Critical Perspectives On Accounting: Lois S. Mahoney, Linda Thorne, Lianna Cecil, William Lagore
Critical Perspectives On Accounting: Lois S. Mahoney, Linda Thorne, Lianna Cecil, William Lagore
Critical Perspectives On Accounting: Lois S. Mahoney, Linda Thorne, Lianna Cecil, William Lagore
A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T
Article history: Over the past two decades, more and more U.S. firms are voluntarily issuing costly
Received 23 December 2011 standalone Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) Reports. Nevertheless, firms’ motivations
Received in revised form 4 September 2012 for issuing standalone CSR Reports are not clear. In this paper, we consider two different
Accepted 17 September 2012
explanations: signaling and greenwashing. The first explanation, signaling, proposes that
Available online 28 September 2012
firms use standalone CSR Reports as a signal of their superior commitment to CSR, which
suggests firms with stronger social and environmental records will be more likely to issue
Keywords:
standalone CSR Reports as compared to those without. The second explanation,
Environmental
Social greenwashing, proposes that firms use standalone CSR Reports to pose as ‘‘good’’
Sustainability corporate citizens even when they do not have stronger social and environmental records.
To provide insight into these explanations we compare the CSR performance scores of
Mots clés: firms that issue CSR reports to those firms that do not. We control for firm size, leverage,
Environnemental profitability and industry. We find that firms that voluntarily issue standalone CSR Reports
Social
generally have higher CSR performance scores, which suggests that firms are using
Développement durable
voluntary CSR Reports to publicize stronger social and environmental records to
Keywords: stakeholders.
Palabras clave:
Ambiental
Social
Sostenibilidad
ß 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
Stakeholders bestow benefits on firms they perceive to be ‘‘good’’ corporate citizens. ‘‘Good’’ corporate citizens are
granted preferential investment opportunities (Sen et al., 2006), have access to capital at lower costs (Orlitzky, 2008), find it
easier to attract and retain employees (Greening and Turban, 2000; Turban and Greening, 1997), and they are the recipients
of beneficial consumer behavior (Marin et al., 2009). To reap the benefits conferred on ‘‘good’’ corporate citizens, firms wish
to be perceived as ‘‘good’’ by their stakeholders.
1045-2354/$ – see front matter ß 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.cpa.2012.09.008
L.S. Mahoney et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 24 (2013) 350–359 351
In the absence of mandatory disclosure of corporate social responsibility (CSR) information, it is difficult for stakeholders
to determine which firms are, in fact, ‘‘good’’ (Gugerty, 2009). The resources needed to gather the available information about
firms’ commitment to social and environmental activities may be difficult to find or not be available (Belal and Cooper, 2011).
Voluntary disclosures of CSR activities are dispersed over an extremely wide range of sources, including media releases,
annual reports, web sites, supplemental disclosures (10-K) as well as standalone CSR Reports.
Voluntary standalone CSR Reports are known by many different names, including ‘‘Sustainability Reports’’,
‘‘Environmental Reports’’, ‘‘GRI Reports’’ and ‘‘Citizenship Reports’’. Standalone CSR Reports are separate compilations of
social and environmental information (Dilling, 2009). Regardless of what they are titled, these reports meet three criteria: a
focus on social and environmental issues, distinction from the firm’s annual report, and content that is not prescribed by
mandatory reporting criteria. CorporateRegister.com (2011) reports that the number of firms issuing voluntary CSR Reports
in the U.S. grew from just two in 1991, to 154 in 2001, and over 500 different firms and entities in 2010.3 Furthermore, a 2011
survey of CSR by KPMG International noted that nearly 95% of the largest 250 companies in the world are now issuing these
standalone CSR Reports.
Though the U.S. lags behind other countries in their issuing of standalone CSR Reports4, issuance of these voluntary
reports is increasing (CorporateRegister.com, 2011). By investigating U.S. firms’ motivation for issuing CSR reports, we gain
insight into whether firms that use standalone CSR Reports are in fact ‘‘good’’ corporate citizens with strong performances in
social and environmental arenas or just trying to appear to be so (Sikka, 2011; Cormier et al., 2004). Not only will this
investigation aid us in assessing whether there is a bias in voluntary CSR Report disclosures, but also adds to our
understanding of the strategy firms adopt for their voluntary CSR disclosures.
This paper is organized as follows. The next section develops the hypotheses. This section will be followed by sections
outlining our methodology, our results and supplementary analysis, and finally, a discussion of our findings.
2. Hypotheses
Our research attempts to understand whether U.S. firms issue standalone CSR Reports as a substantive signal of concern for
society and the environment, or alternatively, whether standalone CSR Reports are issued in an attempt to legitimize firms’
concerns for social and environmental issues (Lyon and Maxwell, 2011). There are several theories that consider the association
between voluntary CSR disclosures and CSR performance, which are generally consistent with either a voluntary disclosure
perspective to which signaling theory belongs, or theories grounded in a socio-political perspective to which greenwashing
belongs (cf., Clarkson et al., 2011a,b). These theoretical perspectives have a significant amount of overlap (Deegan, 2002), but
also have points of difference that can result in contrasting predictions of firms’ behavior (Clarkson et al., 2008).
