Wcms 722482
Wcms 722482
Wcms 722482
CHAPITRE A
in the Balance
ILO ACTRAV Working Paper
by Jelle Visser
ACTRAV
Bureau
for Workers’
Activities
Trade Unions in the Balance
ILO ACTRAV Working Paper
by Jelle Visser
Copyright © International Labour Organization 2019
First published 2019
Publications of the International Labour Office enjoy copyright under Protocol 2 of the Universal Copyright Convention.
Nevertheless, short excerpts from them may be reproduced without authorization, on condition that the source is
indicated. For rights of reproduction or translation, application should be made to ILO Publications (Rights and
Licensing), International Labour Office, CH-1211 Geneva 22, Switzerland, or by email: rights@ilo.org. The International
Labour Office welcomes such applications.
Libraries, institutions and other users registered with a reproduction rights organization may make copies in accordance
with the licences issued to them for this purpose. Visit www.ifrro.org to find the reproduction rights organization in your
country.
The designations employed in ILO publications, which are in conformity with United Nations practice, and the
presentation of material therein do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the International
Labour Office concerning the legal status of any country, area or territory or of its authorities, or concerning the
delimitation of its frontiers.
The responsibility for opinions expressed in signed articles, studies and other contributions rests solely with their
authors, and publication does not constitute an endorsement by the International Labour Office of the opinions
expressed in them.
Reference to names of firms and commercial products and processes does not imply their endorsement by the
International Labour Office, and any failure to mention a particular firm, commercial product or process is not a sign of
disapproval.
Information on ILO publications and digital products can be found at: www.ilo.org/publns.
FOREWORD................................................................................................................................. 5
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY: TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE ...................................................... 7
INTRODUCTION: WHAT FUTURE FOR THE UNIONS?................................................................. 9
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK................................................... 13
1 / Employment and employees – how many union members? ................................................. 14
L 1.1 Economic development.......................................................................................................................... 14
L 1.2 World regions............................................................................................................................................ 15
2 / Changes in employment structure and jobs.......................................................................... 18
L 2.1 Deindustrialization................................................................................................................................... 18
L 2.2 Decline of jobs or unions? .................................................................................................................... 22
L 2.3 Digitalization and technological change ........................................................................................... 24
L 2.4 Disengagement of young people?...................................................................................................... 24
L 2.5 Unions in commercial and social services....................................................................................... 27
L 2.6 The rise of female union membership.............................................................................................. 29
3 / Changing employment relationships..................................................................................... 30
L 3.1 Globalization and migration.................................................................................................................. 32
L 3.2 Migration..................................................................................................................................................... 32
L 3.3 Temporary and part-time workers..................................................................................................... 34
L 3.4 Own-account workers and self-employment ................................................................................ 38
L 3.5 Work and unions in the informal economy...................................................................................... 40
L 3.6 Work and unions in the platform economy...................................................................................... 43
4 / Summary.............................................................................................................................. 47
II. EXPLAINING THE DIFFERENCES IN UNIONIZATION........................................................... 49
1 / Economic development and the informal economy............................................................... 49
2 / Ethnic diversity..................................................................................................................... 50
3 / Labour rights violations........................................................................................................ 52
4 / Institutional union security.................................................................................................... 53
5 / Institutional insecurity, competition and union fragmentation .............................................. 56
III. FOUR POSSIBLE FUTURES................................................................................................. 59
1 / Marginalization .................................................................................................................... 59
2 / Dualization............................................................................................................................ 62
3 / Substitution........................................................................................................................... 66
4 / Revitalization........................................................................................................................ 68
CONCLUSION............................................................................................................................ 71
REFERENCES............................................................................................................................ 72
ENDNOTES................................................................................................................................ 79
Foreword
This year the International Labour Organization (ILO) is celebrating its 100th anniversary. It is in preparation
of this celebration that the Future of Work Initiative was launched in 2015 by the Director General Guy
Ryder1 and based on the acknowledgement that the world of work is changing at a faster pace than ever
before, creating critical challenges for workers and workers’ organizations worldwide.2
In June 2019, at the 108th Session of the International Labour Conference (ILC), ILO tripartite constituents
adopted the ‘Centenary Declaration for the Future of Work’, which will guide the work of the organization
and its constituents for years to come.3
The Centenary Declaration stresses the transformative change in the world of work driven by
technological innovations, demographic shifts, environmental and climate change and globalization.
It recognizes the historic advances in the past 100 years in the world of work. However, it also points
towards the enormous challenges in front of us, such as persistent poverty, inequalities and injustices,
conflict, disasters and other humanitarian emergencies that shape the world of work of today and
constitute a threat for the workforce of tomorrow. As such, the Declaration stresses the urgency to act
in shaping a fair, inclusive and secure future of work with full, productive and freely chosen employment
and decent work for all.
The Centenary Declaration calls upon the ILO to carry forward with unrelenting vigour its constitutional
mandate for social justice by further developing its human-centred approach to the future of work, which
puts workers’ rights and the needs, aspirations and rights of all people at the heart of economic, social
and environmental policies.
It also underlines the significance of promoting multilateralism and ensuring policy coherence within the
multilateral system.
The respect for all fundamental principles and rights at work (FPRW), including freedom of association
and the right to collective bargaining, is an essential foundation of the ILO and key to successful policy
and decision making. As the world of work is changing at an ever increasing pace, strong, influential and
inclusive social dialogue is, and will be, a key vehicle to shape the world of work that we want.
The second pillar of the house are international labour standards (ILS). The Centenary Declaration
reaffirms the fundamental importance of setting, promoting, ratifying and supervising ILS in the
governance of the world of work. It is at the 108th ILC that ILO tripartite constituents adopted a new
Convention, supplemented by a Recommendation, on ‘Violence and harassment in the world of work’.
As a tripartite organization, member states, workers’ and employers’ organizations are critical to
the success of the organization. The Declaration calls for strengthening the capacity of its tripartite
constituents first and foremost by encouraging the development of strong and representative social
partner-organizations.
Trade unions have enormous challenges ahead of them. It is hard to be a unionist today. Violations of
trade union rights are widespread. Technological and economic changes affect the nature and type of
jobs and with that the potential of organizing and representing workers both in the North and in the
Global South.
6 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
It is in that light that trade unions have to further assess their organizing and advocacy strategies. How
to strengthen the employment relationship while ensuring adequate protection to all workers, including
living wages and safety and health at work? Efforts have to be made to organize and represent new forms
of employment including those workers that fall outside the employment relationship or workers in the
informal economy. Think for instance of the Deliveroo or Uber drivers. How to convince young workers
to join unions and integrate them in the union’s governance structure? Whereas some trade unions are
progressing on the gender equality agenda, more has to be done to ensure equal opportunities, equal
participation, equal treatment and equal remuneration.
