Serendipity in Entrepreneurship: Nicholas Dew
Serendipity in Entrepreneurship: Nicholas Dew
Serendipity in Entrepreneurship: Nicholas Dew
Serendipity in Entrepreneurship
Nicholas Dew
Abstract
Nicholas Dew This paper addresses the concept of serendipity in entrepreneurship, defined as search
Naval Postgraduate leading to unintended discovery. It conceptually delineates serendipity, showing how it is
School, Monterey, related to the entrepreneurship literature on prior knowledge and systematic search. The
USA paper also discusses how serendipitous entrepreneurship relates to some aspects of evo-
lutionary theory, socio-economic institutions, and social psychology. It is suggested that
serendipity may be a quite prevalent feature of entrepreneurship and thus has implications
for both research and practice.
Introduction
‘Entrepreneurship is a series of random collisions. Sure, you start with a plan and follow
it systematically. But even though you start out in the alternative energy business, you
are just as likely to end up in real estate development.’ (David A. Padwa, founder of
Agrigenetics Corp., quoted by Silver 1985: 16)
As well as the idea of serendipity, there is also the idea of pseudo serendipity, which
refers to a situation in which someone is looking for something in particular, but the
route by which they discover it is accidental and unanticipated. For instance, Charles
Goodyear made many attempts to stabilize natural rubber so that it could be made
useful, but it was only when he accidentally allowed a mixture of rubber and sulfur
to touch a hot stove that he discovered vulcanization (Roberts 1989: 54). Similarly,
Alfred Nobel had experimented extensively with ways of taming nitroglycerin, but
it was an accidentally cut finger that prompted him to experiment with a mixture of
collodion (commonly applied to wounds in Nobel’s day) and nitroglycerin, a com-
bination that was later patented as blasting gelatin, and is still used to this day.
There are diverse examples of serendipity in entrepreneurship. The founding
of Staples office supply retail chain provides one example of the serendipitous
discovery of an underserved market (Sarasvathy 2007). On the Thursday before
the Fourth of July weekend in 1985, Thomas Stemberg, who had recently lost
his job as division manager for a supermarket chain, was working on a business
plan for starting a new chain, when he ran out of the printer ribbon for his Apple
Imagewriter. When he went out to purchase a new ribbon, he simply could not
get it. Either stationery stores had closed early for the weekend, or the ones that
were open did not carry the ribbon. ‘It dawned on me’, he said in an interview
with CNN’s Stuart Varney, ‘that not only could small entrepreneurs not get sta-
tionery at the rate of bigger companies, sometimes they couldn’t get it at all.’ He
still had no ribbon to finish his business plan over the weekend, but he had found
the new venture he actually wanted to start in that contingency.
Honda’s discovery of a market for small motorcycles in the USA has also been
cited in the literature as an example of serendipity (Denrell et al. 2003; Van Andei
1994). In the late 1950s Honda sought to introduce large motorcycles into the US
market in competition with Harley Davidson and European importers. Its strategy
was based on its analysis of the US market, where big bikes were very popular.
However, members of Honda’s import staff used small 50cc bikes for their own
transport needs. According to Kihachiro Kawashima, Honda’s US president:
‘We used the 50s ourselves to ride around Los Angeles. They attracted a lot of attention.
One day we had a call from a Sears buyer … surprisingly, the retailers who wanted to sell
them weren’t motorcycle dealers, they were sporting goods stores.’ (Pascale 1984: 55)
Thus Honda serendipitously discovered a latent market for small motorcycles in the
USA, in a classic example of searching for one opportunity and discovering another
through a contingent interaction — in this case, with a Sears buyer — what
Mintzberg (1996) has described as being ‘pleasantly surprised’ by a contingency.
Serendipity also sometimes occurs in the discovery of new combinations of fac-
tors of production (Schumpeter 1934). An example of this can be found in the his-
tory of J. R. Simplot, the potato magnate. Simplot built a business storing and sorting
potatoes and onions during the Great Depression. Silver (1985) recounts that:
‘in the spring of 1940, Jack Simplot decided to drive to Berkeley, California, to find out why
an onion exporter there had run up a bill of $8,400 for cull (or reject) onions without pay-
ing. … The girl in the office said the boss wasn’t in. Fine, said J. R., he would wait until the
man arrived.