Both theories assume benefits will accrue to ‘‘good’’ corporate citizens and stakeholders will punish ‘‘bad’’ corporate
citizens. Both theories assume that disclosure is costly (e.g., Verrecchia, 1983), and according to both theoretical
perspectives, firms will undertake voluntary disclosure when the benefits of providing standalone CSR Reports outweigh the
associated costs (Li et al., 1997).
One significant difference between the theoretical perspectives is the relative costs and benefits imposed on those that do
not ‘‘honestly report’’. On the one hand, signaling theory considers that the ‘‘costs’’ imposed by society on those that do not
‘‘honestly’’ report will be a sufficient deterrent so that ‘‘bad’’ corporate citizens will be less willing to voluntarily report than
‘‘good’’ corporate citizens. On the other hand, greenwashing considers that the ‘‘benefits’’ conferred to ‘‘bad’’ corporate
citizens is greater than those conferred to ‘‘good’’ corporate citizens. As a result, signaling theory suggests that ‘‘good’’
corporate citizens will be more likely to employ CSR disclosures, whereas greenwashing suggests that ‘‘bad’’ corporate
citizens will be more likely to employ CSR disclosures (Clarkson et al., 2008). The next section outlines the two theoretical
explanations leading to contrasting predictions.
The first explanation, signaling, draws from voluntary disclosure theory, which suggest that firms use standalone CSR
Reports as a substantive signal of their superior commitment to CSR (Clarkson et al., 2008; Al-Tuwaijri et al., 2004; Brammer
and Pavelin, 2004; Berthelot et al., 2003). Voluntary disclosure theory suggests that firms are voluntarily disclosing social
and environmental information to signal their actual superior position regarding CSR activities (cf., Healy and Palepu, 2001;
Verrecchia, 1983). According to a voluntary disclosure explanation, firms issue standalone CSR Reports to ensure that
stakeholders are aware of the appropriateness of the firms’ actions taken on social and environmental issues (Gray et al.,
1995; Clarkson et al., 2011a,b).
Voluntary disclosure theory suggests that ‘‘good’’ firms will use standalone CSR Reports to signal that the firm is a
‘‘good’’ corporate citizen (cf., Dye, 1985; Lizzeri, 1999). Even though disclosure is costly, ‘‘good’’ firms will benefit from
3
CorporateRegister.com hosts the world’s largest online directory of CSR and estimates that it has access to over 90% of the world’s published CSR Reports
(CorporateRegister.com, 2011).
4
For example, two-thirds of non-reporting G250 companies are based in the U.S. (KPMG, 2011a,b); therefore, it is particularly important to understand
the motivations of U.S. firms for issuing standalone CSR Reports.
352 L.S. Mahoney et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 24 (2013) 350–359
making stakeholders aware of their ‘‘good’’ performance, while firms that are not ‘‘good’’ may be punished by stakeholders5
(e.g., Verrecchia, 1983). Therefore, firms will undertake voluntary disclosure when the benefit of providing standalone
voluntary information, such as CSR Reports, outweighs the associated costs (Li et al., 1997). As applied to CSR performance,
Prado-Lorenzo and Garcia-Sanchez (2010) argue that companies with the superior CSR performance will try to obtain a
competitive advantage by voluntarily providing relevant CSR information. Consequently, companies with inferior CSR
performance will avoid distributing CSR information that would adversely affect their reputations (Prado-Lorenzo and
Garcia-Sanchez, 2010).
Signaling theory assumes that it is less costly for a firm with stronger performance to engage in voluntary disclosure
than one with weaker performance (Verrecchia, 1983). Although scarce, there is some support for the argument that firms
with stronger CSR performance will find it less costly to disclose CSR data than firms with weaker CSR performance in the
domain of voluntary CSR reporting.6 Sinclair-Desgagne and Gozlan (2003) present theoretical models where external
agents punish firms that purport to be ‘‘good’’ corporate citizens when they are not, and the Nike-Kasky Case (2002)
provides evidence that supports their models. Prior to 2002, Nike issued standalone CSR Reports that included false claims
regarding labor practices of its subcontractors in the third world. When the claims were subsequently proven false,
stockholders took legal action against Nike, which was subsequently settled when Nike agreed to pay $1.5 million to a labor
standards organization (Murray, 2005).7 This example shows that stakeholders are willing to punish false disclosures
included in CSR Reports.
As applied to the standalone CSR Reports, the signaling argument suggests that firms with stronger CSR performances will
incur lower costs when issuing standalone CSR Reports than firms with weaker CSR performances. Because it is less costly for
firms with stronger CSR performances, it follows that they will be more likely to issue standalone CSR Reports than those
with weaker CSR performance. This gives rise to our first hypothesis, consistent with a voluntary reporting perspective:
H1. Firms that issue standalone CSR Reports have stronger CSR performance than firms that do not issue standalone CSR
Reports.
