaced and smooth roll roofing, with the exception of the final roll
formation step. Instead of forming rolls with the roofing sheets, the sheets are passed
through a cutter, which cuts the sheet into individual shingles. If the shingles are going to be
made into laminated products, they must also pass through a lamination stage where
laminant is applied in narrow strips to the bottom of the sheet (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant,
1991).
Each of the emissions sources from the manufacture of surfaced and smooth roll
roofing is applicable to shingle production as well. These sources are indicated in
2-9
Figure 2-2. In addition to these sources, emissions are produced by the laminant applicators
used in shingle production. These applicators are sources of trace quantities of PM and
VOCs.
After the asphalt has been modified, a reinforcement is added. The reinforcements
most commonly used in modified bitumen production are polyester and fiberglass mats.
Both polyester and fiberglass mats are used with SBS-modified bitumen, while polyester
mats are most commonly used with APP-modified bitumen (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant,
1991). Polyester mats are superior to fiberglass mats as reinforcements in modified bitumen
membranes because polyester has higher elongation and higher puncture resistance than
fiberglass. However, fiberglass has higher tensile strength than polyester.
2-10
2.1.5 Major By-Products, Co-Products, and Input Substitution Possibilities
In this section, the costs of producing asphalt roofing products, historical costs for the
industry, and plant size efficiency are examined. These figures are reported for
NAICS 324122, Asphalt Shingle and Coating Materials Manufacturing, which includes
asphalt coatings and mopping asphalts. These two products are included in Section 2.1.6
because more disaggregated data are not available.
Table 2-2 provides the primary costs of production for the asphalt roofing industry
for the years 1990 through 1998 in both current and constant 1999 dollars. In general, costs
of production in real terms have increased over the past 9 years. Costs as a percentage of
value of shipments have been relatively flat, fluctuating between 73 percent and 79 percent.
In 1998, costs of production accounted for 73 percent of the value of shipments.
Table 2-3 provides information on the efficiency of plant size for those facilities in
NAICS 324122. Using the value added per production worker as a measure of efficiency,
there are no apparent economies of size for this industry. As Table 2-2 shows, the value
added per production worker hour peaks at $97.50 for those facilities with 5 to 9 employees,
2-11
Table 2-2. Historical Costs of Production for NAICS 324122, Asphalt Shingle and Coating Materials
Manufacturing: 1990-1998
1997 $3,722 $3,755 $499 $504 $150 $151 $3,072 $3,100 $5,095 $5,141 73%
1998 $3,887 $3,956 $523 $532 $149 $151 $3,216 $3,272 $5,350 $5,444 73%
Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995b. 1992 Census of Manufactures, Industry Series—Petroleum and Coal
Products. MC92-I-29A. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 2000. 1998 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and
Industries. M98(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1998. 1996 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and
Industries. M96(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1997. 1995 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and
Industries. M95(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1996. 1994 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and
Industries. M94(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995c. 1993 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and
Industries. M93(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2000a. “Producer Price Index Revision—Commodities: WPUSOP3000, Finished Goods: 1990-1999.”
<http://146.142.4.24/cgi-bin/surveymost>.
Table 2-3. Efficiency of Plant Size for Facilities in NAICS 324122, Asphalt Shingle and
Coating Materials Manufacturing
Value
Value Added by Number of Production Added/Production
Employees Manufacturer ($106) Worker Hours (hrs) Worker Hour
1 to 4 employees $11.0 0.2 $55.00
5 to 9 employees $19.5 0.2 $97.50
10 to 19 employees $71.3 0.8 $89.13
20 to 49 employees $225.8 2.4 $94.08
50 to 99 employees $477.9 5.7 $83.84
100 to 249 employees $869.3 10.2 $85.23
250 to 499 employees NA NA NA
500 to 999 employees NA NA NA
NA = Not available.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1999. 1997 Economic Census: Manufacturing
Industry Series—Asphalt Shingle and Coating Materials Manufacturing. EC97M-3241C.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. <http://www.census.gov/prod/ec97/97m3241c.pdf>.
and it generally drops for the following categories. The 1 to 4 employees category has the
lowest value added, which is $55 per production worker hour. For the 250 to 499 employees
and 500 to 999 employees categories, the information is withheld to avoid disclosing data on
individual companies.
The primary consumers of asphalt roofing products are those in the construction
industry. This industry selects asphalt-based products for roofing applications for a number
of reasons, especially their excellent waterproofing capabilities. In addition to asphalt
roofing products, the construction industry also relies on a number of substitute roofing
products. The characteristics, uses, and consumers of asphalt roofing products, as well as the
substitutes for these products, are the focus of this section.
Asphalt roofing products are popular among consumers because of their excellent
waterproofing capabilities. The specific type of asphalt product desired by an end user varies
2-13
depending on a number of factors. These factors include the end-user’s budget, the ease of
installation, the type of surface area to which the product is being applied, and the climate
and weather patterns of the location where the roofing products are installed.
If climate or weather patterns are of concern to the end user, the type of asphalt
shingle desired depends on the climatic conditions. Compared to organic-based asphalt
shingles, fiberglass-based shingles are generally better suited for warmer climates because
they can stiffen in cold climates. In warmer climates fiberglass-based shingles are preferred
because they are more weather resistant and have the highest ASTM fire-resistance rating.
This is because fiberglass-based shingles contain more coating asphalt, which provides
greater resistence to warping, rotting, blistering, and curling (Hillstrom and Ruby, 1994).
The desired shape of asphalt shingles also varies depending on the geographic area of
application. The most common shape is the three-tab shingle, which has two slots cut in its
front edge. These slots serve to provide stress relief as the shingle expands and contracts
with the weather. In areas often characterized by strong winds, the T-lock shingle may be
the shingle of choice. This is a highly wind-resistant slotted T-shaped shingle that locks to
the shingle both above and below it (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant, 1991).
Consumers may select modified bitumen membranes if they desire a product that is
versatile and able to suit a wide variety of project needs. These membranes are suitable for
both steep and low-slope applications and have the durability and flexibility necessary for
free span buildings, such as aircraft hangars and warehouses. In addition, modified bitumen
membranes are effective in both cold and warm weather climates (Kroschwitz and Howe-
Grant, 1991).
Asphalt roofing products are initially consumed by the construction industry, with
only a small percentage going to nonbuilding uses. It is worth noting that asphalt products
are intermediate goods that are inputs into final products, such as housing and other
buildings, produced by the construction industry. In addition, asphalt roofing products may
be sold to consumers for home improvement. The uses of these products and the demand for
asphalt roofing products by the construction industry sector are discussed below.
2-14
2.2.2.1 Uses of Asphalt Roofing Products
Table 2-4 lists the primary types of asphalt roofing products. As a percentage of
value of shipments, asphalt strip shingles make up the majority of products in this industry
(52.1 percent). Roll roofing and cap sheets account for 9.7 percent of the total, while roofing
asphalt accounts for 6.4 percent. The “other” asphalt roofing products category includes
asphalt roofing cements and pitches, modified bitumen membranes, and asphalt- and tar-
saturated felts for nonbuilding uses.
Table 2-4. Major Uses of Products in NAICS 324122, Asphalt Shingle and Coating
Materials Manufacturing
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1999. 1997 Economic Census: Manufacturing
Industry Series—Asphalt Shingle and Coating Materials Manufacturing. EC97M-3241C.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. <http://www.census.gov/prod/ec97/97m3241c.pdf>.
About 81 percent of all asphalt roofing products are used in residential construction,
while the remaining 19 percent are used in the commercial construction market (Kroschwitz
and Howe-Grant, 1991). For the residential market, reroofing jobs consume 79 percent of all
asphalt roofing products and the remaining 21 percent are used in new construction
applications (Burns and Paulson, 1997).
The majority of these products are used in nonfarm residential structure maintenance
(24.4 percent). Two sectors—maintenance of nonfarm buildings not elsewhere classified
(n.e.c.) and nonfarm residential one-unit structures—also consume a large portion of asphalt
roofing products (22 percent and 13.4 percent, respectively). Other sectors that rely on
asphalt roofing products are office buildings (7.1 percent), nonfarm residential
2-15
additions/alterations (4.7 percent), construction of educational buildings (3.1 percent), and
industrial buildings (3.1 percent).
This section identifies the characteristics of the asphalt roofing industry in the United
States. The issues affecting the asphalt roofing industry’s organization are addressed at both
the company and the facility levels.
When compared across industries, firms in industries with fewer firms, more product
differentiation, and restricted entry are more likely to be able to influence the price they
receive for a product by reducing output below perfectly competitive levels. This ability to
2-16
influence price is referred to as exerting market power. At the extreme, a single
monopolistic firm may supply the entire market and hence set the price of the output.
Table 2-5 presents the various measures of market concentration for the asphalt felts
and coatings industry. The HHI for NAICS 324122 is 778, which is less than the
Department of Justice’s threshold value of 1,000 for market power potential. The
unconcentrated nature of the asphalt roofing industry implies that individual producers in this
industry are less likely to be able to set the market price of asphalt roofing products.
Table 2-6 lists all of the asphalt roofing manufacturing facilities in the 50 states and
the District of Columbia as of 1999 and provides company name, facility location, product
type, and sales and employment ranges. Data on plant locations and product types were
obtained from the Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing Association (ARMA) and Dun &
Bradstreet and complemented with information from American Business Information.