‘Two hours later, at ten o’clock, a bearded old man walked in. Assuming this was his
debtor, Simplot accosted him. But he turned out to be a man named Sokol, inquiring why
he was not getting his due deliveries of onion flakes and powder. They sat together until
noon, but still the exporter failed to arrive.
‘As the noon hour passed, Simplot was suddenly struck with an idea. He asked the
bewhiskered old trader to a fateful lunch at the Berkeley Hotel. “You want onion pow-
der and flakes,” said J. R., “I’ve got onions. I’ll dry ‘em and make powder and flakes
in Idaho.”’
Table 1.
Examples of Domains and overlaps Examples
Domains and
Overlaps in Figure 1 Contingency/accident J. R. Simplot’s chance meeting with Sokol (Silver 1985);
Peter Hodgson’s chance attendance of a party where kids
happened to be playing with Silly Putty as a toy (Van Andei 1994).
Prior knowledge Knowledge of technologies, markets, and customer needs learned
from working with users in their prior jobs. Bhidé (1996) found
that over 50% of HBS entrepreneurs he sampled started their firms
based on specific insights gained in prior employment.
Search activity Thomas Edison searched 6000 vegetable growths and ‘ransacked
the world’ for a suitable filament for his most important innovation:
the electric light bulb (Weitzman 1998).
Systematic exploration An entrepreneur’s periodic scrutiny of their storehouse of previously
shelved venture ideas; for firms, periodic scrutiny of previously
shelved technologies, patents, etc. (Wilson and Hlavacek 1984).
Spontaneous recognition Opportunities for commercializing. MIT’s 3DP technology was
spontaneously recognized by eight different entrepreneurs
(Shane 2000).
Pre-discovery Corning’s pre-discovery of technology for optical fibers
(Cattani 2006).
Serendipity Thomas Stemberg’s founding of Staples office supply retail chain
(Sarasvathy 2007).
Domain of Pre-discovery
Systematic Search – Hunch that something has
been discovered but lack of
Exploration pre-existing knowledge to
– Discovery of opportunities make an on-the-spot
is based on purposefully evaluation
searching knowledge
corridors
Domain of
Domain of
Prior
Contingency
Knowledge
Spontaneous
Recognition
– Sheer/utter surprise
Systematic Exploration
Spontaneous Recognition
Pre-discovery
Figure 1 also reveals one space of opportunity discovery that has been less
studied in the literature. This is the space where contingency and search overlap,
but without prior knowledge (sagacity). In this space, unanticipated opportuni-
ties are ‘pre-discovered’, i.e. an entrepreneur may suspect that they have dis-
covered an opportunity but they lack the pre-existing knowledge that is needed
in order to immediately recognize what has been discovered. For example, peni-
cillin had been ‘pre-discovered’ by many bacteriologists who had observed the
growth of one bacterium inhibiting the growth of another. However, these indi-
viduals lacked the prior knowledge that was needed in order to make an on-the-
spot evaluation of what they had found (Merton and Barber 2004: 176).
In the literature on technology evolution, recent empirical research by Cattani
(2006) highlights that pre-discoveries are quite commonplace. Cattani uses the
term ‘pre-adaptation’ to describe some technology discoveries firms make: ‘that
part of a firm’s technological knowledge base that is accumulated without antic-
ipation of subsequent uses (foresight), but might later prove to be functionally
“pre-adapted” (i.e., valuable) for alternative, as yet unknown, applications’
(Cattani 2006: 286). One firm Cattani studied was Corning, where the technolo-
gies for optical fibers and flat-panel display glass were both pre-discovered
years before the complementary knowledge necessary to commercialize them
was developed. As emphasized by Garud and Nayyar (1994) in their framework,
such discoveries may be systematically explored for their knowledge character-
istics, and relevant knowledge about them may be stored for potential reactiva-
tion, synthesis, and use in the future.3
Serendipity
For the purposes of this paper, I shall define pure luck as some kind of favorable
contingency or chance happening (i.e. an event completely beyond the entrepre-
neur’s control) that impacts the entrepreneur in a positive way. Luck is some-
thing that (sometimes) happens to you. It does not presuppose any search
activity or prior knowledge on the part of the entrepreneur. Also, by contrast with
luck, the role of contingencies in serendipity can come in more or less fortunate
forms, such that unlucky incidents may sometimes constitute the contingent
component of serendipity.