The second explanation, greenwashing, emerges from a socio-political perspective that suggests that firms use
standalone CSR Reports to influence and enhance stakeholders’ perceptions of the appropriateness of their firm’s pro social
and environmental actions (Guidry and Patten, 2010; Lyon and Maxwell, 2011). The socio-political perspective encompasses
legitimacy theory, stakeholder theory, and political economy of accounting theory, which all suggest environmental
disclosure is a function of political and social pressures (Clarkson et al., 2008; Gray et al., 1995). Gray et al. (1995) view both
legitimacy and stakeholder theories being within the framework of political economy theory, which insists that the domain
of economics cannot be studied in isolation from the political, social and institutional considerations. This explanation also is
consistent with Holder-Webb et al. (2009) who suggest that CSR disclosures are undertaken to build or maintain legitimacy
with the social environment. Legitimacy exists when the firm’s value system is congruent with that of its stakeholders
(Lindblom, 1994).
Greenwashing is a legitimation strategy that occurs when firms voluntarily issue CSR Reports to promote an impression
of legitimate social and environmental values, which may or may not be substantiated (Lindblom, 1994; Neu et al., 1998).
Lindblom (1994) suggests that one path to legitimation is to manipulate stakeholders’ perceptions through association with
legitimatizing symbols, which may include targeted disclosures (Deegan, 2002). For instance, if stakeholders perceive
voluntary CSR Reports to be a symbol of ‘‘good’’ corporate citizenship, then firms would deflect stakeholders’ pressure by
issuing standalone CSR Reports. It follows that firms may voluntarily issue standalone CSR Reports to legitimize their status
with stakeholders, and accrue the benefits of being a ‘‘good’’ corporate citizen even when they have not made any attempt at
actual conformity.8
According to a greenwashing explanation, firms issue standalone CSR Reports to pose as strong corporate citizens even
when they are not (Greer and Bruno, 1996). Greenwashing involves selective disclosure of positive social and environmental
actions resulting in misleading and biased reporting. An example of Greenwashing was presented in Adams (2004) who
5
Firms issue standalone CSR Reports to avoid adverse selection, because in the absence of a positive signal that a firm is a ‘‘good’’ corporate citizen,
stakeholders will assume that a firm is ‘‘bad’’ (Milgrom, 1981).
6
Prior empirical research suggests that proprietary costs vary according to firm size (Cormier and Magnan, 2003).
7
Immediately after the settlement was reached, Nike stopped producing its standalone CSR Report for three years. In 2005, Nike started once again to
voluntarily reissue its standalone CSR Reports, and has been presented as an industry leader due to its extremely high levels of transparency and disclosure
(Murray, 2005).
8
Lindblom (1994) describes four different paths to legitimization used by firms involving a combination of voluntary CSR disclosure and substantive
actions: (1) Change in actions and selectively inform stakeholders of ‘‘new’’ conforming actions, which may or may not involve neutral and unbiased
reporting; (2) No change in actions and unbiased reporting of existing actions; (3) No change in actions, and manipulation of stakeholders’ perceptions
through association with legitimate symbols, which involves misleading reporting; and, (4) No change in actions, but change stakeholders expectations, and
also may involve biased reporting. Only the second strategy involves unbiased reporting, which is consistent with signaling. Three of Lindblom’s (1994)
strategies involve biased or misleading reporting, and are consistent with greenwashing.
L.S. Mahoney et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 24 (2013) 350–359 353
compared a company’s actual environmental performance to its environmental reporting and found very little disclosure of
its negative environmental performance, which was attributed to a firm’s attempt to portray itself as a good corporate
citizen.
Greenwashing occurs when firms are willing to incur costs to voluntary disclose biased and misleading social and
environmental information so that their stakeholders believe that they are ‘‘good’’ (Guidry and Patten, 2010; Cho et al., 2010;
Lyon and Maxwell, 2011). While Greenwashing may not involve false disclosures, it may include those firms that
conveniently exclude damaging disclosures. Some examples of ‘‘advantageous’’ omission in CSR Reports is reported by Belal
and Cooper (2011) who found a number of companies in Bangladesh that were not in compliance with labor-related laws did
not disclose their non-compliance in order to avoid negative publicity and potential restrictions on their activities. Belal and
Cooper (2011) suggest that non-disclosure serves corporate interests and benefits particular stakeholder groups including
management and shareholders. It follows that greenwashing implies that voluntary CSR disclosures do not (necessarily)
correspond with actual social and environmental performance (Cho and Patten, 2007) and can be used to help mediate the
effect of poor environmental performance on environmental reputations (Cho et al., 2010).
Greenwashing suggests that firms with weaker social and environmental performance records acquire a greater benefit
from influencing stakeholders’ perceptions of the firms’ CSR performance than firms with stronger social and environmental
records (Clarkson et al., 2008; Patten, 2002). It follows that we would expect weaker corporate citizens to more likely issue
standalone CSR Reports to manipulate stakeholders’ perceptions of the firms’ social and environmental position than
stronger corporate citizens. This gives rise to our second hypothesis, which is consistent with a greenwashing perspective.
H2. Firms that issue standalone CSR Reports have weaker CSR performance than firms that do not issue standalone CSR
Reports.
3. Methodology
Our method involved obtaining a sample of firms that issue standalone CSR Reports and matching it to similar firms that
do not issue standalone CSR Reports. Our primary sample included those U.S. publicly held firms that issued standalone CSR
Reports in 2006. On the basis of size and industry, we match our primary sample of firms that issue standalone CSR Reports to
a set of comparable U.S. firms that do not.