As reported in Table 2-6, 34 companies owned and operated 123 facilities that
produce asphalt roofing materials during 1999. Figure 2-3 presents the distribution of the 76
facilities for which sales data were available by sales ranges. The range with the largest
number of facilities (25) is $20 to $50 million, followed by the number of facilities (24) with
sales between $50 to 100 million dollars. Four facilities have sales volumes less than
2-17
Table 2-5. Market Concentration Measures for NAICS 324122, Asphalt Shingle and
Coating Materials Manufacturing
Category Value
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) 778
Four-firm concentration ratio (CR4) 47
Eight-firm concentration ratio (CR8) 65
Number of companies 149
Number of facilities 248
6
Value of shipments ($10 ) 4,932
Sources: U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission. Horizontal Merger Guidelines.
<http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/horiz_book/hmg1.html> April 8, 1997.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1992. Concentration Ratios in
Manufacturing. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1999. 1997 Economic Census: Manufacturing
Industry Series—Asphalt Shingle and Coating Materials Manufacturing. EC97M-3241C.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. <http://www.census.gov/prod/ec97/97m3241c.pdf>.
$5 million, five between $5 to $10 million, nine between $10 to $20 million, and nine with
more than $100 million. Sales data were not available for 47 facilities.
Employment information was not available for 45 of the 123 facilities. Figure 2-4
illustrates the distribution of facility employment for 78 facilities for which employment
information is available. Facilities with between 100 and 249 employees are the most
numerous (38 establishments), and those employing fewer than 100 employees
(36 establishments) make up the second largest segment. Only four facilities employ more
than 249 workers.
Besides asphalt roofing manufacturing facilities, Table 2-7 also reports the refineries
that process asphalt. In 1999, seven companies owned and operated nine refineries that
produce blown asphalt as their only asphalt product. Likewise Figures 2-3 and 2-4
incorporate sales and employment data for the identified refineries, which have larger sales
volumes and employ more workers when compared to asphalt roofing manufacturing
facilities. However, sales information was lacking for three refineries, and employment
information was lacking for two refineries. Two refineries have sales volumes less than
$100 million, while the other three have sales volumes of more than $100 million. Four out
of seven refineries employ more than 249 workers and the rest employ fewer than 249.
2-18
Table 2-6. Facility-Level Product, Sales, and Employment for Asphalt Roofing Manufacturers
Products
Employment
Blown Fiberglass Organic Built-up Modified Saturated Sales Range Range
Company Facility Location Asphalt Shingle Shingle Roofing Bitumen Felt ($106) (number)
Atlas Roofing Corp. Ardmore, OK Y 10–20 100
Atlas Roofing Corp. Daingerfield, TX Y 50–100 138
Atlas Roofing Corp. Franklin, OH Y 20–50 170
Atlas Roofing Corp. Hampton, GA Y 100–500 160
Atlas Roofing Corp. Meridian, MS Y NA 207
Atlas Roofing Corp. Quakertown, PA Y 50–100 90
Bitec Morrilton, AR Y 12 45
Carlisle Syntec Systems Sapulpa, OK Y 112 750
Certainteed Corp. Avery, OH Y Y NA NA
Certainteed Corp. Birmingham, AL Y NA NA
Certainteed Corp. Charleston, SC Y Y 50–100 120
Certainteed Corp. Chester, PA Y NA NA
2-19
(continued)
Table 2-6. Facility-Level Product, Sales, and Employment for Asphalt Roofing Manufacturers (continued)
Products
Employment
Blown Fiberglass Organic Built-up Modified Saturated Sales Range Range
Company Facility Location Asphalt Shingle Shingle Roofing Bitumen Felt ($106) (number)
Elk Corp. Ennis, TX Y 50–100 250
Elk Corp. Meyerstown, PA Y NA NA
Elk Corp. Shafter, CA Y 20-50 100
Elk Corp. Tuscaloosa, AL Y 50-100 158
Firestone Building Products Beech Grove, IN Y Y NA NA
Firestone Building Products Bristol, CT Y NA NA
GAF Corp. Albuquerque, NM Y NA NA
GAF Corp. Baltimore, MD Y 100–500 165
GAF Corp. Corvalis, OR Y NA NA
GAF Corp. Dallas, TX Y Y 20–50 100–249
GAF Corp. Erie, PA Y Y 20–50 140
GAF Corp. Fontana, CA Y Y NA NA
2-20
(continued)
Table 2-6. Facility-Level Product, Sales, and Employment for Asphalt Roofing Manufacturers (continued)
Products
Employment
Blown Fiberglass Organic Built-up Modified Saturated Sales Range Range
Company Facility Location Asphalt Shingle Shingle Roofing Bitumen Felt ($106) (number)
Globe Building Materials, Inc. St. Paul, MN Y Y Y Y 50–100 120
Globe Building Materials, Inc. Whiting, IN Y Y Y Y 50–100, 120, 30
100–500
Herbert Malarkey Roofing Co. Portland, OR Y Y Y Y 38.0 100
Honeywell Inc. Detroit, MI Y NA NA
Honeywell Inc. Fairfield, AL Y NA NA
Honeywell Inc. Ironton, OH Y 50–100 90
Iko Production, Inc. Chicago, IL Y Y 20–50 100
Iko Production, Inc. Franklin, OH Y Y 20–50 50
Iko Production, Inc. Sumas, WA Y Y 5–10 5
Iko Production, Inc. Wilmington, DE Y 20–50 70
Johns Manville Corp. Kansas City, KS Y 10–20 30
2-21
(continued)
Table 2-6. Facility-Level Product, Sales, and Employment for Asphalt Roofing Manufacturers (continued)
Products
Employment
Blown Fiberglass Organic Built-up Modified Saturated Sales Range Range
Company Facility Location Asphalt Shingle Shingle Roofing Bitumen Felt ($106) (number)
Owens Corning Denver, CO Y 50–100 80
Owens Corning Denver, CO Y NA NA
Owens Corning Detroit, MI Y NA NA
Owens Corning Houston, TX Y 2.5–5 5
Owens Corning Irving, TX Y 50–100 115
Owens Corning Jacksonville, FL Y 50–100 90
Owens Corning Jessup, MD Y 20–50 98
Owens Corning Kearny, NJ Y 50–100 100
Owens Corning Medina, OH Y 100–500 160
Owens Corning Memphis, TN Y 20–50 105
Owens Corning Memphis, TN Y NA NA
Owens Corning Minneapolis, MN Y 20–50 77
2-22
(continued)
Table 2-6. Facility-Level Product, Sales, and Employment for Asphalt Roofing Manufacturers (continued)
Products
Employment
Blown Fiberglass Organic Built-up Modified Saturated Sales Range Range
Company Facility Location Asphalt Shingle Shingle Roofing Bitumen Felt ($106) (number)
Tamko Roofing Products, Inc. Dallas, TX Y 50–100 150
Tamko Roofing Products, Inc. Frederick, MD Y Y Y 100–500 200
Tamko Roofing Products, Inc. Green Cove Springs, Y NA NA
FL
Tamko Roofing Products, Inc. Joplin, MO Y Y Y Y Y 100–500 300
Tamko Roofing Products, Inc. Knoxville, TN Y 20–50 81
Tamko Roofing Products, Inc. Naples, TX Y NA NA
Tamko Roofing Products, Inc. Phillipsburg, KS Y Y Y Y 100–500 271
Tamko Roofing Products, Inc. Tuscaloosa, AL Y Y 20–50 100–249
Tarco, Inc. Belton, TX Y Y 10–20 50
Tarco, Inc. Greencastle, PA Y 1–2.5 5
Tarco, Inc. N. Little Rock, AR Y 10–20 30
The Garland Co. Cleveland, OH Y 50–100 100
2-23
(continued)
Table 2-6. Facility-Level Product, Sales, and Employment for Asphalt Roofing Manufacturers (continued)
Products
Employment
Blown Fiberglass Organic Built-up Modified Saturated Sales Range Range
Company Facility Location Asphalt Shingle Shingle Roofing Bitumen Felt ($106) (number)
Refineries (continued)
Inland Refining Inc. Woods Cross, UT Y 40.6 85
Marathon Ashland Petroleum St. Paul Park, MN Y 500-1000 250-499
LLC
Marathon Ashland Petroleum Cattlesburg, KY Y NA NA
LLC
Marathon Ashland Petroleum Canton, OH Y over 1 250-499
LLC billion
Paramount Petroleum Corp Paramount, CA Y 239.7 413
Tesoro Refining Kapolei, HI Y 28.5 240
NA = Not available.
2-24
Sources: Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing Association. 1997. “Manufacturing Plants.” Facsimile on member company plant listing. Calverton, MD. September
24.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000a. 2000 Dun & Bradstreet Million Dollar Directory Series. America’s Leading Public and Private Companies.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000b. Electronic database.
American Business Information (ABI). 2000. Electronic database. Omaha, NE.
30
25
Number of Facilities
20
15
10
0
Less than $5 $5 to $10 $10 to $20 $20 to $50 $50 to $100 More than
$100
Sales ($106)
40
35
30
Number of Facilities
25
20
15
10
0
Fewer than 20 20 to 49 50 to 99 100 to 249 More than 249
Employees
2-25
Table 2-7. Location of Asphalt Roofing Products Manufacturing Facilities by State
a
Total number of facilities in each state may not add up to the total number of production lines in each state.