Having thus defined a framework in which serendipity can be understood as
an inclusive element of entrepreneurial opportunity, it may help to place this
framework in a broader context in which entrepreneurial discovery and creation
occur. To do this, I next turn to examining serendipity in an evolutionary and
institution-rich context. What emerges from this analysis is the sense that
serendipity occupies an important place in some widely used and powerful ideas
about social and economic dynamics.
Human systems are complex and evolving, creatively open-ended, and subject to
several types of nonlinear behavior (Buchanan and Vanberg, 1990; Prigogine and
Stengers 1984). Dooley and Van de Ven (1999) highlight four patterns in such
dynamics (periodic, chaotic, white noise, or pink noise) which suggest different
underlying generative mechanisms. Their analysis points to differences in the
causes of complex behavior in evolving systems, and the necessity of using dif-
ferent process theories to understand and explain them. For some types of sys-
tems, seemingly innocuous and improbable serendipities may have far-reaching
consequences because the system sometimes amplifies small events into large
effects (Taleb 2007). That things could have turned out very differently in the face
of equally plausible serendipities, or without the surprises of serendipity, is a fact
that we will inevitably have to admit. In other types of systems, the vast majority
of serendipities may merely be ‘lost’ events that, in effect, are swallowed up by
other processes, eventually becoming errors of omission — just one more micro-
scopic element in the cloudy, confusing human comedy. These are the serendipi-
ties that went sufficiently unattended to in the flow of human experience that they
had no meaningful impact on the shape of future social artifacts (Garud and
Karnoe 2001). Indeed, because all human descriptions of events depend on social
processes that shape patterns of noticing and inattentiveness (Weick 1979), it is
also possible that the fraction of serendipities that we (collectively) pay attention
to are merely those few mindfully noted events that have been selected — perhaps
retrospectively — for their meaningfulness. This is to say, that the concept of
serendipity may sometimes be a useful tool for helping us generate good entre-
preneurial stories out of vaguely understood, highly complex situations.
Yet, serendipity is not just a product of our mental limitations, which mask
underlying processes that are deterministic in nature. Consistent with complex
Few institutional thinkers have shown such a clear appreciation of the role of
serendipity and entrepreneurship as Hayek (1960). Hayek didn’t use the term
‘serendipity’ but he was clearly thinking about something very similar in the
following passage:
‘Humiliating to human pride as the insight may be, we must recognize that we owe the
advance and even the preservation of civilization to a maximum of opportunity for acci-
dents to happen.’ (Hayek, 1960: 29)
‘If there were omniscient men, if we could know not only all that affects the achievement
of our present wishes but also our future wants and desires, there would be little case for
liberty … Liberty is essential to leave room for the unforeseeable and unpredictable; we
want it because we have learned to expect from it the opportunity of realizing many of
our aims.’ (Hayek 1960: 29)
Important implications follow from this argument for the design (whether delib-
erate or evolutionary) of institutional frameworks that best leverage serendipities.
First, individual entrepreneurs must allow enough freedom in their own plans that
they might leverage serendipities. Relentless predefinition of entrepreneurial
ventures, either in the form of business planning or ‘vision’, restricts the entre-
preneur’s opportunity to harness serendipity (contra Witt 2007). Next, the institu-
tional constraints imposed by organizations on employees also need careful
examination so that employees are allowed sufficient autonomy to pursue
serendipitously discovered opportunities (Tsoukas 1996). In this regard, Hayek’s
arguments for freedom are just as relevant to private institutions as they are for
public ones (see, for example, Schlender 1992 on Sony’s practices). Furthermore,
institutions vary in how well they encourage the retention of knowledge that
might fund future serendipitous events. As noted by Garud et al. (1997: 348):
‘Institutions are not mechanisms to sanction individuals for “failed” efforts, but
are devices for the retention of knowledge from “experiments”.’ Institutions that
support the retention of prior knowledge help access (future, possible) serendipi-
ties. Thus, organizations that value serendipity are motivated to take a different
approach to ‘failure’ and ‘waste’, one that recognizes the option value inherent in
establishing a stock of prior knowledge, even when that is a product of creative
endeavors that ostensibly went ‘wrong’ (Garud et al. 1997).