The list of firms issuing standalone CSR Reports was obtained from CorporateRegister.com. CorporateRegister.com
estimates to have over 90% of the world’s published CSR Reports (CorporateRegister.com, 2011), making it the world’s largest
online directory of CSR Reports. CorporateRegister.com only publishes CSR Reports that contain quantitative data. A total of
230 different US entities issued CSR Reports in 2006. Of these entities, 16 were non-profit or governmental entities and 14
were foreign subsidiaries reducing the sample size to 200 companies. An additional 33 companies were removed (30 private
and 3 public companies) as no CSR performance score was available for them, reducing the sample size to167. Finally, 11
companies were removed due to missing financial data resulting in a final sample size of 156. These 156 public firms were
matched (based on SIC code and Total Assets) to firms that had not filed standalone CSR Reports in 2006 and had a Total CSR
performance score available from KLD, resulting in a combined sample size of 312 firms.
3.2. Measures
calculated by summing the strength performance scores across all categories in each of the seven dimensions for each
company and subtracting the sum of the weaknesses performance scores across the same categories for the seven
dimensions.9
where: i = firm, t = time, Match = 1 if firm issues standalone CSR Report; 0 otherwise, CSR = Total Corporate Social
Responsibility Score, ROA = Return on Assets, Debt-to-equity = Total Debt/Total Equity, Assets = Total Assets in Millions,
Industryk = 1 if industry k; 0 otherwise; k = 1, 2. . . 7 (number of SIC codes minus one), eit are independent, normally
distributed error terms with mean 0 and variance s2.
4. Results
Table 1 shows the means, standard deviations, and correlations for our independent, dependent and control variables for
the entire sample of firms, including both firms that issue standalone CSR Reports and those who do not. The average Total
CSR performance score for the entire sample is .20. The average Total Assets, Debt-to-equity and ROA for the entire sample
is $65,006 million, 3.68 and 5.36, respectively.
The means, standard deviations, and correlations for the sample of firms that issue standalone CSR Reports and for the
sample of firms that do not are shown in Table 2 and Table 3, respectively. Table 2 shows that Total CSR performance score is
.64 for firms who issue standalone CSR Reports. The average Total Assets, Debt-to-equity and ROA for the sample of firms
with standalone CSR Reports are $89,155 million, 5.27 and 6.34, respectively. Table 3 shows that Total CSR performance
score is 1.05 for firms that do not issue standalone CSR Reports. The average Total Assets, Debt-to-equity and ROA is
$40,856 million, 2.09 and 4.37, respectively. Total CSR performance is significantly related to ROA at p < .05 for firms that
issue standalone CSR Reports. For firms that do not issue standalone CSR Reports, Total CSR performance is significantly
related to Total Assets. Thus, firms that issue standalone CSR Reports have a higher Total CSR performance than firms that do
not issue standalone CSR Reports.
9
Total CSR Performance scores for the sample ranged from a low of 10 to a high of 14.
10
In supplemental analyses, we used various measures of firm size taken from previous studies: total sales and total assets (Waddock and Graves, 1997);
total sales (Pinkston and Carroll, 1993); and log of total sales (Goll and Rasheed, 2004; Ruf et al., 2001).
L.S. Mahoney et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 24 (2013) 350–359 355
Table 1
Correlations with total CSR performance for combined sample.
** p < .05.
* p < .01.
Table 2
Correlations with total CSR performance for firms that issue standalone CSR reports.
Table 3
Correlations with total CSR performance for firms who do not issue standalone CSR reports.
Hypothesis 1 is that firms that issue standalone CSR Reports have stronger CSR performance than firms who do not issue
standalone CSR Reports, and in direct contrast is H2 that states firms that issue standalone CSR Reports have weaker CSR
performance than firms who do not issue these reports. Table 4 presents the results of the independent t-tests comparing
Total CSR performance scores for firms that issue standalone CSR Reports to those who do not. Table 4 shows that Total CSR
performance is significantly higher (p < .01) for firms that issue standalone CSR Reports than for those that do not issue
standalone CSR Reports. These results support H1 and the signaling explanation that firms who issue standalone CSR Reports
have stronger CSR performance. Table 4 does not provide support for H2 and the greenwashing explanation.
Hypothesis 1 and 2 were also tested using logistic regression where the dependent variable was whether or not a firm
issued a standalone CSR Report. Table 5 reports the results of this logistic regression. Table 5 shows a significant positive
association between Total CSR performance and the issuing of standalone CSR Reports at p < .01 level, after controlling for
ROA, Debt-to-equity, Total Assets and Industry. Thus firms that issue standalone CSR Reports have significantly higher CSR
performance scores. These results are consistent with H1, the signaling explanation.
In order to assess the robustness of the results, we performed several additional tests of the models presented in the
paper. We evaluated whether our analysis was biased due to the inclusion of firms in our ‘‘matched sample’’ that had
previously issued standalone CSR Reports but were no longer doing so. A sensitivity analysis was considered on a sample of
companies where firms were removed from the original sample that had issued standalone CSR Reports anytime during the
previous three years, along with the company to which they were matched. The resulting sample was 135 firms that were
not currently issuing standalone CSR reports and had not previously issued these reports in the prior three years and the 135
Table 4
Results of independent T-tests of CSR means.