Some of the facilities have more than one production line.
Source: Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing Association. 1997. “Manufacturing Plants.” Facsimile on member
company plant listing. Calverton, MD. September 24.
2-26
2.3.2.1 Geographic Distribution
Asphalt roofing plants are located in 35 states. Overall, California is the state with
the largest number of facilities (18), followed by Texas (13), Ohio (11), Alabama (8), and
Georgia (7). These five states are home to approximately 44 percent of the total number of
asphalt roofing facilities in the country.
Product information is available for the 123 facilities and nine refineries identified in
Table 2-6. In 25 states, 66 asphalt roofing factories produce fiberglass shingles as one of
their outputs. California and Texas have the most factories (by state) producing fiberglass
shingles (seven and eight, respectively). Other states with a large number of fiberglass
shingle facilities are Georgia and Ohio (five each).
Thirty-seven of the 123 facilities for which product information is available produce
MBR as one of their outputs. These facilities that produce MBR are located across 20 states.
With five facilities, California has the most factories producing MBR, followed by Ohio,
which has four. Arkansas and Texas each have three facilities producing MBR.
Of the 123 facilities for which product data are available, 34 produce built-up
roofing. Of the 20 states with facilities producing built-up roofing, California has the most
factories (five), followed by Alabama (four) and Texas (three). (Built up roofing is
manufactured at the building site with alternating layers of mopping asphalt and roofing felt.)
Twenty-five facilities in the group produce saturated felt. Of the 19 states with
saturated felt factories, California (five), Alabama (two), and Arkansas (two) are the only
states that have more than one facility.
Seven facilities produce organic shingles. Minnesota (two) is the only state that has
more than one asphalt roofing facility with organic shingles as a product. Six states have
organic shingles factories.
Besides nine refineries, blown asphalt is also produced in six facilities, representing
nearly 5 percent of the 123 asphalt roofing manufacturing facilities for which data are
available. The 14 factories are located in Alabama, California (two refineries), Colorado,
Kentucky, Michigan, Minnesota, North Carolina, Ohio, Oklahoma (one refinery and one
asphalt roofing manufacturing facility), Oregon, Tennessee, and Utah.
2-27
2.3.2.2 Current Trends
The U.S. asphalt roofing products industry expanded in the mid-1990s because of
new purchases, additions, and plants. Both GAF Corp. and Firestone Building Products
increased capacity at their plants in Tampa, FL, and Beech Grove, IN, respectively. Elk
Corporation’s new $30 million facility in Shafter, CA, began producing laminated asphalt
shingles in 1995 (Straub, 1995). Owens Corning will open its new Fiberteq LLC facility in
Danville, IL, in the third quarter of 2001, which is a joint venture with Canada’s IKO
Industries. This Fiberteq facility will manufacture high quality wet-formed glass fiber mat,
which will be used primarily in the production of asphalt roofing shingles (Owens Corning,
2001).
Facilities comprise a site of land with a plant and equipment that combine inputs to
produce output (in this case blown asphalt, fiberglass shingles, organic shingles, built-up
roofing, modified bitumen roofing, saturated felt, and glass mat). Companies owning these
facilities are legal business entities that have the capacity to conduct transactions and make
business decisions that affect that facility. The terms establishment, facility, and plant are
synonymous in this study and refer to the physical location where products are
manufactured. Likewise, the terms company and firm are synonymous and refer to the legal
business entity that owns one or more facilities. This firm characteristics section presents
information on the parent companies that own the asphalt roofing manufacturing plants and
refineries identified in Section 2.3.2.
2.3.3.1 Ownership
2-28
Table 2-8. Parent Companies
(continued)
2-29
Table 2-8. Parent Companies (continued)
NA = Not available.
a
Owns Carlisle Syntec Systems
b
Owned by Compagnie de Saint-Gobain
c
Owns Elk Corp.
d
Owns GAF Materials Corp.
e
Owns IKO Production, Inc.
f
Owns Honeywell Inc.
g
Owns Pabco Roofing Products
h
Owns Tremco Inc.
i
Owns Inland Refining Inc.
Sources: Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing Association. 1997. Manufacturing Plants. Facsimile on member
company plant listing. Calverton, MD. September 24.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000a. 2000 Dun & Bradstreet Million Dollar Directory Series. America’s
Leading Public and Private Companies.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000b. Electronic database.
American Business Information (ABI). 2000. Electronic database. Omaha, NE.
2-30
asphalt at its seven refinery operations in the United States (Hoover’s, 2001). Other firms
operating refineries that produce blown asphalt include Hunt Refining, Huntway Refining,
Paramount Petroleum, Gary-Williams Energy, Inland Refining, and Tesoro Refining.
Figure 2-5 presents the distribution of companies by sales ranges and is limited to
companies for which data were available. Sales and employment information for
four companies is currently unavailable. Twenty-four companies have sales lower than
$300 million a year, four have sales between $300 million and $1 billion, and nine have sales
greater than $1 billion.
30
25
Number of Companies
20
15
10
0
Less than $300 million Between $300 million and $1 More than $1 billion
billion
Sales (Dollars)
Figure 2-6 presents the distribution of the same companies by employment range.
Twenty-two companies employ 749 or fewer people, three employ between 750 and 1,499,
and ten companies employ 1,500 or more.
2-31
25
20
Number of Companies
15
10
0
Fewer than 750 Between 750 and 1,499 More than 1,499
Employees
2-32
However, vertical and horizontal integration are not mutually exclusive, meaning that
a corporation is usually not either in a pure form, but a mixture of both. Perceiving a firm as
horizontally or vertically integrated depends on vantage point. The above companies can be
seen as vertically integrated because one subsidiary feeds an input into another. However,
the products each subsidiary produces may be as varied as tires and asphalt shingles, an
aspect of horizontal integration. The smaller companies involved in manufacturing asphalt
roofing products are, for the most part, neither vertically nor horizontally integrated; they
produce a sole product without having forward or backward corporate linkages. These
companies purchase inputs from outside suppliers, not of their corporate tree. Then they
manufacture the product and sell it either directly to consumers or through wholesalers. In
its pure form, horizontal integration is the situation in which one company produces various,
unrelated products rather than specializing in one particular product.
2.4 Markets
This section examines the historical market statistics and future trends and
projections for the asphalt roofing industry. Historical data for this industry are provided for
the value of shipments, prices, foreign trade, and consumption of asphalt roofing products.
The future trends section focuses on projected demand and employment for the asphalt
roofing industry.
Data on the value of shipments from 1990 through 1998 for the asphalt roofing
industry are available from the Census Bureau. However, historical data on prices and
domestic production volumes of asphalt roofing products are not available. Prices were
estimated in 1999 constant dollars for asphalt roofing products by using the producer price
index (PPI) for asphalt roofing products, which is obtained from the U.S. Department of
2-33
Table 2-9. Small Companies: 1999
NA = Not available.
a
Owned by Compagnie de Saint-Gobain
b
Owns IKO Production, Inc.
c
Owns Inland Refining Inc.
Sources: Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing Association. 1997. “Manufacturing Plants.” Facsimile on member
company plant listing. Calverton, MD. September 24.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000a. 2000 Dun & Bradstreet Million Dollar Directory Series. America’s
Leading Public and Private Companies.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000b. Electronic database.
American Business Information (ABI). 2000. Electronic database. Omaha, NE.
2-34
Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Foreign trade data for individual asphalt roofing products
are not reported because of the aggregate nature of the available data. Industry-level import
and export data were obtained from the U.S. Department of Commerce and are reported for
the years 1990 through 1999.
Table 2-10 provides the value of shipments for the asphalt roofing industry. As the
table shows, the value of shipments, in constant 1999 dollars, is highest for the year 1998, at
$5.3 billion. After dropping to its lowest value at $3.5 billion in 1991, the value of
shipments began to rise. However, the value of shipments was relatively flat over the years
1992 through 1996.
2.4.1.2 Prices
A time series of estimated prices in current dollars for asphalt roofing products is
presented in Table 2-11. The products for which prices are provided are smooth and
surfaced roll roofing, strip shingles, and individual organic or inorganic shingles. The 1992
price for each product was estimated by dividing the 1992 value of shipments by the 1992
volume of shipments for that product. The 1992 price was then multiplied by the PPI for
asphalt felts and coatings for the years 1990 through 1999 to obtain prices for other years.
As Table 2-11 shows, the estimated prices for asphalt roofing products are
characterized by moderate fluctuations over the 1990 through 1999 time period. Prices were
at their peak in 1997 and at their lowest in 1994. Estimated 1999 prices for asphalt roofing
products range from $6.78 to $11.21 per square.
U.S. exports and imports of asphalt roofing products make up only a small portion of
the total asphalt roofing product market. In 1998, the domestic value of shipments of this
industry was $5 billion. By comparison, only $75 million worth of asphalt roofing products
were exported, and $46 million worth were imported in 1998.