Serendipity — which might be thought of as a fancy word for ‘chance and smart
fellows’ (Merton and Barber 2004: 169) — thus has popular appeal precisely
because it is an equalizing factor that enables people to vicariously imagine them-
selves as the scientist, or entrepreneur, who discovers or creates the next big thing.
This social psychology might be traced to notions of fairness (Rawls 1971),
i.e. that whereas the lottery of birth may have treated people unfairly by gifting
them with unequal skills and motivations, contingency rebalances the scales
somewhat, precisely because of the synergistic interaction required between
contingency, sagacity, and effort that is required to yield serendipity. Accident
may be no use without effort and sagacity, but effort and sagacity are of little
value without being complemented by fortunate accidents which can be lever-
aged — and these may be randomly distributed. The attractiveness of this image
to the public psyche — that even the gifted need their lucky accidents — brings
to mind the image of Greek gods rolling dice to determine human destinies.
Thus, the popular appeal of entrepreneurship may be said to stretch just as far as
the concept of serendipity stretches: the public likes its entrepreneurial heroes
(popular figures like Bill Gates) to be worthy of their wealth by being meritori-
ous; but only insofar as they were also recipients of good fortune. This combi-
nation centers popular perceptions of entrepreneurship squarely on the concept
of serendipity, which serves to keep entrepreneurship both imaginatively acces-
sible and enables its outcomes to be perceived as ‘fair’ in the popular psyche.
Research Implications
Brown (2005) argues that this has been the case in marketing, where everyone is
familiar with serendipities in the history of Velcro, Corn Flakes, Band Aids, and
Post-it-Notes, but there remains a systematic and misleading underestimation of
the total impact of contingency (Pina E Cunha 2004). Marketing scholars have
used extremely sophisticated statistical analyses, ‘But for all this probabilistic
prowess, our concepts hardly capture the sheer capriciousness of commercial
life’ (Brown 2005: 1231). Dooley and Van de Ven further argue that, in organi-
zation studies, the value placed on generalizability of research findings is based
on ‘the assumption that knowledge about commonalities … are of more interest,
or value, than knowledge about differences … Aren’t practicing managers as
interested in what they cannot generalize, as well as what they can?’ (Dooley and
Van de Ven 1999: 370). The same arguments could be made for entrepreneurship
research. And so what remains to be done is to incorporate a systematic role for
contingency the way the literati, historians and biologists have married chance
and necessity in their disciplines. In entrepreneurship, we have to find the right
balance between attending to, and ignoring, contingencies. Serendipity might be
fashioned into a useful concept for exactly this purpose.
The notion that some serendipities become venues for action, and some not, raises
a second implication: when are serendipities more likely to occur and be acted upon
(or not)? As suggested by McMullen and Shepherd (2006: 132), entrepreneurship
involves acting on ‘the possibility that one has identified an opportunity worth pur-
suing’. In the framework presented in this paper, I have made no particular assump-
tions about the ‘hit rate’ of serendipities, i.e. the framework is agnostic about what
entrepreneurs do with their serendipitously discovered opportunities. However,
whether serendipities are acted upon might be important for them to be considered
serendipitous by others.5 Also, it does seem that some entrepreneurs may be more
exposed to serendipity and more likely to develop and create new businesses based
on a serendipitously discovered opportunity (Ardichvili et al. 2003). These points
beg questions about the process of generating and acting on serendipity.
While there are several frameworks one could use to examine this issue, one
attractive framework is effectuation, because it suggests that a predisposition to
flexibly exploit contingency is a central element in the behavior of expert entre-
preneurs (Sarasvathy 2001). According to Sarasvathy (2007: 87):
‘Surprises are usually relegated to error terms in formal models. Instead an effectual logic
suggests they may be the source of opportunities for value creation, but only if someone
seizes upon them in an instrumental fashion and imaginatively combines them with
extant inputs to create new possibilities.’
This study also has implications for several aspects of practitioner behavior.