Standalone reporting firms CSR Non standalone reporting firms CSR T Statistic
Table 5
Logistic regression between the decision to issue standalone CSR reports and CSR performance scores.
Independent
Total CSR performance 0.143 (3.72)*
Control
2005 ROA 0.046 (1.90)
2005 Debt-to-equity 0.041 (1.31)
2005 Total assets 0.000 (1.97)**
Pseudo R square .084
N 312
Chi2 36.51*
Table 6
Results of logistic regression of GRI used in standalone CSR reports.
Independent
Total CSR performance 0.123 (2.25)**
Control
2005 ROA 0.070 (1.27)
2005 Debt-to-equity 0.063 (0.87)
2005 Total assets 0.000 (2.29)**
Pseudo R square .175
N 133
Chi2 31.13*
companies there were matched too, resulting in a total sample size of 270 firms. Our independent t-test shows that average
Total CSR performance scores (0.67) of firms that issued stand-alone CSR was significantly higher than Total CSR
performance scores (1.19) of firms that did not issue these reports at p < .01. Additionally, our revised logistic regressions
results were consistent with our prior reported results as Total CSR performance scores were significantly related at p < .01
level to the issuance of standalone CSR Reports. Thus, we conclude that the prior issuance of standalone CSR Reports did not
affect our results as presented.
We extended our supplementary analysis to consider firms that choose to follow the Global Reporting Initiative (GRI)
reporting framework in their standalone CSR Reports. The GRI is widely acknowledged as the leader in the development of
sustainability reporting guidelines (Ballou et al., 2006; Woods, 2003). The GRI frameworks contain principles and indicators
that firms use to benchmark social and environmental performance with respect to laws, norms, codes, performance
standards and voluntary initiatives (GRI, 2008). Extending our reasoning to GRI firms, we expect that the 53 firms that adopt
GRI standards in their standalone CSR Reports have higher CSR performance scores when compared to those 103 reporting
firms that do not adopt GRI standards.
Table 6 shows the results of our logistic regression equation that compares Total CSR performance between firms that
follow GRI standards and those that do not, while controlling for profitability leverage and size variables. Total CSR
performance is significant at p < .05, which means that firms that adopt GRI standards in their standalone CSR Report have
higher CSR performance scores than firms that do not follow GRI standards in their standalone CSR Reports.11
Our final supplemental analysis considers different operationalizations of firm size. Following previous studies, firm size
was measured as Total Sales and Total Assets (Waddock and Graves, 1997); Total Sales (Pinkston and Carroll, 1993); and log
of Total Sales (Goll and Rasheed, 2004; Ruf et al., 2001). Using these different measures, our findings did not change.
5. Discussion
The purpose of our research is to provide insight into the motivations behind why firms choose to issue voluntary
standalone CSR Reports. We consider whether voluntary standalone CSR Reports are used as a signal of superior social and
11
Sample size was reduced to 133 as logic regression automatically dropped observations for certain SIC codes that predicted failure or success perfectly.
When these SIC codes were dropped from the logistic regression to test the entire sample of 156 firms, Total CSR performance was still significantly
positively associated with the decision to follow GRI standards at p < .05.
L.S. Mahoney et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 24 (2013) 350–359 357
environmental performance or to manipulate stakeholders’ perceptions of a firm’s pro social and environmental actions
through greenwashing (Clarkson et al., 2008). The first explanation, signaling, suggests firms with ‘‘good’’ social and
environmental records will be more likely to issue standalone CSR Reports as compared to those without ‘‘good’’ social and
environmental records. The second explanation, greenwashing suggests that standalone CSR Reports are published primarily
to influence stakeholders’ perceptions that firms are concerned with social and environmental issues. Greenwashing
suggests that firms use standalone CSR Reports to pose as ‘‘good’’ corporate citizens even when they are not, through biased
reporting tending to be overly positive about their pro-social and environmental actions, and neglecting or avoiding the
reporting of negative social and environmental actions (Lindblom, 1994; Adams et al., 1995; Adams, 2004).
Greenwashing may help explain why companies with ‘‘bad’’ social and environmental activities voluntarily release their
social and environmental activities in a positive light (Adams, 2004) and fail to disclose negative environmental performance
or disclose it in less detail (Adams et al., 1995; Belal and Cooper, 2011) to protect their self-interests. The Bourgeois variant of
political economy theory argues that environmental disclosures are a response to pressure from various stakeholders (Gray
et al., 1995; Branco and Rodrigues, 2007; Ramanathan, 1976). Following this argument, Williams (1999) suggests that if a
firm is perceived to be engaging in negative social actions, it will lose society’s endorsement and likely fail, and to maintain
right standing in society, firms will voluntarily report on their social and environmental activities, and will ‘‘greenwash’’ poor
environmental performance by emphasizing positive social actions and failing to disclose poor performance (Adams et al.,
1995; Belal and Cooper, 2011).
We compare the CSR performance scores of firms that issue CSR reports to those firms that do not issue CSR reports to
provide insight into these explanations. We control for firm size, leverage, profitability, and industry (Cormier and Magnan,
2003). We find that U.S. firms that voluntarily issue standalone CSR Reports generally have higher CSR performance scores,
which supports the signaling theory explanation that voluntary CSR Reports are used primarily by U.S. firms with good social
and environmental records so that stakeholders are aware of their ‘‘good’’ records.