Although the total value of imports to the United States (see Table 2-12) over the
1989 through 1996 time period was higher than the total value of exports, the value of
exports was higher on a per-kilogram basis. The price range of the value of exports in 1999
dollars was $0.40 to $0.58, while the price range for the value of imports was only $0.18 to
$0.29. Therefore, asphalt roofing products exported from the United States have a higher
value than U.S. imports of these products.
2-35
Table 2-10. Value of Shipments for NAICS 324122, Asphalt Shingle and Coating Materials
Manufacturing: 1990-1998 ($109)
Value of Shipments
Current $ 1999 $
1990 $3.6 $3.8
1991 $3.4 $3.5
1992 $3.9 $4.1
1993 $4.2 $4.3
1994 $4.0 $4.3
1995 $4.3 $4.3
1996 $4.5 $4.5
1997 $5.1 $5.1
1998 $5.4 $5.3
Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 2000. 1998 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries.” M98(AS)-1. Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1998. 1996 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M96(AS)-1. Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1997. 1995 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M95(AS)-1. Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1996. 1994 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M94(AS)-1. Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995c. 1993 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M93(AS)-1. Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995a. 1991 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M91(AS)-1. Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2000b. “Producer Price Index Revision—Current Series:
PCU2952#, Asphalt Felts and Coatings: 1990-1999.” <http://146.142.4.24/servlet/
SurveyOutputServlet?jrunsessionid=9772358862760607>.
A small number of countries make up the majority of U.S. import sources and export
destinations for U.S. asphalt roofing products. Canada’s exports of asphalt roofing products
to the United States, which were valued at $27 million in 1999, make up over 55 percent of
the total U.S. imports of these products. Other countries from which the United States
2-36
Table 2-11. Historical Prices of Asphalt Roofing Products: 1990-1999a
a
Prices were calculated by dividing 1992 value of shipments by quantities and then multiplying by the PPI for
the relevant year for asphalt felts and coatings divided by 100.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995b. 1992 Census of Manufactures,
Industry Series—Petroleum and Coal Products. MC92-I-29A. Washington, DC: Government
Printing Office.
imports asphalt roofing products are Mexico (26.5 percent) and Venezuela (8.8 percent).
Among the primary importers of U.S. asphalt roofing products are Canada, Korea, and
Mexico. Exports to Canada make up 48.1 percent of all U.S. exports of these products, while
exports to Korea and Mexico make up much smaller shares of the total value of U.S. exports
of asphalt roofing products (13 percent and 6.2 percent, respectively).
2.4.1.4 Consumption
2-37
Table 2-12. Apparent U.S. Consumption and Import Concentration of Asphalt Roofing
Products: 1990-1998 ($103)
a
Apparent consumption = U.S. shipments – U.S. exports + U.S. imports.
b
Import concentration was calculated as the ratio of imports to apparent U.S. consumption.
Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 2000. 1998 Annual Survey of Manufactures:
Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries.” M98(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing
Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1998. 1996 Annual Survey of Manufactures:
Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M96(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing
Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1997. 1995 Annual Survey of Manufactures:
Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M95(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing
Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1996. 1994 Annual Survey of Manufactures:
Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M94(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing
Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995c. 1993 Annual Survey of Manufactures:
Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M93(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing
Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995a. 1991 Annual Survey of Manufactures:
Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M91(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing
Office.
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2000b. “Producer Price Index Revision—Current Series:
PCU2952#, Asphalt Felts and Coatings: 1990-1999.” <http://146.142.4.24/servlet/
SurveyOutputServlet?jrunsessionid=9772358862760607>.
2-38
years. Apparent U.S. consumption of asphalt roofing products was at its highest in 1998 at
$5.3 billion.
Table 2-12 also provides the import concentration for asphalt roofing products, which
indicates the percentage of total U.S. consumption that comprises imports. As the table
shows, imports made up only a small percentage of apparent U.S. consumption of asphalt
roofing products. The import concentrations ranged from only 0.86 percent to 1.91 percent
over the 1990 through 1998 time period.
Limited information is available on future trends and projections for the asphalt
roofing industry. Based on the forecasts of the Freedonia Group (1997) and Gale Research
(1995), the industry is expected to see a moderate increase in the demand for its products,
while employment in the industry is projected to decline. Demand for asphalt roofing is
expected to increase slightly into the next century as the market for building materials
improves. However, competition from new synthetic roofing materials is expected to keep
the rise in demand for asphalt roofing products at a minimum. Employment in the asphalt
roofing industry is expected to decline into the 21st century as a result of productivity
improvements from increased automation and layoffs by manufacturers. According to the
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, positions in the asphalt roofing industry are expected to
decrease by 10 to 20 percent between 1990 and 2005.
2-39
SECTION 3
EPA identified 123 asphalt roofing manufacturing plants and nine refineries in the
United States and estimated the costs for each to comply with the NESHAP for asphalt
roofing manufacturing. Only nine of the asphalt roofing manufacturing facilities are directly
affected by the rule; all nine refineries are expected to incur costs due to the rule.
EPA identified incremental compliance activities that would be required for these
facilities to comply with the rule, and estimated the costs they would incur to install new
capital equipment (thermal oxidizer and ductwork and/or particulate matter device and
ductwork), and to perform incremental operating and maintenance activities associated with
the equipment.
EPA estimated the total annual compliance cost of this rule to be $1.7 million for
existing asphalt roofing manufacturing facilities and refineries. These estimates are based on
the number of facilities and refineries expected to incur emission control costs which are
made up of capital costs and operating and maintenance (O&M) costs; monitoring, record
keeping, and reporting (MRR) costs; or both. Table 3-1 presents the estimated annual
compliance costs for both asphalt roofing manufacturing plants and refineries in terms of
emission control costs and MRR costs. For asphalt roofing manufacturing facilities, the
estimated total capital costs for emission control is $1.1 million and the total annualized
costs are $0.5 million. Refineries are projected to incur $1.6 million in capital costs, and
total annualized costs of $0.9 million. Table 3-2 summarizes estimated emission control
costs for the eighteen facilities that are projected to incur these costs because of the rule. The
average total capital cost is $151,000 while the average total annualized emission control
cost is about $78,000. The total capital costs range from less than $2,000 to $1.4 million.
The total annualized emission control costs vary from $800 to $0.9 million. Monitoring,
recordkeeping and reporting costs are estimated to average $16,850 per year for each facility.
3-1
Table 3-1. National Control Costs Estimates for Existing Facilities
Notes: Total Annualized Emission Control Costs = Annualized Capital Costs + O&M Costs
Average Annual MRR Cost = (Year 1 Total Annual Cost + Year 2 Total Annual Cost + Year 3 Total
Annual Cost)/3
Total Annual Cost = Total Annualized Emission Control Costs + Average Monitoring, Recordkeeping,
and Reporting Costs
Totals may not sum due to rounding errors.
Source: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2002. “Summary of Cost Impacts for the Final Asphalt
Processing and Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing NESHAP.”
EPA also calculated the compliance costs for new asphalt roofing manufacturing
plants. Table 3-3 lists the estimated compliance costs based on the year when the new
manufacturing plants begin production. If a manufacturing facility comes in the market in
year 1, year 2, or year 3, the estimated total annual cost would be about $0.4 million. Even
though the total annual costs are about the same regardless of the year, the MRR costs are
less for those facilities that enter the market later. For its analysis, EPA assumes a plant
beginning operations in year 2.
3-2
Table 3-2. Summary of Facility-Level Emission Control Costs Estimates
Source: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2002. “Summary of Cost Impacts for the Final Asphalt
Processing and Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing NESHAP.”
a
EPA assumes one new facility per year.
Notes: Total Annualized Emission Control Costs = Annualized Capital Costs + O&M Costs
Average Annual MRR Cost = (Year 1 Total Annual Cost + Year 2 Total Annual Cost + Year 3 Total
Annual Cost)/3
Total Annualized Cost = Total Annualized Emission Control Costs + Monitoring, Recordkeeping, and
Reporting Costs
Source: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2002. “Summary of Cost Impacts for the Final Asphalt
Processing and Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing NESHAP.”
3-3
SECTION 4
This section describes the methodology used to estimate the economic impacts on
society resulting from the final regulation. This framework employs standard
microeconomic concepts to model behavioral responses expected to occur with regulation
and is consistent with other economic analyses performed by the Agency.
The Agency uses several types of economic impact modeling approaches to support
regulatory development. Models incorporating different levels of economic decisionmaking
can generally be categorized as without-behavior responses (nonbehavioral/accounting
approach) and with-behavior responses (behavioral approach).
4-1
4.2 Conceptual Approach
EPA utilizes a simple national competitive market model in which buyers and sellers
exert no individual influence on market prices for asphalt roofing commodities potentially
affected by the rule. Prices in these markets are set by the collective actions of producers
and consumers, who take the market price as a given in making their production and
consumption choices. The model compared baseline conditions (1999) to with-regulation
conditions projected to exist in these markets.
Many asphalt roofing plants produce multiple asphalt roofing products. Therefore,
individual product-line supply decisions for existing producers have been modeled in this
analysis. Note these decisions have been modeled as intermediate-run decisions, assuming
that the plant size, equipment, and technologies are fixed. Given the existence of these fixed
production factors, each product line has been characterized by an upward-sloping supply
function (see Figure 4-1). A profit-maximizing firm would select its output level according
to this schedule as long as the market price is sufficiently high to cover average variable
costs (i.e., greater than C0 in Figure 4-1). Thus, in the short run, a profit-maximizing firm
would not pass up an opportunity to recover even part of its fixed investment in plant and
equipment. These individual supply decisions have been aggregated (i.e., horizontally
summed) to develop a market supply curve for each asphalt roofing product.