What can be learned from existing experiences to ensure access to lifelong learning to all workers, to
support working people through the transitions they face throughout their working lives and to ensure
universal access to adequate social protection?
How to broaden the union agenda to socio-economic and environmental issues that all affect the world
of work, for instance when dealing with trade, industrial or macro-economic policies, or in the context of
the Sustainable Development Goals? And how to replicate and upscale innovative and successful union
strategies to weigh in on policy making and sustainable enterprise behavior in a globalized economy?
The ILO Future of Work discussion is an extraordinary opportunity for all of us to build the future that
we want, putting the dignity of workers at the centre of the debate. To do so it is vital that strong and
representative trade unions play an active role in shaping the political process and making the voices of
workers heard.
It is for the occasion of the Centenary celebration of the ILO that ACTRAV commissioned the research
on ‘Trade Unions in the Balance’ by Prof. Jelle Visser (Amsterdam University) to examine the current
state of the unions in the world. Prof. Visser explores developments in union membership across the
world in the past decades. This is set against important changes in the economy and labour market. The
paper also suggests four daring but equally realistic future scenarios for trade unions: marginalization,
dualization, replacement and revitalization. The future will tell which of these scenarios will become
reality.
I am infinitely grateful to Prof. Jelle Visser for this excellent work and collaboration. I invite trade unions,
policy makers and other stakeholders to read this thought-provoking paper on the state of the union of
workers’ organizations worldwide and scenarios of trade unionism in the future world of work.
The world of work is changing at a very rapid pace. The decline of jobs in manufacturing, the rise of
non-standard and flexible work and the persistence and growth of the informal economy, coupled
with changes in employment regulations and behavior and the limitation and violation of trade union
rights have caused unionization rates to fall in most countries worldwide. A ‘new instability of work’ has
come to characterize labour relations in the twenty-first century and this has important implications for
trade unions worldwide. Against this background, trade unions face two major challenges: the digital
economy and the way it transforms jobs and employment relationships as well as the social divide
between workers with stable, paying jobs and workers with unstable, poorly paid or precarious jobs, or
no job at all.
The first part of this paper describes the current ‘state of the unions’ and explores developments in union
membership and union density in 18 world regions in Africa, America, Asia and Europe since 2000.
This is set against the changes in the economy and labour market relating to economic development,
technological change and deindustrialization, globalization, migration, changes in politics and labour
regulations using recent cross-sectional as well as longitudinal data. The analysis is directed both at
levels and changes in the composition of union membership.
Part two attempts to estimate the influence of various conditions – some external, others of the union’s
own making – on the level of unionization: income levels and the share of agriculture or industry; the
size of the informal economy; ethnic diversity and conflict; violation of labour rights; the institutions of
collective bargaining and labour-management relations and union fragmentation.
The paper concludes in part three by describing four possible futures: marginalization through the
continuation of current trends of decreasing rates of unionization and aging unions; dualization of
unions defending their positions and, under conditions of increased instability of work and decreased
institutional protection, focusing their decreasing resources on defending the members closest to them
at the expense of outsiders and precarious workers when necessary; replacement, or a process in
which trade unions are increasingly replaced by other forms of social action and protection provided by
employers, states, intermediary agencies, NGOs or emerging social movements; and lastly, revitalization
based on policies and coalitions which strengthen trade unions as a relevant actor in shaping the ‘new
unstable workforce’ in the digital economy.
8 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
Introduction:
what future for the unions?
In the next decade or two, what can we expect from trade unions and what can we expect for them?4
Will they continue as large membership organizations and represent the full diversity of today’s world of
work or resign to representing a small, protected minority? Will the decline of recent decades continue
or will unions bounce back and be as relevant to labour relations in the Digital Age as they were in the
Age of Industry?
A cloud of uncertainty hangs over the future of trade unions. This is part of what has motivated the ILO
to launch its Future of Work Centenary Initiative, in particular “the fear that the direction of change in
the world of work is away from, not towards, the achievement of social justice”.5 The decline of jobs in
manufacturing and the rise of various forms of non-standard and flexible work, through subcontracting
and outsourcing in much of the developed world and the persistence and growth of the informal economy
in developing countries, have caused union density rates to fall in nearly all countries worldwide. Collective
bargaining coverage in many parts of the world is perilously low and on a downward trend (Visser, Hayter
and Gammarino, 2015). A ‘new instability of work’ has come to characterize labour relations in the
twenty-first century, “undermining the regulatory regimes that organized and governed labour markets
and employment relationships for much of the twentieth century” (Stone and Arthurs, 2013). Beneath
that lie changes in international trade and migration, industrial structure, company behavior and politics.
It is against this background that trade unions must resolve two major challenges: the digital economy
and the social divide between workers with stable, paying jobs and workers with unstable, poorly paid or
precarious jobs, or no job at all. Artificial intelligence and robots have the potential to create and destroy
jobs, but from the union’s perspective, the wrong jobs are destroyed. Current employment statistics
reflecting the first stage of the ‘digital revolution’ indicate a decline in the share of jobs in the middle,
crafts-related jobs and the skilled and semi-skilled jobs in industry – the very jobs that have been co-
shaped by the trade unions in their long history and have provided them with their core membership and
clout in politics and industrial relations. Jobs in teaching and nursing are currently beyond the capability
of computers, but this may soon change and threaten another batch of highly unionized jobs.
The hollowing out of the middle increases the pressure on trade unions to stay relevant for workers in
the high and low end of the labour market. On top of that, the platform economy, still in its infancy but
growing fast, threatens unions in their core activity of conditioning work through collective bargaining
and conflict management. New digital technologies facilitate a reduction in transaction costs that was
unthinkable just a few years ago and eliminates a key reason for the existence of firms, employees
and the employment relationship itself (Coase, 1937). Online platforms can thus push the process of
decentralization, networking, outsourcing, subcontracting and breaking up work in single performances
or ‘gigs’ to a new limit in which all that remains of the firm is a profit-making technique. This technique
is attached to a platform or app through which clients or service requesters can post their tasks and
worker-contractors can accept, perform and submit the service and get paid for it – all of this happening
outside the traditional structures defined by labour and social security law and union contracts.
This business model can be used for almost any kind of task, local or global, general or branded, in
transportation, delivery, laundry, personal training, repair, furniture and kitchen assembly, editing,
graphic design, photography, tuition, guided tours, translation and cooking (Todolí-Signes, 2017). In many
ways, it resembles the old ‘putting out’ system of early capitalism in which workers brought and used
their own tools, but now upgraded with electronic oversight (Finkin, 2017). As this system does not have
employees in the traditional sense, the question is, will it have trade unions? And what tools will these
unions use to leverage power and offer social protection?