Our results show that U.S. firms issuing standalone CSR Reports are in fact better corporate citizens than firms that do not
issue standalone CSR Reports, which is consistent with a signaling theory perspective. Signaling theory suggests that ‘‘good’’
corporate citizens issue standalone CSR Reports to eliminate information asymmetries that may be preventing them from
reaping the benefits of their actions. Signaling suggests that firms use standalone CSR Reports as a signal of their superior
commitment to CSR, and ‘‘good’’ firms are prepared to undertake the ‘‘costs’’ of voluntary CSR reporting to obtain the benefit
conferred upon ‘‘good’’ corporate citizens.
Our results have several implications. First our findings imply that U.S. firms issue standalone CSR Reports because
stakeholders cannot distinguish between ‘‘good’’ and ‘‘bad’’ corporate citizens (in the absence of mandatory disclosure).
‘‘Good’’ corporate citizens use voluntary standalone CSR Reports to ensure that they obtain the positive benefits bestowed on
‘‘good’’ corporate citizens by society. It follows that disclosures in voluntary CSR reports cannot be extrapolated or
considered to be representative of the entire population of U.S. firms, as they primarily reflect ‘‘good’’ social and
environmental firms that are ensuring that they gain recognition from society for their positive actions. Thus, our results
support Adams (2004) suggestion that mandatory disclosure in the U.S. is needed to obtain an unbiased understanding of
social and environmental performance.
Secondly, our results highlight the importance of activist stakeholders and stakeholder pressure for social and
environmental reporting, as our findings suggest that, in the absence of mandated disclosure, it is critical that society
rewards ‘‘good’’ corporate citizens for their positive social and environmental policies and actions. Stakeholder pressure can
motivate companies to adopt various environmental practices (Buysse and Verbeke, 2003; Eesley and Lenox, 2006; Deegan
and Blomquist, 2006). For example, Deegan and Blomquist (2006) find that a stakeholder group, WWF-Australia, influenced
the Australian minerals industry to change its environmental reporting by developing an environmental reporting scorecard.
The pressure the WWF-Australia was able to exert through its environmental scorecard led to changes in environmental
disclosures and changes in the Australian environmental code for the minerals industry.
Our findings reinforce an important implication of Lyon and Maxwell’s (2011) study that stakeholders must be active and
willing to punish firms that inappropriately report their voluntary disclosures of social and environmental activities. Thus,
our findings expose that without mandated disclosure, full transparency regarding firms’ social and environmental actions is
dependent upon stakeholder pressure.
Third, another implication following from our findings is that stakeholder pressure for firms to take positive social and
environmental actions may be less in the U.S. than in other countries across the globe. Given two-thirds of non-reporting
G250 companies are based in the U.S. (KPMG, 2011a,b), our findings underscore that stakeholder pressure for transparent
reporting of social and environmental performance may not be as prevalent in the U.S. as compared to other countries (e.g.,
Australia, see Deegan and Blomquist, 2006). Future research is needed to consider the factors that may account for the
differences and the ‘‘lag’’ between voluntary standalone CSR Reports in U.S. firms as compared to other national contexts.
Finally, our supplemental analysis shows that firms that voluntarily issue CSR Reports that follow GRI guidelines also use
GRI guidelines to signal their superior corporate citizenry over firms that do not follow these guidelines. Thus, our findings
reinforce claims by KPMG International (2008, p. 10) that ‘‘corporate responsibility reporting is building value for companies
in many ways’’ and ‘‘enhancing reputation by providing truthful and robust information on tough issues’’.
Like all research, ours has limitations associated with the measures, methodology and sample size. First, the results of our
study cannot be extended beyond the U.S. Also, we rely on the use of the KLD scores as a proxy for actual CSR performance,
although the KLD, like all quantitative measures, has its inherent limitations (see Chatterji and Levine, 2006; Chatterji et al.,
358 L.S. Mahoney et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 24 (2013) 350–359
2009; Schreck, 2011). Furthermore, our analysis was limited to considering only whether or not firms issue standalone CSR
Reports. We did not measure or consider the variation in quality of the CSR Reports, although we are aware that there may be
variation in the quality of CSR Reports issued by a firm. Future research that integrates qualitative and quantitative
approaches to CSR research is needed to explore quality differences across reports, and to build further upon our
understanding of the attributes of firms that voluntarily issue CSR Reports. For example, future research may consider the
quality of the CSR Report and the extent to which the information contained in the CSR Report is new information or is
information that is already publicly available.
References
Adams CA. The ethical, social, and environmental reporting-performance portrayal gap. Accounting Auditing and Accountability Journal 2004;17(5):731–57.
Adams CA, Coutts A, Harte G. Corporate equal opportunities (non-) disclosures. British Accounting Review 1995;27:87–108.
Albinger HS, Freeman SJ. Corporate social performance and attractiveness as an employer to different job seeking populations. Journal of Business Ethics
2000;28(3):243–53.
Al-Tuwaijri S, Christensen T, Hughes K. The relations among environmental disclosure, environmental performance, and economic performance: a simultaneous
equations approach. Accounting Organizations and Society 2004;29(5–6):447–71.