4-2
$/lb Sd
C0
lbs/year
Demand for asphalt roofing products comes mainly from the construction industry,
although a small share is sold directly to consumers for home improvements and repairs.
Eighty-one percent of asphalt roofing products are used in residential construction, while the
remaining 19 percent are used in the commercial construction market (Kroschwitz and
Howe-Grant, 1991). Of the residential market, re-roofing jobs consume 79 percent of all
asphalt roofing products, and the remaining 21 percent are used in new construction
applications. Asphalt shingles alone accounted for about 57 percent of the residential new
construction market and 68.5 percent of the residential reroofing market (Burns and Paulson,
1997). Substitutes for asphalt shingles and roll roofing in residential applications include
wood shingles, metal roofing, and tile roofing. Only coal tar bitumen is a substitute for
asphalt-saturated felt. Synthetic rubbers can be used in place of modified bitumen
membranes in BUR applications (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant, 1991). All of these
substitutes exhibit somewhat different properties from asphalt products, however, and are not
perfect substitutes. Given data limitations, each commodity market has been modeled as
having a single aggregate consumer with a downward-sloping market demand curve (see
Figure 4-2).
4-3
4.2.4 Baseline and With-Regulation Equilibrium
The competitive model of price formation, as shown in Figure 4-2(a), posits that
market prices and quantities are determined by the intersection of the market supply and
demand curves. Under the baseline scenario, a market price and quantity (p,Q) are
determined by the downward-sloping market demand curve (D) and the upward-sloping
market supply curve (S) that reflects the sum of the individual supply curves of domestic
plants that produce a given asphalt roofing product.
With the regulation, the costs of production increase for affected suppliers. These
additional costs include a variable component consisting of the operating and maintenance
costs and a fixed component that does not vary with output (i.e., expenditures for
control-related capital equipment to comply with the regulatory alternative). The imposition
of these regulatory control costs is represented as an upward shift in the supply curve for
each directly affected product line. As a result of the upward shift in these individual supply
curves, the market supply curve for asphalt roofing products will shift upward as shown in
Figure 4-2(b) to reflect the increased costs of production at affected plants.
In baseline without the final standards, the industry produces total output, Q, at price,
p, with directly affected facilities producing the amount qa and indirectly affected facilities
accounting for Q minus qa, or qu. With the regulation, the market price increases from p to
p1, and market output (as determined from the market demand curve, D) declines from Q to
Q1. This reduction in market output is the net result of reductions at directly affected
facilities and increases at indirectly affected facilities.
EPA collected market information to characterize the baseline year, 1999 and
provided total domestic production quantities of individual commodities. As described in the
industry profile, foreign trade represents an insignificant fraction of the activity in the U.S.
asphalt roofing market. Net exports for NAICS 324122 were well below 1 percent of value
of shipments during the period 1990 through 1998. Therefore, foreign producers and
consumers were not modeled in the economic analysis. Instead, we made the simplifying
assumption that the U.S. domestic market for asphalt roofing products is supplied entirely by
domestic manufacturers and that domestic manufacturers do not export asphalt roofing
products to other countries.
4-4
Sa Su SM
p + p = p
DM
qa qu Q
a) Baseline Equilibrium
S′a Sa Su SM′ SM
p′ p′ p′
p + p = p
DM
q′a qa qu q′u Q′ Q
b) With-Regulation Equilibrium
4-5
To identify the economic impact of the final NESHAP on the asphalt roofing
industry, we incorporated the facility-level data from various sources into our economic
model. One hundred twenty-three asphalt roofing manufacturing plants and nine refineries
in the United States have been identified as facilities potentially affected by the rule. Table
4-1 lists the data elements of the asphalt roofing manufacturers dataset, which was compiled
from data provided by the Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing Association (ARMA), EPA’s
Information Collection Request, and public sources. Data on facility locations, product
types, and production capacity were obtained from ARMA. EPA’s Information Collection
Request provided data on production of individual asphalt roofing products at the facility
level. In addition, we collected sales volumes and employment data from the available
public sources, such as American Business Information, Dun & Bradstreet, and the
Freedonia Group, as well as foreign trade information from the Census Bureau and
International Trade Commission websites. We also collected and computed an average price
for each commodity based on price data we have obtained from statistical publications (i.e.,
Census of Manufactures, 1995) and from the Freedonia Group (2000).
On the supply side, the supply of asphalt roofing products has been relatively stable.
The asphalt roofing industry is not as cyclical as the building industry despite the integral
relationship between the two industries. The reason that asphalt roofing is not a highly
cyclical industry is that there are essentially two roofing markets: the new construction
market and the reroofing market. As noted earlier, the reroofing market represented over 75
percent of the total residential roofing market. Thus, reroofing activity dampens swings in
new construction activity. Entry into the industry is not difficult because there are no major
patent obstacles, and capital requirements are not excessive. However, the ease of entry into
the industry is offset by the fact that existing plant capacity is underutilized. The capacity
utilization ratio for existing plants in the asphalt felts and coatings industry (NAICS 324122/
SIC 2952) ranged from 68 to 80 percent during the period 1993 to 1998 (U.S. Census
Bureau, 2000). These factors indicate that the supply of asphalt roofing products is relatively
stable. Due to the lack of estimates readily available in the literature, a price elasticity of
supply of 1 is assumed for asphalt roofing products for the market analysis.
On the demand side, several substitution possibilities exist for asphalt roofing
products. Popular substitutes include elastomeric roofing (used in single-ply roofing) and
metal roofing. Wood shingles, tile, clay, metal, and plastic are other materials that can be
used in place of asphalt shingles and roll roofing. Although several substitutes exist, asphalt
4-6
Table 4-1. Types and Sources of Asphalt Roofing and Processing Facility Data
Sources: Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing Association (ARMA). 1997. “Manufacturing Plants.” Facsimile on member
company plant listing. Calverton, MD. September 24.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2001. Asphalt Roofing Industry Database.
American Business Information (ABI). 2000. Electronic database. Omaha, NE.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000a. 2000 Dun & Bradstreet Million Dollar Directory Series: America’s Leading Public
and Private Companies.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000b. Electronic database.
Hoover’s Online. 2001. Electronic database.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995a. 1991 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics
for Industry Groups and Industries. M91(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995b. 1993 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics
for Industry Groups and Industries. M93(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1996. 1994 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics for
Industry Groups and Industries. M94(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1997. 1995 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics for
Industry Groups and Industries. M95(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1998. 1996 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics for
Industry Groups and Industries. M96(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 2000. 1998 Annual Survey of Manufactures: Statistics for
Industry Groups and Industries. M98(AS)-1. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
Freedonia Group. February 2000. “Asphalt Products and Markets in the United States to 2003—Introduction,
Executive Summary, Market Environment, Technology and Regulation, International Environment, Primary
Supply, Demand, Products and Products by Market.” Profound WorldSearch <http://www.profound.com>.
U.S. International Trade Commission. Trade Database. <http://dataweb.usitc.gov/scripts/>.
4-7
roofing products still dominate the market. Asphalt shingles alone accounted for about 57
percent of the residential new construction market and 68.5 percent of the residential
reroofing market (Burns and Paulson, 1997). In contrast, wood shingles accounted for only
3.5 percent of the residential new construction market and 3.2 percent of the reroofing
market. Asphalt-saturated felts and modified bitumen membranes have few substitution
possibilities. Coal tar bitumen is the only known suitable replacement for asphalt-saturated
felt. Synthetic rubbers can be used in place of modified bitumen membranes in BUR
applications. However, synthetic rubbers are less adaptable to repair and maintenance work
than modified bitumen roofing (Kroschwitz and Howe-Grant, 1991).
& demand elasticity for the final good it will be used to produce,
& the cost share of the input in total production cost,
& the elasticity of substitution between this input and other inputs in production, and
& the elasticity of supply of other inputs (Hicks, 1961; Hicks, 1966; and Allen,
1938).
Using Hicks’ formula,
4-8
where
n = absolute elasticity of demand for final product (housing and other structures),
In the appendix to The Theory of Wages, Hicks (1966) shows that, if n > s, the
demand for the input is less elastic the smaller its cost share. If the data were available, this
formula could be used to actually compute the elasticity of demand for each asphalt roofing
product. The final products for which asphalt roofing is an input include housing repair and
maintenance services and construction of housing and other structures. Of these, our
literature review identified an estimate for the short-run elasticity of demand for housing,
which is estimated to be –0.579 (Glennon, 1989). Lacking estimates of other elasticities of
final product demand and of the other parameters in the formula makes direct computation of
the elasticity of demand, i, impossible. In spite of this, the formula is useful because it
identifies factors that influence the magnitude of the elasticity of derived demand.
Knowledge of the general magnitude of those factors makes it possible to make an educated
assumption about the magnitude of the elasticity of demand for asphalt roofing products (i).