10 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
Referring to the United States labour market around 1980, Freeman and Medoff (1984) wrote that trade
unions, by negotiating wages, working hours, job security, and fringe benefits as well as influencing
productivity and worker participation, “alter nearly every … measurable aspect of workplaces and
enterprises.” The ultimate leverage of these unions was the threat of striking or working to rule. Can
unions have the same effect when work is no longer organized in firms and workplaces – the legal,
social and physical entities where workers interact, share common experiences, claim rights and act
together? This is a new question for the trade unions in advanced industrial economies. It is an old
question for the unions in developing countries where most work is fluid and done outside formally
registered enterprises (Breman, 2010).
These are existential questions for the trade unions. The risk is that in the global market, online networks
will auction existing labour and social security laws adding a new dimension to the downward bidding
inherent in global supply chains. To claim that the existence of unions is at risk after the success story of
a century of trade unionism and expanding labour law may sound unnecessarily dramatic. Trade unions
still count among the largest voluntary organizations in the world. Covering 150 countries, the statistics
in this paper add up to 519 million employed union members, 214 million if we leave out China and a few
other countries, where workers’ freedom to join the union of their choice is questioned. The International
Trade Union Confederation (ITUC) claims 207.5 million members in 331 affiliated peak federations in
163 countries and territories.6 A movement that is not exactly small or near death. Yet for some time
now, nearly all trends in unionization have pointed in the wrong direction and “there is no evidence on
whether a recovery from the crisis of unionism or the maintenance of the status quo of trade unions will
be witnessed in the future (Avdagic and Baccaro, 2016).”
I see four possible futures:
1) Gradual marginalization of trade unions through the continuation of present trends with
decreasing rates of unionization and trade unions becoming less relevant or powerless in
shaping the newly emerging labour markets. This can be interpreted as the result of a relentless
process of liberalization and freeing capital from its dependence on labour, national states and
international commitments.
2) Dualization of union representation and policies. Rather than gradual deterioration, unions
will defend their positions and resist where they are currently strong (large firms, skilled and
craft workers in industry and logistics, professionals in the public sector and social services).
Under conditions of the increased instability of work, this implies a sharper distinction between
unionized and non-unionized firms and a smaller share for the former.
3) Replacement. Unions will gradually give way to other forms of social action and representation,
based on legislation (minimum and living wage guarantees, wage panels, works councils,
productivity boards, arbitration and review bodies), employers’ initiatives (employee involvement,
ethical codes, participation and sharing models), business models (law firms, intermediating
labour agencies, consultants) and more or less spontaneous, intermittent forms of social and
community action.
4) Revitalization. Unions will find ways to strengthen existing practices of trade union renewal,
reverse the current trend, rejuvenate, expand beyond their current membership base and
succeed in organizing parts of the ‘new unstable workforce’ in the digital economy.
The first and third scenarios bear some semblance to the unitary frame of reference in industrial relations
and Human Resource Management (HRM), which has predicted a steady decline of ‘external’ unions as
management increasingly cleverly fulfils its harmonizing and trust-building functions within the firm and
to orthodox liberal market theories that presume well-educated and fully informed workers who have
no need for collective bargaining and representation. This harmonious view is at odds with the work and
life of many workers in today’s capitalism exists. The second and fourth scenarios both assume that
a countervailing power in the form of collective action by workers will not only be necessary but also
available, albeit on a very different basis. In the second scenario, trade unions will spend their resources
INTRODUCTION: WHAT FUTURE FOR THE UNIONS? 11
on defending those groups that are currently organized at the expense of weaker groups which, while
more difficult to organize, would benefit most from collective organization and protection (Crouch, 1982).
The fourth scenario starts at the other end and posits that union revival – reversing the current downward
trend in membership – depends on renewal and, in particular, on policies, institutions and coalitions that
enhance the inclusion of weaker and precarious groups in the labour market.
I have organized this paper into three parts. Part one describes the current ‘state of the unions’, mainly by
looking at developments in union membership and union density. This will be set against the changes in
the economy and in the labour market using recent cross-sectional as well as longitudinal data. I am as
interested in union membership levels as in the composition of membership. In part two I try to estimate
the influence of various conditions – some external, others of the union’s own making – on the level of
unionization: income levels and the share of agriculture or industry; the size of the informal economy;
ethnic diversity and conflict; violation of labour rights; the institutions of collective bargaining and labour-
management relations and union fragmentation. Part three concludes by examining the four scenarios
for the future of unions – marginalization, dualization, replacement, and revitalization – and weighs the
pros and cons of each.
I look at trade unions through the lenses of membership and representation. There is more to unions and
unionism than membership and it would be wrong to reduce union power in any given country, industry
or enterprise to the share of unionized workers. Unions differ in how they reach and mobilize workers,
what they ask from members and offer in return, how they co-operate with each other and with other
social, economic or political actors, how they negotiate with employers and represent workers within the
workplace and the economy at large, how they access and influence politics and how they are treated in
the law. Representation and recognition criteria for the purpose of establishing bargaining jurisdiction
rights, seats on works councils, insurance boards or tripartite councils vary widely across countries
and over time. In addition to membership, we might look at electoral and public opinion data as well
as unions’ capacity to mobilize and win strikes. However, membership remains a critical resource for
voluntary organizations like trade unions and is the best way to secure independence from other social
forces and actors, to win elections and bring out workers in strikes and protests. Without members,
unions will have to turn to other sources (parties, governments, tax payers, employers, sponsors, NGOs)
for finance, not without consequences for their independence (Rosanvallon, 1988).
No matter how carefully we construct reliable and comparable data series, comparing union density
rates remains a question of interpretation. Comparing density rates over time within the same unit of
measurement (country, sector, firm) is like taking the temperature – big or rapid changes warn us that
some underlying factors have changed. Comparing density rates across countries requires caution since
the rules differ from place to place, with some countries excluding union organization of public servants,
the military, the police, workers in small firms, the self-employed, migrants and foreign workers. One
of the issues addressed in this paper is whether unions include and are legally allowed to admit self-
employed, foreign nationals and migrants.
Finally, reviewing whether and how trade unions organize workers in the ‘new unstable economy’ of the
Digital Age, one must not lose sight of the purpose they serve. I cannot state this better than was done in
a booklet on union renewal by the Dutch Federation of Trade Unions (FNV):
Do (unions) act on behalf of a privileged group of workers who are already members, or do they try to
involve new groups of workers? Do they prioritize job growth over environmental concerns or do they
advocate sustainable growth? Do they have transparent and democratic decision-making procedures,
or are decisions made in back rooms? Do they fight for equal rights, or do they leave it to symbolic
good intentions? Do they actually involve their members or do they treat them as passive consumers?
(Kloosterboer, 2007)
It is in the spirit of these questions that I have conducted my inquiry.