Ballou B, Heitger D, Landes CE. The future of corporate sustainability reporting. Journal of Accountancy 2006;202(6):65–74.
Belal AR, Cooper S. The absence of corporate social responsibility reporting in Bangladesh. Critical Perspectives on Accounting 2011;22(7):654–67.
Berthelot S, Cormier D, Magnan M. Environmental disclosure research: review and synthesis. Journal of Accounting Literature 2003;22:1–44.
Brammer S, Pavelin S. Voluntary social disclosures by large UK companies. Business Ethics A European Review 2004;13(2–3):86–99.
Branco MC, Rodrigues LL. Issues in corporate social and environmental reporting research: an overview. Issues in Social and Environmental Accounting
2007;1(1):72–90.
Burke L, Logsdon JM, Mitchell W, Reiner M, Vogel D. Corporate community involvement in the San Francisco Bay area. California Management Review
1986;18(3):122–41.
Buysse K, Verbeke A. Proactive environmental strategies: a stakeholder management perspective. Strategic Management Journal 2003;24:453–70.
Chatterji AK, Levine D. Breaking down the wall of codes: evaluating non-financial performance measurement. California Management Review 2006;48(2):29–51.
Chatterji AK, Levine D, Toffel MW. How well do social scores actually measure corporate social responsibility? Journal of Economics and Management Strategy
2009;18(1):125–69.
Cho C, Patten M. The role of environmental disclosures as tools of legitimacy: a research note. Accounting Organizations and Society 2007;32(7–8):639–47.
Cho C, Roberts R, Patten D. The language of US corporate environmental disclosure. Accounting Organizations and Society 2010;35(4):431–43.
Clarkson P, Li Y, Richardson G, Vasvari F. Revisiting the relation between environmental performance and environmental disclosure: an empirical analysis.
Accounting Organizations and Society 2008;33(4–5):303–27.
Clarkson P, Li Y, Richardson G, Vasvari F. Does it really pay to be green? Determinants and consequences of proactive environmental strategies Journal of
Accounting and Public Policy 2011a;30(2):122–44.
Clarkson P, Overell M, Chapple L. Environmental reporting and its relation to corporate environmental performance. Abacus 2011b;47(1):27–60.
Cormier D, Gordon I, Magnan M. Corporate environmental disclosure: contrasting management’s perceptions with reality. Journal of Business Ethics
2004;49(2):143–65.
Cormier D, Magnan M. Environmental reporting management: a continental European perspective. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 2003;2:43–62.
CorporateRegister.com, Which companies and reports feature in the GRI register? Retrieved Sept. 22, 2011 from http://www.corporat3434eregister.com/
aboutreports.html; 2011.
Dawkins C, Fraas J. Coming clean: the impact of environmental performance and visibility on corporate climate change disclosure. Journal of Business Ethics
2011;100(2):303–22.
Deegan C. The legitimizing effect of social and environmental disclosures—a theoretical foundation. Accounting Auditing & Accountability Journal
2002;15(3):282–311.
Deegan C, Blomquist C. Stakeholder influence on corporate reporting: an exploration of the interaction between WWF-Australia and the Australian minerals
industry. Accounting Organizations and Society 2006;3(1):343–72.
Dilling PFA. Sustainability reporting in a global context: what are the characteristics of corporations that provide high quality sustainability reports—an empirical
analysis. International Business & Economics Research Journal 2009;9(1):19–30.
Dye R. Disclosure of non-proprietary information. Journal of Accounting Research 1985;23(1):123–45.
Eesley C, Lenox MJ. Firms responses to secondary stakeholder action. Strategic Management Journal 2006;27:765–81.
Global Reporting Initiative, About GRI. Retrieved on November 1, 2008 from http://www.globalreporting.org/AboutGRI/WhatWeDo/; 2008.
Goll I, Rasheed AA. The mode score effect of environmental munificence and dynamism on the relationship between discretionary social responsibility and firm
performance. Journal of Business Ethics 2004;49(1):41–54.
Graves SB, Waddock SA. Institutional owners and corporate social performance. Academy of Management Journal 1994;37(4):1034–46.
Gray R, Kouhy R, Lavers S. Corporate social and environmental reporting: a review of the literature and a longitudinal study of UK disclosure. Accounting Auditing
and Accountability Journal 1995;8(2):47–77.
Greening DW, Turban DB. Corporate social performance as a competitive advantage in attracting a quality workforce. Business and Society 2000;39(3):254–80.
Greer J, Bruno K. Greenwash the reality behind corporate environmentalism. Penang, Malyasia: Third World Network and New York: the Apex Press; 1996.
Guidry R, Patten D. Market reactions to the first-time issuance of corporate sustainability reports: evidence that quality matters. Sustainability Accounting
Management and Policy Journal 2010;1(1):33–50.
Gugerty MK. Signaling virtue, voluntary accountability programs among nonprofit organizations. Policy Sciences 2009;42:243–73.
Healy P, Palepu KG. Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure, and the capital markets: a review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting &
Economics 2001;31(1-3):405–40.
Hillman AJ, Keim GD. Shareholder value, stakeholder management, and social issues: what’s the bottom line? Strategic Management Journal 2001;22(2):125–39.