The elasticity of substitution, (s), between asphalt roofing products and other inputs
to construction is likely to be low but nonzero. For this analysis, EPA assumes the elasticity
of substitution between asphalt roofing products and other inputs to construction to be 0.1.
Building owners or builders have some alternative roofing options available, but they are
imperfect substitutes for asphalt roofing products.
EPA expects that the elasticity of demand for the final product exceeds the elasticity
of substitution, implying that the magnitude of i is proportional to the magnitude of K, the
cost share of asphalt roofing in overall building construction. Based on the benchmark input-
output accounts for the United States, petroleum and refined products (including asphalt
roofing) represent 1.2 percent of new construction and 2.0 percent of maintenance and repair
construction (Lawson, 1997). Because re-roofing uses the majority of asphalt roofing
products, EPA used the cost share for maintenance and repair construction, and set the cost
share, K, for this analysis at 0.02.
4-9
Given that the cost share of roofing products in the total production cost of new and
maintenance construction is very small (0.02), the elasticity of demand for one of the final
products (housing) is relatively low (–0.579), and ease of substitution between inputs
imperfect, the elasticity of demand for asphalt roofing products would be inelastic (i.e., less
than 1 in absolute value). In fact, it may be substantially lower. Assuming the elasticity of
supply of other inputs, e, is 1, and the elasticity of substitution between asphalt roofing and
other inputs, s, is 0.1, EPA estimated the elasticity of demand for asphalt roofing products.
Using these assumptions and the elasticity of demand for housing (–0.579), EPA computed
an estimated elasticity of demand for organic shingles, fiberglass singles, and roll roofing
equal to –0.107. For MBR and blown asphalt, which are not so closely associated with
housing, EPA computed the elasticity of demand using the same assumptions as mentioned
above, but assuming that the elasticity of demand for construction is –1. Under these
assumptions, the computed elasticity of demand for those asphalt roofing projects is –0.11.
The uncertainty of these elasticity of demand estimates is acknowledged.
The simple analytics presented in Section 4.2 suggest that, when faced with higher
costs of asphalt roofing production, producers will attempt to mitigate their impacts by
making adjustments to shift as much of the burden to other economic agents as market
conditions allow. The adjustments available to facility operators include changing
production processes, changing inputs, changing output rates, or closing product lines and/or
facilities. This analysis focuses on the last two options because they appear to be the most
viable for asphalt roofing facilities, at least in the near term. We would expect upward
pressure on prices as producers facing higher costs reduce output rates in response to these
costs. Changes in market prices and, through the impact of price on quantity demanded,
output for each product will lead to changes in the profitability of product lines, facilities,
and firms. These market and industry adjustments will also determine the social costs of the
regulation, as described in Appendix B.
The increased cost of production due to the regulation is expected to increase the
price of asphalt roofing products and reduce production/consumption from baseline levels.
Based on the applicability of engineering compliance costs from Section 3, a total of $0.645
million (including $0.476 million in emissions control costs and $0.168 million in MRR
costs) are applied to firms in the model. As shown in Table 4-2, the final regulation is
projected to increase the average price of asphalt roofing products by less than 0.01 percent.
4-10
Domestic production of asphalt roofing products declines by approximately 258 tons.
However, no price or quantity change is projected for organic shingles, because no costs of
compliance are assigned to that industry sector.
Revenue, costs, and profitability of the asphalt industry also change as prices and
production levels adjust to increased costs associated with compliance. Operating profits are
projected to decrease by $0.23 million (see Table 4-3). Operating profit decreases are the net
result of three effects: increased revenue ($0.37 million), reductions in production costs as
output declines ($0.04 million), and incurred control costs ($0.64 million). Table 4-4
provides the detailed information about distributional impacts across the facilities. Asphalt
roofing facilities incurring compliance costs are projected to earn $0.57 million less in profits
with the regulation, while facilities that do not incur costs are projected to experience
increased profits of $0.34 million.
One of the most sensitive issues to consider in the EIA is the possibility that the
regulation may induce a producer to shut down operations rather than comply with the
regulation. The data (such as direct observations of plant-level costs and profits) necessary
to make definitive projections of these impacts are unavailable from the survey data.
Therefore, EPA employed a method of estimating plant closure decisions using broad
industry measures of profitability as described below. EPA defined a plant closure as the
cessation of all asphalt roofing manufacturing operations at a site. It is possible that some
plant locations may have other activities on-site that are unaffected by the final rule and that
may continue even if asphalt roofing operations cease.
The plant closure criterion used for this analysis is defined as follows:
(4.2)
where total revenue (TRj) is the sum of the product revenue from plant j’s product lines, and
total cost (TCj) is the sum of the plant’s variable production costs and total avoidable fixed
costs, which are estimated using baseline revenues, variable production costs, and estimated
profits, which were computed based on an industrywide profit margin of 3 percent. This
4-11
Table 4-2. Market-Level Impacts: 1999
With Change
Baseline Regulation Absolute Relative
Blown Asphalt
Price ($/ton) $168.67 $168.70 $0.03 0.02%
Quantity (tpy) 3,328,394 3,328,330 –69 0.00%
Fiberglass Shingles
Price ($/ton) $161.69 $161.70 $0.02 0.01%
Quantity (tpy) 15,138,624 15,138,450 –184 0.00%
Organic Shingles
Price ($/ton) $161.69 $161.69 $0.00 0.00%
Quantity (tpy) 552,853 552,853 0 0.00%
Total
Price ($/ton) $320.03 $320.04 $0.02 0.00%
Quantity (tpy) 28,862,292 28,862,050 –258 0.00%
4-12
Table 4-3. Industry-Level Impacts: 1999
With
Baseline Regulation Absolute Relative
6
Total revenue ($10 /yr) $9,236.71 $9,237.08 $0.37 0.00%
6
Total costs ($10 /yr) $8,931.90 $8,932.50 $0.60 0.01%
Control $0.00 $0.64 $0.64 NA
Production $8,931.90 $8,931.86 –$0.04 0.00%
6
Pre-tax earnings ($10 /yr) $304.81 $304.58 –$0.23 –0.08%
a
Full-time equivalents
profit margin for the asphalt shingles and coating industry (SIC 2952: Asphalt Felts and
Coatings Industry) was obtained from Industry Norms and Business Ratios 1999/2000 (Dun
and Bradstreet, 2000c). The conceptually correct view would assume the plant also has some
positive liquidation value or opportunity value in an alternative use that is not captured in the
TC elements used to compute %j. However, no data are available to estimate these
opportunity costs. Therefore, the Agency has assumed that the plant’s liquidation value is
exactly offset by the costs of closing a plant.
(4.3)
4-13
Table 4-4. Distributional Impacts Across Facilities: 1999
Pre-Tax Earnings
Gain or no
Loss change Close Total
Facilites (#) 10 113 0 123
Production
Total (tpy) 3,192,000 25,671.000 0 28,862,000
Average (tons/facility) 319,000 227,000 NA 235,000
Compliance costs
Total ($106/yr) $645,000 $0 $0 $645,000
Average ($/unit) $0.20 $0.00 NA $0.02
NA = Not available
a
Earnings before income taxes
b
Full-time equivalents
Because changes in output at most facilities are very small, EPA projects changes in
employment at each facility that are in the range of fractions of a full-time equivalent
employee. Overall, employment increases at facilities that do not incur compliance costs are
projected to more-or-less offset employment decreases at facilities incurring compliance
costs due to the rule. EPA’s model essentially projects no change in industry employment as
a result of the regulation, as reported in Tables 4-3 and 4-4.
4-14
that this measure does not include benefits that occur outside the market, that is, the value of
reduced levels of air pollution with the regulation.
Value ($106/yr)
Consumer Surplus –$0.41
Blown asphalt –$0.11
Fiberglass shingles –$0.28
Organic roll roofing –$0.03
Organic shingles $0.00
Modified bitumen roll roofing (MBR) $0.00
4-15
4.5 Impacts on Refineries
EPA has identified seven companies, owning nine refineries, that may be affected by
the rule. The companies are shown in Table 4-6. Marathon Ashland Petroleum owns three
affected facilities; all the other companies listed own a single affected facility. Of the
companies listed, four are small: Huntway Refining, Gary Williams Energy, Silver Eagle
Refining (Inland Refining) and Paramount Petroleum. Because only nine refineries owned
by seven companies are affected by the rule, EPA assumes that companies owning refineries
will be unable to pass any of the costs along to their customers in the form of higher prices
for refinery products. This is a conservative assumption, resulting in the maximum estimate
of impacts on refineries. In fact, some increase in prices may be possible. Analysis of
impacts on refineries is conducted at the firm level based on this full-cost absorption
approach, using a cost-to-sales analysis.
Estimated compliance costs for companies owning refineries range from $17,600 to
$894,000, and total $1.09 million. The median cost for companies is $21,800. Costs for the
three large companies total more than $993,000. Costs for the small companies total
$89,800. Data on company sales are available for all four large companies owning
refineries, and for two of the three small companies. Costs for large companies range from
0.0004 percent of sales to 0.119 percent of sales. Costs for the three small companies with
sales data range from 0.011 percent of sales to 0.045 percent of sales. Thus, EPA expects
impacts on refineries to be generally very small.
Sources: Electronic Databases: American Business Information (ABI), Dun & Bradstreet, Hoover’s Online.