12 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
I. The state of the unions
and the future of work
Work and employment are core activities for individuals and society.7 Participation in the labour market
largely determines the types of opportunities that will be afforded to men and women and is also a
stepping stone for joining a union. Paid work contributes to the realization of important human needs of
performance, agency, skill development and personal control, of reward, recognition, and self-esteem,
and of participating in wider social networks, including trade unions, that can provide support and a sense
of belonging. Exclusion from paid work and poor-quality jobs are powerful threats to human health and
well-being.
From the perspective of unions there are three main questions. Will there be enough jobs for all? Which
jobs will replace the jobs that disappear and will the new jobs be of sufficient quality in terms of earnings,
skill development, recognition and rights? How will changes in technology and the organization of work
affect workers’ rights and employment relationships? The answers to these questions are not written in
stone, but depend also on political choices and union policies. Looking at the initial stage of digitalization,
there is currently no evidence for an ‘end of work’, but that is not a guarantee for the future. One policy
that will surely remain relevant is work sharing in its many different forms (daily, annually, lifetime,
intermittently combined with other activities including learning), which requires new thinking and new
approaches to income and social insurance. What we do know is that working for an extended period at
the same workplace or in the same firm will become rarer, as will work based on a single, once-acquired
technique. Also, it is likely that digitalization will make certain skilled and semi-skilled jobs redundant,
and that this will affect many union members in the middle earnings range. Finally, many signs of a
change in employment relationships have emerged through the development of digital on-line platform
markets in which pay, hours, rights and obligations are less clearly defined by, and attached to, the status
of ‘employee’ and ‘employer’. This creates a challenge for politics, labour law and trade unions, and
comes on top of the problems created by the growth of flexible and, in many parts of the world, informal
work. In short, the challenge of digitalization for trade unions is less the volume than the quality of jobs
and what that means for the earnings and rights of workers.
This section on ‘the state of the unions’ is organized into three parts, with various subsections. Part one
gives a picture of where unions stand in terms of membership and how they have done since 2000. That
picture is sharpened by focusing on the different stages of economic development in the different continents
and regions of the world. Part two addresses the changes in employment and technology and their effect
on trade union membership. This begins with the well-known story of industrial decline and asks how
much of the decline in recent times can be attributed to the disappearance of jobs in manufacturing.
The sharp fall in unionization among new entrants and young people is one of the issues discussed in
greater detail. Employment in the service economy can be split into two main parts with quite different
conditions for union organizing – commercial services (trade, tourism, transport and communication,
finance and business services) and social, communal and personal services (public administration,
security, education, healthcare, arts and culture and personal services, including household work). The
rise of women in the labour market and in unions is closely connected to the rise of services. Part three is
devoted to changing employment relations, with separate stories about temporary and part-time work,
self-employment and contract work, informal work and work in the platform economy. Globalization and
migration are two of the issues that run through this final part.
14 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
The right side of Figure 1 shows that union density rates for employees have been declining since 2000,
with the largest drop in unionization occurring in developed and lower-middle-income countries. In
the latter case, the decline is due to the rapid increase in jobs (India, Indonesia, Cambodia, Vietnam),
which had outpaced union membership growth and to huge membership losses of the unions in former
Communist countries in Asia and Eastern Europe. Unions in the developed countries lost 14 million
members between 2000 and 2008 and another 10 million between 2008 and 2017. Unions in the other
groups, while still declining until 2008, have gained an estimated 11 million members since 2008. The
result is that the share of union membership in developed countries has fallen to 50 per cent of the
world’s total in 2017, down from 57 per cent in 2000.
25 25
20 20
15 15
10 10
05 05
00 00
all countries developed upper middle lower middle developing all countries developed upper middle lower middle developing
Note: developed countries (average over 52 countries), upper middle (37 countries, w/o China, Cuba and Belarus), lower middle (38
countries), and developing (19 countries). The union density data are weighted averages for each group of countries.
Source: the data in this and all following Figures and Tables were calculated by the author from IRData (www.ilo.org/ilostat/irdata) and the
ICTWSS database (http://uva-aias.net/en/ictwss).
those of the United States’ unions since the Canadian unions gained members before and after 2008,
though not enough to keep pace with employment growth.
Taking into consideration the previously mentioned measurement concerns, Table 1 also shows the
membership of the All-China Federation of Trade Unions (ACFTU), if only to note its enormous size.
With around 302 million members, including 140 million migrant (rural to urban) workers, in 2.81 million
grassroots trade unions, the ACFTU is larger than all other union confederations in the world combined.
If correct, these membership figures translate into a union density rate of between 38 and 44 per cent,
higher than in most developed nations with the exception of northern Europe. Reality on the ground is
more complicated. The Chinese model is predominantly top-down and largely dependent on enterprise
funding, which is mandated by law (Traub-Merz and Pringle, 2018).12
Returning to Table 1, we note that unions, in addition to employees, also recruit a significant number
of self-employed (own-account) workers, some 14.5 million in all. Many of them work in the informal
sector or as undeclared workers in registered workplaces. When calculating union density rates for the
employed (column 5), they are included. When calculating union density rates for employees (column
6), they are left out. In both columns, we observe a large variation in union density levels across world
regions. Indeed, northern Europe stands apart at the high end, as do the Arab states in the Middle East at
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 17
the low end. It makes a difference whether we include the self-employed, own-account workers and the
informal sector. If we do, union density rates are below 10 per cent in seven regions: the Arab countries
in the Middle East with their large numbers of migrant workers, East and West Africa, Central America,
and South, South-East and West Asia. Note that this is the case, notwithstanding significant recent
membership gains, in the informal sector, especially in Africa.
Focusing only on the formal sector and employees, though including workers with temporary and part-
time jobs, it is possible to track developments since 2000 (Figure 2). I have added 2008 to determine
whether the Great Recession has marked a turning point for better or worse. In Africa and America,
union decline stopped after 2008 due to strong union growth in North Africa following the Arab Spring
of 2011, the stabilization of unions in a number of countries in southern Africa and union gains in South
America. Unionization in East and West Africa remains very weak and on a downward trend. The same
is true for North and Central America. Overall, the mean unionization level is lower in Asia than in either
America or Africa – 13 per cent compared with 15 per cent for America and 21 for Africa – and variations
across regions have decreased significantly. Lastly, the European exception, where union density rates
are higher than in other parts of the world, is drawing to a close. The mean density rate fell from 39 per
cent in 2000 to 23 per cent in 2017, with each of the five regions impacted, albeit at a very different level in
the case of northern Europe. The decline has, however, slowed down a little in recent years.