Holder-Webb L, Cohen JR, Nath L, Wood D. The supply of corporate social responsibility disclosures among U.S. firms. Journal of Business Ethics 2009;84:497–527.
Johnson RA, Greening DW. The effects of corporate governance and institutional ownership types on corporate social performance. Academy of Management
Journal 1999;42(5):564–76.
KPMG. KPMG International survey of corporate responsibility reporting; 2008.
KPMG Global Sustainability Services and University of Amsterdam: Amsterdam; 2008.
KPMG, KPMG International survey of corporate responsibility reporting; 2011.
KPMG International Cooperative, Switzerland; 2011.
Li Y, Richardson C, Thornton D. Corporate disclosure of environmental liability information: theory and evidence. Contemporary Accounting Research
1997;14(3):435–73.
Lindblom CK. The implications of organizational legitimacy for corporate social performance and disclosure. In: Paper presented at the Critical Perspectives on
Accounting Conference. New York; 1994.
Lizzeri A. Information revelation and certification intermediaries. Journal of Economics 1999;30(2):214–31.
Lyon T, Maxwell J. Greenwash Corporate environmental disclosure under threat of audit. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 2011;20(1):3–41.
L.S. Mahoney et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 24 (2013) 350–359 359
Mahoney L, Roberts R. Corporate social performance, financial performance and institutional ownership in Canadian firms. Accounting Forum 2007;31(3):233–
53.
Marin L, Ruiz S, Rubio A. The role of identity salience in the effects of corporate social responsibility on consumer behavior. Journal of Business Ethics
2009;84(1):65–78.
McGuire JB, Dow S, Argheyd K. CEO incentives and corporate social performance. Journal of Business Ethics 2003;45:341–59.
Milgrom P. Good news and bad news: representation theorems and applications. Bell Journal of Economics 1981;12(2):380–91.
Murray S. Nike makes the step to transparency. Financial Times 2005; April 12.
Neu D, Warsame H, Pedwell K. Managing public impressions: environmental disclosures in Annual Reports. Accounting Organizations and Society
1998;23(3):265–82.
Nike-Kasky Case: 27. Cal 4th 939, 45 P.3d 243 119 Cal Pptr 2 296; 2002.
Orlitzky M. Corporate social performance and financial performance: a research synthesis. In: Crane A, McWilliams A, Matten D, Moon J, Siegel D, editors. The
Oxford handbook of corporate social responsibility. New York: Oxford University Press; 2008. p. 112–34.
Patten DM. The relation between environmental performance and environmental disclosure: a research note. Accounting Organizations and Society
2002;27(8):763–73.
Pinkston TS, Carroll AB. An investigation of the relationship between organizational size and corporate social performance. IABS Proceedings 1993;109–14.
Prado-Lorenzo J, Garcia-Sanchez. I. The role of the board of directors in disseminating relevant information on greenhouse gases. Journal of Business Ethics
2010;97(3):391–424.
Ramanathan KV. Toward a theory of corporate social accounting. Accounting Review 1976;51(3):516–28.
Roberts RW. Determinants of corporate social responsibility disclosure: an application of stakeholder theory. Accounting Organization and Society
1992;17(6):595–612.
Ruf B, Muralidhar K, Brown RM, Janney J, Paul K. An empirical investigation of the relationship between change in corporate social performance and financial
performance: a stakeholder theory perspective. Journal of Business Ethics 2001;32(2):143–56.
Sen S, Bhattacharya CB, Korschun D. The role of corporate social responsibility in strengthening multiple stakeholder relationships: a field experiment. Journal of
the Academy of Marketing Science 2006;34(2):158–66.
Schreck P. Reviewing the business case for corporate social responsibility: new evidence and analysis. Journal of Business Ethics 2011;103(2):167–88.
Sikka P. Accounting for human rights: the challenge of globalization and foreign investment agreements. Critical Perspectives on Accounting 2011;22(8):811–27.
Sinclair-Desgagne B, Gozlan E. A theory of environmental risk disclosure. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 2003;45:377–93.
Thorne L, Mahoney L, Bobek D. A comparison of the association between corporate social responsibility and executive compensation: U.S. versus Canada. Research
on Professional Responsibility and Ethics in Accounting 2009;14:26–36.
Turban DB, Greening DW. Corporate social performance and organizational attractiveness to prospective employees. Academy of Management Journal
1997;40(3):658–72.
Ullmann A. Data in search of a theory: a critical examination of the relationships among social performance, social disclosure, and economic performance of U.S.
firms. Academy of Management Review 1985;10(3):540–57.
Verrecchia R. Discretionary Disclosure Journal of Accounting and Economics 1983;5(3):179–94.
Waddock SA, Graves SB. Industry performance and investment in R&D and capital goods. Journal of High Technology Management Research 1994;5(1):1–17.
Waddock SA, Graves SB. Attraction or repulsion: how institutional owners react to corporate social performance. Management Research News 1995;18(2):20–4.
Waddock SA, Graves SB. The corporate social performance-financial performance link. Strategic Management Journal 1997;18(4):303–19.
Williams SM. Voluntary environmental and social accounting disclosure practices in the Asia-Pacific region: an international empirical test of political economy
theory. The International Journal of Accounting 1999;34(2):209–38.
Woods M. The global reporting initiative. The CPA Journal 2003;73(6):60–5.