4-16
Table 4-7. Cost-to-Sales Ratios for Small and Large Companies
Sources: Final Asphalt Costs 121702.xls, Electronic Databases: American Business Information (ABI), Dun &
Bradstreet, Hoover’s Online.
The competitive model of price formation is provided in Figure 4-3. In the figure, the
willingness of existing suppliers to produce alternative quantities of asphalt products
is represented by SE and the demand for asphalt products is shown as D0. The
equilibrium market price, P0, is determined by the intersection of these curves.
Figure 4-3 shows a constant cost industry where market price is exactly equal to the
unit cost of new facilities, SN.
In a growing industry, the demand for the commodity shifts outward (e.g., to D1),
placing upward pressure on prices and providing the incentive for investors to add
new productive capacity.1 As new capacity enters the market, the new equilibrium
price is P1, which is exactly equal to the unit cost of supply from new facilities. In
this example, it is the same value as the old price, P0. The new equilibrium quantity,
Q1, includes the additional output supplied by new sources: (Q1–Q0).
The final NESHAP will increase existing plants’ costs of producing asphalt products
by shifting existing supply, SE, up. It will also increase the costs of supply from new
1
For simplicity, impacts are considered for one future time period.
4-17
facilities. These increases in costs will place upward pressure on prices. As shown in
Figure 4-4, with demand curve, D1, prices would be expected to increase with shifts
in supply until the average price of asphalt products, P11, is equal to the unit cost of
supply from new facilities including the cost of the NESHAP. However, as shown in
Figure 4-5, no new capacity expansion will take place if the per-unit compliance costs
at new facilities exceeded P11. Thus, the simple analytics presented suggest that the
rule will likely cause investors to delay construction of new facilities until the price
increases just enough to cover all the costs of production.
4-18
$/lb
SE
SN
P0 = P1
D1
D0
Q0 Q1 lbs/year
Given the uncertainty about new facility unit costs (production and compliance) and
future market conditions, the Agency is limited to general assessments of the rule’s
impact on the rate of new facility construction. The Agency modeled two types of
new manufacturing plants—fiberglass shingles plants and MBR plants. Each new
plant will also produce and sell blown asphalt. To inform these assessments, the
Agency:
& estimated total annualized compliance costs to be $451,944 for each new
facility. The estimated total annualized emission control cost is $400,230.
The average annualized MRR cost is estimated to be $51,714 given that
the lifetime for the control equipment is 10 years.
& projected changes in equilibrium output with regulation for a future time
period (2002). Using the conceptual approach presented in Figures 4-4
and 4-5, the Agency estimated the change in facility construction for the
period 2001 to 2002 as follows:
4-19
$/lb
S′E
SE
P1 ′ S′N
P1 SN
D1
Q′1 Q1 lbs/year
where
d = Elasticity of demand
Z = Average size of a new facility
Q2002 = For 1995, the blown asphalt demand was estimated to be 3.3 million
tons, the fiberglass shingle demand was 15.1 million tons, and the
MBR roll roofing was about 2 million tons.2 For the period 1990 to
1998, the estimated growth rate of asphalt roofing products was 4
percent based on the values of shipments presented in Section 2.4.
Using a composite growth rate of 4 percent, the Agency estimated the
quantity of blown asphalt for the baseline year of 2002 to be 4.4
million tons while the estimated quantities for fiberglass shingles and
MBR roll roofing were 20.1 and 2.4 million tons respectively.
P = Calculated change of average new source per-unit control costs ($0.71
per ton for the fiberglass shingles plant and $1.40 per ton for the MBR
plant).
2
Quantity information for each asphalt product was obtained from the EPA Asphalt Roofing Industry Database.
4-20
$/lb S′E
SE
S′N
P1′
P1 SN
D1
Q′1 Q1 lbs/year
P = Baseline price for each asphalt product ($168.67 per ton for blown
asphalt, $161.69 per ton for fiberglass shingles, and $895.27 per ton
for MBR roll roofing).
Using this approach, the Agency projected a very small reduction in the growth of the
asphalt industry, represented by a reduction in the equilibrium quantity of asphalt
products projected in year 1. However, the reduction in equilibrium output of asphalt
products was only a small fraction of the estimated new plant capacity. Thus, the
Agency does not believe that the costs of complying with the regulation will be
sufficient to cause a delay in the construction of new facilities. Overall, the control
costs are not expected to influence the decision to enter the market for asphalt
products, although they may affect the producer’s selection of plant size or rate of
capacity utilization.
4-21
SECTION 5
Businesses producing asphalt roofing products are categorized as small or large using
the Small Business Administration’s (SBA’s) general size standards definitions. For
Asphalt Shingles and Coating Materials Manufacturing (NAICS 324122), the
guidelines indicate companies are considered small businesses if they employ 750 or
fewer workers (U.S. Small Business Administration, 2000). In contrast, the small
business threshold for petroleum refineries (NAICS 324110) is 1,500 employees.
Based on these definitions, the Agency identified 26 companies that are classified as
small, or 65 percent of the total number of companies affected by the regulation.
Twenty-two of these companies produce asphalt roofing products and the remaining
four are refineries (see Table 5-1).
For the purposes of assessing the potential impact of this rule on small businesses, the
Agency calculated the share of annual compliance cost relative to baseline sales for
each company. When a company owns more than one affected facility, the costs for
each facility it owns are summed to develop the numerator of the test ratio. For this
screening-level analysis, annual compliance costs were defined as the engineering
control costs imposed on these companies. Therefore, they do not reflect the changes
in production expected to occur in response to imposing these costs and the resulting
market adjustments.
5-1
Table 5-1. Small Companies: 1999
NA = Not available.
a
Owns Inland Refining Inc.
Sources: Asphalt Roofing Manufacturing Association. 1997. “Manufacturing Plants.” Facsimile on member
company plant listing. Calverton, MD. September 24.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000a. 2000 Dun & Bradstreet Million Dollar Directory Series. America’s
Leading Public and Private Companies.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000b. Electronic database.
American Business Information (ABI). 2000. Electronic database. Omaha, NE.
5-2
Engineering estimates of compliance costs for facilities owned by small businesses
total $89,800, as shown in Table 5-2. The average total annual compliance cost was
projected at slightly below $3,500 per small company as compared to the average of
$109,000 per large company. The annual compliance costs for small businesses
range from 0.00 to 0.04 percent of sales. The average (median) compliance cost-to-
sales ratio (CSR) is 0.003 (0.000) percent for the identified small businesses with
sales data and 0.009 (0.000) percent for the large businesses with sales data. As
shown, no small or large companies are projected to incur costs above 1 percent of
sales. Based on this information, it does not appear that any small businesses will
incur significant adverse economic impacts due to the regulation.
The Agency also analyzed the economic impacts on small businesses under with-
regulation conditions expected to result from implementing the final NESHAP.
Unlike the screening-level analysis described above, this approach examines small
business impacts in light of the expected behavioral responses of producers and
consumers to the regulation. As shown in Table 5-3, pre-tax earnings for facilities
owned by small businesses are projected to decline by $45,000, or 0.03 percent.
Employment (as measured by full-time equivalents) remains essentially unchanged.
5.4 Assessment
The results from the screening and economic analysis show that potential negative
impacts of the final rule on small businesses are small. The screening analysis shows
that compliance costs for all small companies are less than 1 percent of sales.
Reported average industry profit margins are higher than this 1 percent threshold,
typically exceeding 3 percent (Dun and Bradstreet, 1997). The economic analysis,
which accounts for behavioral responses to the regulation, provides additional
evidence that the final rule will have minimal impacts on company profits and
employment. As a result, the Agency has determined that the final rule is not likely
to impose a significant impact on a substantial number of the affected small entities
within this industry.
5-3
Table 5-2. Summary Statistics for SBREFA Screening Analysis: 1999
Note: Assumes no market responses (i.e., price and output adjustments) by regulated entities.
a
Annual sales data were unavailable for four ultimate parent companies. CSRs cannot be computed for these companies.
Table 5-3. Summary of Small Business Impacts: 1999a
Note: These estimates incorporate the expected market (i.e., price and output) adjustments of the regulated entities.
5-5
a
Impacts on refineries owned by small firms are not included in the market model.
b
Full-time equivalents.
REFERENCES
Allen, R.G.D. 1938. Mathematical Analysis for Economists. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Burns, Sandy, and Mari A. Paulson. 1997. “NRCA’s Market Survey Indicates Roofing
Business is Strong.” Professional Roofing April.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000a. 2000 Dun & Bradstreet Million Dollar Directory Series:
America’s Leading Public and Private Companies.
Dun & Bradstreet. 2000c. Industry Norms & Business Ratios 1999/2000.
Freedonia Group. February 2000. “Asphalt Products and Markets in the United States to
2003—Introduction, Executive Summary, Market Environment, Technology and
Regulation, International Environment, Primary Supply, Demand, Products and
Products by Market.” Profound WorldSearch <http://www.profound.com>.
Gale Research, Inc. 1995. U.S. Industry Profiles: The Leading 100. New York: Gale
Research, Inc.
Glennon, Dennis. 1989. “Estimating the Income, Price, and Interest Elasticities of Housing
Demand.” Journal of Urban Economics 25:219-229.