18 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
70 AFRICA 70 ASIA
60 Southern Africa 60 East Asia
50 West Africa 50 South East Asia
40 East Africa 40 South Asia
30 30
North Africa West Asia
20 20 Arab countries
10 10
00 0
2000 2008 2016 2000 2008 2016
AMERICA EUROPE
80 80
70 AMERICA 70 EUROPE
60 North America 60 Eastern and
Central Europe
50 Central America 50
and Caribbean South East Europe
40 40 and Balkans
South America Southern Europe
30 30
Western Europe
20 20
Northern Europe
10 10
0 0
2000 2008 2016 2000 2008 2016
L 2.1 Deindustrialization
Currently, manufacturing accounts for 16 per cent of total employment in upper-middle-income
countries, 12 per cent in lower-middle-income countries, 13 per cent in developed countries and only
6 per cent in developing countries. With few exceptions, mining, quarrying and utilities account for only
a minor share of employment, as these sectors are very capital intensive. By 2017, the service sector
employed the largest share of the workforce everywhere except in low-income developing countries,
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 19
where the employment share of services (21 per cent) is far smaller than that of agriculture (70 per
cent). In developed countries, three out of four workers were employed in the services sector in 2017
(ILO, 2018b).
As a rule, agricultural workers tend to be scattered and non-unionized. Only those working in large
plantations tend to be organized, for instance in Kenya or Uganda where agricultural workers respectively
make up 35 and 21 per cent of all union members. In emerging economies, agricultural workers represent
less than 5 per cent of all union members (for instance in Brazil, India, Russia, South Africa or Turkey). In
developed countries only about 1 per cent of all union members work in agriculture (including gardening
and fishing).13 As might be expected, the share of agricultural employment is negatively correlated with
the level of unionization across countries (ragr=-0,44). Controlling for income levels, the negative relation
is weaker but still significant.
Deindustrialization has been going on for some time and is transforming trade unions. In each and every
country today, most union members have a job in services. Averaged for the 18 advanced industrial
countries of Western Europe and North America, industry’s membership share (manufacturing,
construction, mining and utilities) shrank on average by half a percentage point each year, from 43 per
cent in 1980 to 32 per cent in 2000 and 22.5 per cent in 2015. Manufacturing accounts on average for 17
per cent of all union members in these 18 countries mentioned above (Figure 3); mining for less than
1 per cent; utilities (gas, water and electricity) for 1 to 2 per cent and construction for 4 to 5 per cent.
Unfortunately, I do not have enough data to calculate averages for the other country groups.
50
Share of employeed union membership (%)
40
30
20
10
0
nz da
Bu ania
al i
Ke wi
oz h a
Zi bi a
S ba e
So waz bwe
h nd
Za rica
Co ia
ite an a
St a
Br tes
Ch il
M ile
A ala l
Ba ust nd
Ph lad ia
pi h
Ca Ko es
m rea
Ja dia
Tu an
ey
ng ia
Gr om
rtu e
Li rela l
th nd
e a
Fr den
rw e
Ne Es ay
er ia
Sp ds
De inla n
n nd
ng k
Sw Au ary
e ia
l d
Bu gium
ov ia
o ia
Cz ma ia
h a
p
rm ly
Po any
nd
ico
M nd
Ze ae
I ga
az
M G ny
am an
m qu
Un C mbi
d ad
Po eec
Sw ani
No anc
Be rlan
ec ni
Hu mar
Re
F ai
ilip es
Ge Ita
b
ng ral
Ki tv
th ton
itz str
Sl gar
Sl en
Ro vak
rk
a
n
n
Ta gan
ut ila
la
m
bo
ex
ru
w Isr
a
d
d La
la
Af
u
lo
l
U
Ne
ite
Un
Note: The industrial (or ‘goods producing’) sector comprises mining, manufacturing, utilities and construction. Where
mining is not separately indicated in the Figure, its size (membership share) is so small that it is counted together with
manufacturing.
Figure 3 presents the available data on the share of union membership in manufacturing (including mining)
in 52 countries. I have chosen 1980 as the starting point when employment and union membership in
manufacturing was at its zenith. 1980 also marks the beginning of globalization, the opening of China’s
economy, the withdrawal from import-substitution industrialization policies in developing countries, and
the political turn to neo-liberal policies. The first thing to notice is the huge variation across countries on
each of the four continents. There are just a handful of countries where one-third or more of all union
20 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
members work in industry: South Africa, Zambia, Japan, Turkey, Romania, the Czech Republic, Slovakia,
Italy, Germany and Poland. The German unions stand out with their strong position in manufacturing
(especially in metals and chemicals). In some of the African countries there is a sizeable and highly
unionized mining industry (with unionization rates of up to 80 per cent). Mining is also significant in Chile,
Bulgaria, Romania and Poland, but elsewhere its share of union membership is negligible. The building
industry (in Figure 3 taken together with utilities, such as the provision of gas, water and electricity)
represents a sizeable portion of union membership of 10 per cent or more, in the United States, Australia,
and Switzerland. The flipside is the very small size, in terms of union membership, of the manufacturing
industry. In Canada, the United States, Israel, Australia, Latvia and the United Kingdom its membership
share has fallen below 10 per cent. In Sweden, Denmark, Norway, Finland, Ireland, the Netherlands,
Greece and Portugal there are now fewer union members in manufacturing than in either health or
education.
Figure 3 shows that, since 1980, the decline of the ‘goods producing sector’ in the unions has been
a rather general process affecting all countries, albeit from different starting levels, and hitting some
countries (United States, United Kingdom, Denmark, the Netherlands) much earlier than others
(Germany, Belgium, Italy). Although more intense in the developed – advanced industrial – countries, it
has started to affect unions in developing countries as well, usually starting from a much smaller initial
base in manufacturing.
Figure 4 turns our attention to union density rates in manufacturing (including mining). Again, the
variation across countries in each of the four continents – from Uganda to South Africa; Colombia to
Argentina; Bangladesh to Japan, and Estonia to Sweden – is very large. In some important countries
with a large export base in manufacturing (Bangladesh, India, Mexico, the Czech and Slovak Republics,
and Poland), unions are very weak. Looking at developments since 1980, we can conclude that the
level of unionization has been falling in all countries for which there is historical data. The largest and
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 21
earliest drops in unionization occurred in the United States, Canada, Australia, New Zealand and the
United Kingdom, the five advanced industrial countries in which the neo-liberal policies of financial,
product and labour deregulating were most on display, with new constraints placed on unions calling
strikes. In these five countries, the average union density rate in manufacturing dropped from 47 per
cent around 1980 to 17 per cent in 2017, meaning that current unionization is about one-third of what it
was before globalization and neo-liberalism began their victorious ascent. Union decline, although less
intense, affected countries with less marked neo-liberal politics as well. From 1980 to 2017, the average
unionization rate in manufacturing in the four Nordic countries (Denmark, Finland, Norway, and Sweden)
dropped from 90 to 68 per cent in continental Western Europe (Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy,
the Netherlands, Spain and Switzerland) from 43 to 24 per cent. The shutdown and downsizing of highly
unionized enterprises (coalmining, shipyards, steel) combined with the rise of temporary work and
unemployment are among the factors that help explain the decline of unions within manufacturing.