Many of these implications are not new, but worth reiterating nonetheless. A few
of them are significantly different from existing literature, and worth considera-
tion. First, entrepreneurs might wonder whether they should follow recommen-
dations from the research on systematic exploration (Fiet 2002) or from research
on spontaneous recognition (Shane 2000). The former suggests that entrepre-
neurs should make carefully considered, cost-effective investments in informa-
tion that signals the value of opportunities (Fiet 2002: 3). By contrast, the latter
suggests that ‘people do not discover entrepreneurial opportunities through
search’ and that they can and will discover entrepreneurial opportunities without
actively searching for them (Shane 2000: 451). What should an entrepreneur do?
Serendipitous discovery suggests that both factors, in fact, matter. This is
because an active search process may lead to the recognition of an opportunity,
even though the opportunity is not what the entrepreneur set out to look for. This
perspective allows practitioners to see that there may be a coherent rationale that
unifies these otherwise conflicting perspectives.
A second implication of this paper concerns a long-running debate between com-
mitment and flexibility. Remember that serendipitous discovery suggests that the
entrepreneurial process will involve exploiting accidents and surprises that happen
in the course of developing a venture. This raises the question of the optimal choice
of, and investment in, systems and processes to detect and exploit serendipities. In
a sense, the issue is how much commitment the entrepreneur should make to flex-
ibility (Ghemawat and Costa 1994). This is a conundrum that many academics and
practitioners have stubbed their toes on, so while a solution is clearly beyond the
scope of this paper, a few remarks might be helpful. One is that the entrepreneur
should expect business plans to change; in fact, evolving business plans may be
something to strive for. It is also advisable that, early in the life of a new enterprise,
the entrepreneur should use vision — if it is to be used at all — as a flexible
umbrella under which serendipities may be incorporated (if they occur). The
remarks by David Padwa in the introduction section of this paper stand as a
reminder of how unwise it may be to let deterministic vision constrain the devel-
opment of a new enterprise early in its life. Furthermore, even in very early-stage,
resource-scarce enterprises, entrepreneurs need to find ways of cutting themselves
enough slack to fund some continuing search activity. It has to be remembered that
serendipity is a tripod that relies on some kind of resource-consuming search, as
well as prior knowledge and contingency. Serendipity is not free.
Conclusion
Notes The author would like to thank Raghu Garud and two anonymous Organization Studies reviewers
for their helpful remarks on earlier drafts of this paper. Thanks, as always, also go to my usual cast
of collaborators — you know who you are. The usual disclaimers apply.
1 Throughout the paper, I used the terms ‘accident’ and ‘contingency’ interchangeably.
2 Of course, whether the concept of ‘discovery’ is the most useful language for describing entre-
preneurial opportunity is a matter of debate in the field (McMullen and Shepherd 2006). In this
paper I take no particular position on this issue.
3 Throughout, I assume all opportunities are uncertain to some degree.
4 I would like to acknowledge the wisdom of an anonymous reviewer in pointing out the many dif-
ferent types of complex behaviors exhibited in evolving systems, and the possibility that a deeper
understanding of these different patterns of behavior may indicate that some cases of serendipity
are not, in fact, serendipitous, but may be predictable consequences of the behavior of the system.
5 I am grateful to Raghu Garud for pointing out this issue to me.
References Alsos, Gry A., and Virpi Kaikkonen Baron, Robert A., and Mica D. Ensley
2004 ‘Opportunity recognition and prior 2006 ‘Opportunity recognition as the
knowledge: A study of experienced detection of meaningful patterns:
entrepreneurs’. Paper presented at Evidence from comparisons of novice
the Nordic Conference in Small and experienced entrepreneurs’.
Business Research. Management Science 52/9: 1331–1344.
Alvarez, Sharon A., and Lowell W. Busenitz Bernard, Claude
2001 ‘The entrepreneurship of resource- 1865 An introduction to the study of
based theory.’ Journal of Management experimental medicine, trans.
27: 755–775. H. C. Green, 1957. New York: Dover.
Ardichvili, Alexander, Richard Cardozo, and Bhidé, Amir
Ray Sourav 1996 ‘The road well travelled: A note on
2003 ‘A theory of entrepreneurial the journeys of HBS entrepreneurs’.
opportunity identification and Harvard Business School publication.
development’. Journal of Business
Venturing 18/1: 105–123. Boussouara, Mohammed, and David Deakins
1999 ‘Market-based learning,
Barney, Jay B. entrepreneurship and the high
1997 ‘On flipping coins and making technology small firm’. International
technology choices: Luck as an Journal of Entrepreneurial Behaviour
explanation of technological foresight and Research 5/4: 204–223.
and oversight’ in Technological
innovation: Oversights and Brown, Steven
foresights. Raghu Garud, Praveen R. 2005 ‘Science, serendipity and the
Nayyar and Zur B. Shapira (eds). contemporary marketing condition’.