Hicks, J.R. 1961. “Marshall’s Third Rule: A Further Comment.” Oxford Economic Papers
13:262-65.
R-1
Hicks, J.R. 1966. The Theory of Wages. 2nd Ed. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Hillstrom, Kevin, and Mary K. Ruby, eds. 1994. Encyclopedia of American Industries,
Volume 1: Manufacturing Industries. New York : ITP.
Kelly, Kenneth. 1988. “The Analysis of Causality in Escape Clause Cases.” Journal of
Industrial Economics 37 (2):187-207.
Kroschwitz, Jacqueline I., and Mary Howe-Grant, eds. 1991. Kirk-Othmer Encyclopedia of
Chemical Technology. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Lawson, A. 1997. “Benchmark Input-Output Accounts for the U.S. Economy, 1992:
Requirements Tables.” Survey of Current Business. December, pages 22-47.
Straub, Patricia Sydney. June 14, 1995. Elk Corp. Begins Shingle Production at New
California Plant. The Bakersfield Californian.
Topel, Robert, and Rosen, Sherwin. 1988. “Housing Investment in the United States.”
Journal of Political Economy 96 (4):718-739.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2000. Survey of Plant Capacity: 1998. MQ-C1(98). Washington, DC:
U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995a. 1991 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M91(AS)-1.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995b. 1993 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M93(AS)-1.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
R-2
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1996. 1994 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M94(AS)-1.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1997. 1995 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M95(AS)-1.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1998. 1996 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M96(AS)-1.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 2000. 1998 Annual Survey of
Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and Industries. M98(AS)-1.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 1999. OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource
Document. Durham, NC: Innovative Strategies and Economics Group.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2001. Asphalt Roofing Industry Database.
R-3
APPENDIX A
This appendix describes the operational model used to estimate the economic impacts
of the final Asphalt Roofing Products NESHAP. Both the market supply and demand in the
operational model are characterized here.
To enable EPA to examine the impact of selecting different functional forms for the
supply function, the model includes the ability to express supply using the generalized
Leontief functional form. The generalized Leontief functional form is described below.
A.1.1 Using the Generalized Leontief Profit Function to Derive Output Supply
The specification of a facility j’s profit function for product n given by the
generalized Leontief is as follows:
(A.1)
Equation A.1 is an empirical model to estimate facilities’ profit, where Pn is the net market
price for product n manufactured by facility j, Ijn is the variable production cost variable
(described below), 0, 1, and 2 are model parameters, j indexes producers (i.e., affected
facilities), and n represents the five products identified in Section 4.2.1 (Chambers, 1988).
By applying Hotelling’s lemma to the generalized Leontief profit function, the following
general form of the product n supply function for facility j is obtained:
(A.2)
where qjn is the quantity of product n produced by facility j, Pn is the net market price for
each product, Ijn is the variable production cost variable (described below), jn = 1 and n =
2 are model parameters, j indexes producers (i.e., affected facilities), and n represents the
A-1
five products mentioned in Section 4.2.1. The theoretical restrictions on the model
parameters that ensure upward-sloping supply curves are jn 0 and n < 0.
Figure A-1 illustrates the theoretical supply function for product i represented by Eq.
(A.2). As shown, the upward-sloping supply curve is specified over a productive range with
a lower bound of zero that corresponds with a shutdown price equal to and an upper
bound given by the productive capacity of that is approximated by the supply parameter
jn. The curvature of the supply function is determined by the n parameter.
$/qn
p*
2
β
n
• In
γ 2j
γj = q
M
q*j j qj/t
An aggregate measure of the cost of variable inputs that are not used in fixed
proportions (price Ijn) can be constructed as a cost-share-weighted index of regional- and
state-level average hourly earnings (wj), average fuel prices (fj), and electricity prices (ej).
The Ijn variable varies across facilities because of all three variables (w,f,e). The cost shares
used to weight the variable cost components also vary by NAICS code. In EPA’s economic
impact estimation model, this was not done. The model assumed I=1.
The parameter is related to the facility j’s supply elasticity for product i, which can
be expressed as:
A-2
(A.3)
Taking the derivative of the facility supply function (Eq. [A.2]) with respect to price shows:
(A.4)
Multiplying this expression by Pn/qn results in the expression for the supply elasticity:
(A.5)
(A.6)
Values for the parameter can be computed in two ways: econometric estimation using
facility survey data or substitution of an econometrically estimated or assumed market
supply elasticity for product n (!jn), the average annual production level of facilities (qjn), the
variable production cost index (Ijn), and the market price of the product n (Pn). Note that
unlike the product-specific , the facility supply elasticity is not constant but varies with q, p,
and I.
A-3
The remaining supply function parameter, jn, approximates the productive capacity
and varies across products at each facility. This parameter does not influence the facility’s
production responsiveness to price changes as does the parameter. Thus, the parameter jn
is used to calibrate the model so that each facility’s supply equation replicates the baseline
production data.
(A.7)
(A.8)
where
Bn = a parameter that calibrates the demand equation to replicate the 1999 level of
domestic demand,
3
Total annual compliance cost estimates, provided by EPA’s engineering analysis, include capital costs, annual
operating and maintenance costs, and applicable monitoring costs.
A-4
A-5
APPENDIX B
The economic welfare implications of the market price and output changes with the
regulation can be examined using two different strategies, each giving a somewhat different
insight but the same implications: changes in the net benefits of consumers and producers
based on the price changes and changes in the total benefits and costs of these products based
on the quantity changes. This analysis focuses on the first measure—the changes in the net
benefits of consumers and producers. Figure B-1 depicts the change in economic welfare by
first measuring the change in consumer surplus and then the change in producer surplus. In
essence, the demand and supply curves previously used as predictive devices are now being
used as a valuation tool.
This method of estimating the change in economic welfare with the regulation
divides society into consumers and producers. In a market environment, consumers and
producers of the good or service derive welfare from a market transaction. The difference
between the maximum price consumers are willing to pay for a good and the price they
actually pay is referred to as “consumer surplus.” Consumer surplus is measured as the area
under the demand curve and above the price of the product. Similarly, the difference
between the minimum price producers are willing to accept for a good and the price they
actually receive is referred to as “producer surplus” or profits. Producer surplus is measured
as the area above the supply curve and below the price of the product. These areas can be
thought of as consumers’ net benefits of consumption and producers’ net benefits of
production, respectively.
In Figure B-1, baseline equilibrium occurs at the intersection of the demand curve, D,
and supply curve, S. Price is Pl with quantity Ql. The increased cost of production with the
regulation will cause the market supply curve to shift upward to S1. The new equilibrium
price of the product is P2. With a higher price for the product, there is less consumer welfare,
all else being unchanged as real incomes are reduced. In Figure B-1(a), area A represents the
dollar value of the annual net loss in consumers’ benefits with the increased price. The
rectangular portion represents the loss in consumer surplus on the quantity still consumed,
Q2, while the triangular area represents the foregone surplus resulting from the reduced
quantity consumed, Ql–Q2.
B-1
In addition to the changes in consumer welfare, producer welfare also changes with
the regulation. With the increase in market price, producers receive higher revenues on the
quantity still purchased, Q2. In Figure B-1(b), area B represents the increase in revenues due
to this increase in price. The difference in the area under the supply curve up to the original
$/Q S’
P2
A
P1
Q2 Q1 Q/t
(a) Change in Consumer Surplus with Regulation
$/Q S’
P2
B
P1
C
D
Q2 Q1 Q/t
(b) Change in Producer Surplus with Regulation
$/Q S’
P2
P1
D
D
B-2 Q2 Q1 Q/t
(c) Net Change in Economic Welfare with Regulation
Figure B-1. Economic Welfare Changes with Regulation: Consumer and Producer Surplus
market price, area C, measures the loss in producer surplus, which includes the loss
associated with the quantity no longer produced. The net change in producer welfare is
represented by area B–C.
The change in economic welfare attributable to the compliance costs of the regulation
is the sum of consumer and producer surplus changes, that is, – (A) + (B–C). Figure B-1(c)
shows the net (negative) change in economic welfare associated with the regulation as area
D. However, this analysis does not include the benefits that occur outside the market (i.e.,
the value of the reduced levels of air pollution with the regulation). Including this benefit
may reduce the net cost of the regulation or even make it positive.
B-3
TECHNICAL REPORT DATA
1. REPORT NO. 2. 3. RECIPIENT’S ACCESSION NO.
EPA-452/R-03-005
4. TITLE AND SUBTITLE 5. REPORT DATE
Economic Analysis of Air Pollution Regulations: Asphalt Roofing and Processing February 2003
6. PERFORMING ORGANIZATION CODE
16. ABSTRACT
This document is an Economic Impact Analysis of the National Emission Standard for Hazardous Air Pollutants (NESHAP) to limit air emissions from the production and processing
of asphalt roofing processing and production. For existing asphalt roofing producers and processors, the analysis evaluates the market impacts to the industry including estimates of
potential changes in market price, market quantity, employment impacts and the potential for facility or firm closures. The analysis also estimates the social cost or costs to society of
this regulation. Impacts to potentially affected refineries are evaluated on a cost-to-sales ratio basis. New source impacts and small business impacts are also addressed.
Market Impacts
Social Costs
Unclassified
Environmental Protection Air Quality Strategies and Standards Division February 2003