In Figure 4 I have also indicated the level of unionization in commercial services, which has become the
largest sector in terms of employment in most countries and includes trade, food and tourism, transport
and communication, finance, insurance and real estate and business and administrative services.
Generally, trade unions are better represented in manufacturing than in commercial services. On average,
the likelihood of union membership in manufacturing is two times higher, varying from 1.3 times in
Finland, Sweden, Denmark and the United Kingdom to about 3 times in Germany, Poland or Mexico.14
Given the financial constraints on the expansion of public and social services, it is in the expanding
commercial services sector, rather than in the contracting manufacturing sector, that newcomers to the
labour market and those losing their jobs in manufacturing will have to find their jobs. The gap between
the density rates in manufacturing and commercial services therefore indicates the structural challenge
that unions face. Unless trade unions find ways to halt their decline in manufacturing employment,
strengthen their position in commercial services or expand employment in public and social services
(where density rates tend to be much higher than in manufacturing), they are in for further decline. This
is particularly true in countries such as Germany, where unions are weak in commercial services and the
gap with manufacturing unions is very wide.
90
80
Union density rate, union members as % of employees
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
s
ne
M nda
Sw Gh wi
az ana
n d
*Z ur ia
ba di
Ke e
So Za nya
h ia
a
d bia
M tes
*C co
Ca hile
Ar Bra a
ge zil
a
sh
*Is dia
el
Tu lia
w Ko y
Ca ala a
m nd
Ja ia
n
L a
n a
ov y
*C Fr kia
ch ce
Po ep
Gr nd
rtu e
itz U l
er K
Ne land
*S rlan in
lo ds
Ir nia
rm d
Au ny
ria
*B rw y
el ay
F um
nm nd
Sw ark
en
ga
pi
e
Sl gar
No Ital
Ta ilan
bw
ric
in
Ze re
ni
Hu atvi
Po eec
Ge elan
pa
*B zan
im un
ut mb
d
ra
e a
ze an
rk
a
ra
a
de
na
R
la
De inla
ed
st
ex
ite m
In
bo
a
nt
to
th Sp
ve
a
ilip
gi
al
a
Af
St
st
la
Ug
Es
Un Colo
Ph
Au
ng
Sw
Ba
Ne
Note: Density rates in manufacturing are calculated with the inclusion of mining in all countries. Commercial services
include retail and wholesale trade, hotels and restaurants, transport and communication, finance and insurance, real
estate, business and administrative services.
22 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
1 2 3 4 5
due to fewer
due to fewer
000’s % 000’s members in 000’s
jobs (%)
jobs (%)
Lastly, I would like to draw the attention to columns 1 and 5 in Table 2, which show changes in membership
in the total economy and in services, in thousands. Between 1980 and 2016, unions lost on aggregate
one quarter of their members. Most of this decline, with a loss of 5 to 6 million union members in each
case, occurred in just three countries: Germany, the United Kingdom and the United States. There were,
however, five countries where unions expanded their membership: Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Norway
and Spain. Spain, which had a very low level of unionization in 1980, is actually the only country where
unions gained more members in industry, until 2008 when a steep decline set in. Perhaps even more
remarkable is that fewer than half of these countries – Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Italy, Norway, Spain,
Sweden – significantly increased their membership in services. This is not the case in Australia, France,
Germany, Portugal, the United Kingdom and the US, despite the fact that the number of service sector
jobs in the 18 countries of Table 2 increased in each and every country by an average of 77 per cent.
24 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
many countries, this is transforming trade unions. Why young people have a much lower propensity to
join unions than those of one or two generations ago is not fully clear. It is, however, a development that
can be observed in nearly all advanced industrial countries for which we have data (Figure 5).
60
50
Union density rate (% of employees)
40
30
20
10
00
ia
l
ce
ain
nia
ce
kia
UK
ly
da
ia
en
um
k
ga
ar
an
nd
lan
ali
lan
lan
xic
US
ar
Ita
ton
str
an
ee
na
ed
va
Sp
ve
rtu
ng
lgi
rm
nm
str
rla
Me
Po
Ire
Fin
Au
Gr
Fr
Sw
Ca
Es
Slo
Slo
Hu
Be
Po
the
Au
Ge
De
Ne
Union density rates of young workers vary from 1 per cent in Estonia (and virtually 0 per cent in Latvia and
Lithuania) to 44 per cent in Belgium. Density rates are calculated as the proportion of union members in
employment – basically those who have found jobs. Hence, these percentages do not consider the large
number of full-time students or unemployed in this age group. In two-thirds of the countries shown in
Figure 5, less than 8 per cent of young workers join a union. A considerable drop in youth membership
was seen in Sweden, Finland and Denmark (in each case related to changes in union unemployment
insurance funds), in Australia and Slovenia, and in Greece and Portugal (undoubtedly related to the sharp
increase in youth unemployment). On the other hand, the density rate of young people in Canada has
not decreased and in Germany and Belgium the changes, at least since 2000, have been modest. Where
entry into employment is channeled through a dual (work and school) vocational training path, as in
Germany, unions may stand a better chance of recruiting young people. The Belgian example offers
some thoughts on the price of union membership, which may be too high for the large numbers of young
people working in odd jobs and insecure temporary, agency and part-time jobs. In Belgium, workers
under the age of 25, including students and job-seekers, can join the unions almost free of charge; they
pay strongly reduced dues or none, yet can share in the benefits and activities of the unions (Pulignano
and Doerflinger, 2014). According to these authors, the problem of Belgian unions is not the lack of
membership among young people, but the lack of active participation.
Spanish unions present a contrasting case: the union density rate of young people is very low and falling
and the gap with older workers very large (Figure 5 and 6). Pulignano, Gervasi and Franceschi (2016)
attribute this to the fact that most young people are trapped in temporary jobs and Spanish unions are
mainly there for permanent workers. This ‘dualism’ was reinforced by the 2008 crisis and the ensuing
austerity policies, when unemployment and precarious employment among young people increased
massively. This may well be a reason why ‘Juventud Sin Futuro’ (Youth without a Future), a movement
that denounced the precarious situation of young people in the labour market and rose at the same time
as the Indignados movement in 2011 (Antentas, 2011), explicitly rejected any link to the unions (and to
26 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
the established political parties). ‘They do not represent us’ was one of their slogans (Flesher Fominaya,
2015; Hyman and Gumbrell-McCormick, 2017). Although the two main trade union confederations have
attempted to counteract declining membership by recruiting women, young workers and the large
proportion of employees engaged in temporary contracts (Heery and Adler, 2004), initiatives of this kind
have tended to remain rather weak as actual resources dedicated to this task are rather meager (Keune,
2013).