Cambridge: Cambridge University European Journal of Marketing
Press. 39/11–12: 1229–1234.
Kantorovich, Aharon, and Yuval Neeman Prigogine, IIya, and Isabelle Stengers
1989 ‘Serendipity as a source of 1984 Order out of chaos — man’s new
evolutionary progress in science’. dialogue with nature. Toronto: Bantam.
Studies in History and Philosophy of Rawls, John
Science 20/4: 505–529. 1971 A theory of justice. New York: Belknap.
Kirzner, Israel Roberts, Royston M.
1997 ‘Entrepreneurial discovery and the 1989 Serendipity: Accidental discoveries in
competitive market process: An science. New York: Wiley.
Austrian approach’. Journal of
Economic Literature 35: 60–85. Ronstadt, Robert
1988 ‘The corridor principle’. Journal of
Ma, Hao Business Venturing 3/1: 31–40.
2002 ‘Competitive advantage: What’s luck
got to do with it?’ Management Rorty, Richard
Decision 40/6: 525–536. 1989 Contingency, irony, and solidarity.
Cambridge: Cambridge University
McMullen, Jeff S., and Dean A. Shepherd Press.
2006 ‘Entrepreneurial action and the role of
uncertainty in the theory of the Sarasvathy, Saras D.
entrepreneur’. Academy of 2001 ‘Causation and effectuation: Toward a
Management Review 31/1: 132–152. theoretical shift from economic
inevitability to entrepreneurial
Mandelbrot, Benoit, and Richard L. Hudson contingency’. Academy of
2006 The misbehavior of markets: A fractal Management Review 26/2: 243–263.
view of risk, ruin and reward.
Sarasvathy, Saras D.
New York: Basic Books.
2007 Effectuation: Elements of
March, James G. entrepreneurial expertise.
1982 ‘The technology of foolishness’ in Cheltenham: Routledge.
Ambiguity and choice in Sarasvathy, Sars D., Nicholas Dew, Stuart
organizations. James G. March and Read, and Robert Wiltbank
Johann P. Olsen, 69–81. Bergen: 2008 ‘Designing organizations that design
Universitetsforlaget. environments’. Organization Studies
Merton, Robert K., and Eleanor Barber 29/3: 331–350.
2004 The travels and adventures of Schlender, Brenton R.
serendipity: A study in sociological 1992 ‘How Sony keeps the magic going’.
semantics and the sociology of Fortune, 24 February 1992: 76–82.
science. Princeton: Princeton
University Press. Schumpeter, Joseph A.
1934 The theory of economic development.
Mintzberg, Henry Oxford: Oxford University Press.
1996 ‘Learning 1, planning 0’. California
Management Review 38/4: 92–93. Scitovsky, Tibor
1976 The joyless economy: An inquiry into
Mintzberg, Henry, and James A. Waters human satisfaction and consumer
1982 ‘Tracking strategy in an dissatisfaction. Oxford: Oxford
entrepreneurial firm’. Academy of University Press.
Management Journal 25/3: 465–499.
Shane, Scott
Obstfeld, David 2000 ‘Prior knowledge and the discovery
2005 ‘Social networks, the tertius iungens of entrepreneurial opportunities’.
orientation, and involvement in Organization Science 11/4: 448–469.
Nicholas Dew Nick Dew is an Assistant Professor of Strategic Management at the Naval Postgraduate
School, Monterey. His research focuses on entrepreneurial cognition and industry evolu-
tion. He has a PhD in management from the University of Virginia and an MBA from the
Darden school. Before entering academia, he spent eight years working internationally in
the oil industry. His work has been published in several academic journals, including the
Journal of Marketing, Strategic Management Journal, the Journal of Business Venturing,
the Journal of Business Ethics and Organization Studies. He has received the Louis D.
Liskin award for teaching excellence at NPS.
Address: Graduate School of Business and Public Policy, Naval Postgraduate School,
Monterey, CA 93943, USA.
Email: ndew@nps.edu