Figure 6: Union density rates of workers entering and leaving the labour market, 2014
aged 16-24 years aged 55-64 years
80
70
60
Union density rare (% employees)
50
40
30
20
10
00
Es ia
ia
Hu a
ec y
Po p
Po d
Isr l
Fr l
ce
ain
A
Slo ico
G a
the ce
Ze s
Slo nd
kia
UK
a
itz ly
Ca d
Ge da
Au y
Ire ia
No d
De ay
Fin k
Sw d
Be en
um
ga
ae
Cz gar
an
d
tvi
ni
lan
ali
lan
lan
lan
e
ar
US
Sw Ita
an
ton
str
an
Ne ree
rw
Ne rlan
na
hR
ed
ala
x
va
Sp
ve
rtu
nm
lgi
rm
La
str
Me
hu
er
n
Au
Lit
The gap in unionization between young workers entering the labour market and older workers close
to retirement is larger than ever, not only in Spain. Figure 6 shows the gap in the unionization rates of
workers in the two age groups (16–24 and 55–64) in which the average worker enters or leaves the
labour market.16 In 2014 in advanced industrial countries, the age cohort of older workers, those that
entered the labour market in the 1970s, is on average 4.3 times more unionized than the age cohort that
has entered the labour marked in the past decade (Figure 6).17 Fifteen years ago the average gap was
only half that large. The implication is that unions have aged and the share of union members who will
leave the labour market in the coming years has grown. The average age of union members in European
countries has risen to 45 years (calculated from the European Social Survey) and on average 20 percent
of all union members are over 55 years of age, not counting those who have retired.
Union density rates tend to increase with age in almost all countries. The issue here is that the differences
between young and old have increased. The higher density rates of older workers are the result of higher
density rates of past generations – in other words, of decisions made some thirty to forty years ago.
Workers tend to join the union when they are young, most often when they have landed their first stable
job and begun establishing a family (Visser, 2002). The probability of leaving the union is also highest in
the first years of membership and then sharply decreases (Van Rij and Saris, 1993). Workers who do not
join a union before the age of 30 or 35 will most probably never join. This means that together with the
decline of union membership among young people over the last thirty or forty years, the proportion of
workers who never join a union has increased, as Booth, Budd and Munday (2010) have shown with data
for the United States and Bryson and Gomez (2005) for the United Kingdom.
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 27
Density rates vary within commercial services. The lowest levels of unionization are typically found in
retail, hotels, restaurants, catering and tourism, private road transport, business services (including
rentals and work agencies) and personal commercial services (cleaning). To illustrate, the union
density rate in hotels and restaurants is below 3 per cent in the United States, the United Kingdom,
and Hungary, 4 per cent in France, 5 per cent in Australia and Japan, 6 per cent in Canada and 7 per
cent in the Netherlands and these rates have been falling in the last decade in all of these countries. In
retail, unions have their stronghold in the bigger department stores, but in recent years, business has
increasingly shifted to online shopping and delivery services like Amazon. Current union density rates
range from 1 per cent in Tanzania, 2 per cent in Poland, 4 per cent in Hungary, The Republic of Korea and
the United States, 5 to 6 per cent in France and between 11 and 13 per cent in the United Kingdom, the
Netherlands, Canada, Australia and Japan. Union density rates in business services, including finance
and insurance, tend to be below 10 per cent and, like in industry, middle-range administrative jobs, are
disappearing while the share of ‘own-account’ workers is increasing. In transport and communication,
the unions’ strongholds are in publicly owned or publicly regulated services (rail-and airways, ports and
ferries, municipal transport, postal services), but privatization, off-shoring (seafarers) and the opening of
international competition in road and sea transport and in communication has created a far more difficult
environment for the unions.
70
60
Density rates (% of employees)
50
40
30
20
10
0
Zim nza d
ba nia
Za we
Mo Ma bia
m i
Gh ue
Ug ana
So Ke da
Af a
a
bia
Ch A
Co ex le
st ico
nd a
B s
Ca razil
da
K ey
str a
Ne J alia
Ze an
Isr d
l
hu a
P nia
ng d
Slo ary
Cz ulga ia
ec ria
L ep
Slo atvia
nia
itz nce
S nd
Ne erm ain
rl y
Po ands
Gr gal
Ire ce
d
Au UK
ia
lg y
No ium
nm y
Fin ark
Sw nd
en
za law
ae
the an
Be Ital
De rwa
a
Ta ilan
uth ny
ric
Ho a Ric
Au ore
Lit toni
Hu olan
lan
US
B ak
str
i
rk
ee
ur
an
na
hR
ed
w ap
biq
ala
la
la
m
lom
b
ve
G p
rtu
Sw Fra
v
er
Tu
az
Es
M
Co
Sw
Figure 7 also displays the union density rates in social and community services. This sector includes public
administration, social security, policy and security forces, education, health, arts and entertainment and
other social and personal services. Unsurprisingly, union density rates in public, social, community and
personal services are much higher than in commercial services. The exception to that general finding
happens when government workers are barred from unionization, as is the case in Chile. On average,
for the 49 countries shown in Figure 7, the level of unionization is 3.4 times higher in social as compared
to commercial services. As a rule, civil servants, administrators, local and central government workers,
teachers and, where allowed, the police and the military are those with the highest union density
rates in any country. There can be many reasons for this, including facilitation and encouragement of
unions by the authorities, professionalism and esprit de corps, particular insurances that come with
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 29
union membership and a higher degree of employment stability than in the private sector, even though
short-time contracts and interim work have become quite common, especially in education, healthcare
and subsidiary government services. Historical data on a much smaller set of countries show that the
unionization gap between workers in commercial and social services (and those working in the private
or public sector generally) rapidly widened in the 1980s and 1990s following the sharp decline of union
membership in the private sector (in services no less than in industry). However, since 2000, union density
rates have also declined in public service due to privatization, increased use of temporary contracts in
public administration and education, and the shift from employee to own-account status in health care.
Teachers have played a key role in the making of African unions. They often are the single largest group in
the unions. Teachers’ unions account for 53 per cent of total paying membership in Sierra Leone, 47 per
cent in Tanzania, 31 per cent in Ghana, 30 per cent in Uganda, 29 per cent in Zimbabwe and 24 per cent
in Malawi. These numbers are larger than for any other occupational group. Similar high shares are also
typical for some ‘low unionization’ countries in the developed world, for instance in the United States
where union membership in education represents 28 per cent of total membership in 2017, France with
22 per cent in 2013, or Mexico with 20 per cent in 2015. Nurses and medical professionals are usually
also well represented in the trade unions, albeit often through professional associations outside the
mainstream union movement.
Generally, the employment shift from industry to services, and more particularly to social and community
services, is accompanied by a higher average level of educational attainment. Union density rates tend
to increase with educational attainment. I only have data for the OECD, showing that, on average, more
than two out of five union members have obtained the tertiary level of education, two out of five the
upper secondary level and fewer than one-fifth less than the secondary level. The countries with the
largest share of unskilled workers and members with less than the secondary level of education, above
30 per cent of all union members, are Turkey, Mexico, the Republic of Korea, Spain and Portugal. Like the
shift to services, rising numbers of women in the unions has also pushed up the level of education. The
higher the share of women in the unions, the lower the share of members without secondary education
(r=-0,57).
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
i
Mo anda
So Gh cco
Af a
Gu ca
d S ala
Me tes
Ch o
Br ile
Ni nad l
c a
ge ua
na
tan
ilip ey
lay s
Ba Ko sia
lad a
str h
Ne J alia
Ze an
m nd
Isr ia
l
hu ia
Hu ania
Cz lova ry
ec kia
Po ep
L nd
Bu atvia
a
m a
Ru Cr nia
ian ia
d
Po nce
G Sp l
Ne erm ain
Sw rla y
er s
Gr and
ite Ir ece
ing nd
Lu Au om
m ia
g
Cy aly
Ma s
No lta
lg y
Fin ium
Sw land
nm n
Ice ark
d
Rw und
Ca azi
ae
ga
the an
Be rwa
Ma pine
itz nd
u
uth an
ng re
Slo ri
Ro veni
Fe
lan
xic
ur
De ede
Au es
Lit ton
ss at
xe str
S ga
Ph urk
ri
pr
hR
nti
w ap
Ca ala
la
d K ela
Ar arag
lga
It
bo
a
ite m
ta
rtu
kis
bo
ro
e
a
o
l
r
Fr
Es
Un ate
Bu
T
Pa
Un
The lowest unionization rates of women, and the largest gap between male and female unionization rates
are witnessed in Argentina, Pakistan, Turkey, the Republic of Korea, Japan, Austria, Germany, Greece
and Cyprus. The reasons for unions’ failure to recruit more women in these countries are not always
clear. With the exception of Greece, Cyprus, and Pakistan there is a strong tradition and large presence
of industry and industrial unionism in these countries – even today – and perhaps this has delayed the
focus on women and female unionization that is found in public and private services. Religious and
cultural factors (Confucianism in Japan, the influence of Islam in Pakistan, a masculine union culture in
the Republic of Korea and Japan, machismo in Latin America, paternalism in Africa and the persistence
of the male breadwinner model in some continental European countries) may also have their hand in the
failure of bringing women on a par with men in the unions (see Cook et al., 1984). However, variations
within the same regions, cultures and even religions, and in some cases rapid changes over time (for
instance in Ireland or the Netherlands), should make us cautious when using these cultural explanations.
Not so long ago, Christian ideology required women to return to their homes upon marriage and childbirth.
The diversity of employment relationships in high-income countries has grown and ranges from
permanent or stable formal employment to different forms of non-standard work, in particular part-
time work, fixed-term contracts, temporary agency work, on-call work, and different forms of self-
employment. Increased flexibility and diversity can also be observed with respect to working time, mobile
working patterns and working from home. Some of these new work arrangements position workers
as autonomous, independent or self-employed, dispatch them from a temporary employment agency,
post them to other countries on temporary contracts, or redeploy them from the core workforce of large
dominant firms and companies to that of their smaller and less stable suppliers.
Casual employment is a prominent feature of low- and middle-income countries and has grown in
importance in industrialized countries. In Bangladesh, nearly two-thirds of wage employment is casual;
in Mali and Zimbabwe, one in three employees works in a casual job. In Australia, casual employment
affects one out of four employees (IPSP, 2018). The OECD estimates that non-standard work, which
includes self-employed, temporary and part-time workers on temporary contracts, make up almost a
quarter of total employment. The rise of non-standard work took place well before the Great Recession of
2008. On average, almost 2.6 per cent of permanent full-time jobs in the OECD countries were destroyed
in the aftermath of that recession, accounting for a further rise in the share of non-standard work. The
ILO estimates that, averaged over 150 countries, the incidence of temporary employment in the formal
sector is 11 per cent, with a wide-ranging variation from less than 5 per cent in Latvia, Norway and Sierra
Leone to over 25 per cent in Peru, Poland and Spain (ILO, 2018b).
32 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
L 3.2 Migration
Not only jobs move, people move as well. Migration flows to the North particularly intensified in the ten-
year period preceding the global financial crisis. Afterwards, they slowed down but have since picked up,
with a growing share of refugees fleeing war and misery (Afonso and Devitt, 2016). The International
Organization for Migration (IOM) estimates the number of migrants in 2015 at nearly 1 billion worldwide
– that’s one in seven people globally (IOM, 2016). The large majority (740 million) are internal (mostly
rural-urban) migrants, with 150 million in China alone. International migrants numbered 244 million,
an increase of 41 per cent since 2000. International migration within the Global South, at 90 million
(35 per cent of all international migrants), is slightly higher than migration from the South to the North
(33 per cent), whereas only 23 per cent have moved between countries in the North and 5 per cent from
the North to the South. ILO data for 2013 suggest that most international migrants, 130 million, are
labour migrants, the vast majority (75 per cent) in high-income countries (ILO, 2015b). The proportion of
international migrant workers as a share of all workers varies from below 3 per cent in much of Africa,
Latin America, and South and East Asia to 9–10 per cent in Eastern Europe and Central Western Asia,
to 16 per cent in northern, western and southern Europe, 20 per cent in North America and 35 per cent
in the Arab States. Between 2003 and 2013, international migrants contributed to 70 per cent of the
increase in the workforce in Europe and 47 per cent in the United States.
Under the ‘guest workers’ programs in continental Europe, labour migrants from southern Europe,
Turkey and North Africa were not always welcomed by the unions of the North, and at times this
created tensions within the nascent European Union movement (Penninx and Roosblad, 2000). When
these programs ended following the economic shocks of the 1970s, many countries adopted zero
immigration policies but did not prevent resident migrants to stay and reunite with their families. The
neoliberal globalization policies of the 1980s and 1990s led to a new phase of migration ‘pulled in’ by the
re-emergence of sweatshops, informal employment and exploitative work in the Global North (Reyneri,
2003). Immigrant workers have traditionally found themselves more often than not outside the unions
and they have always been less unionized than native workers in the same jobs. Whether this was
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 33
because migrant workers had a lower propensity to join the union or because unions did not target
migrant workers is not always clear.
However, by 2000 in North America, Western Europe and South-East Asia, trade unions had become more
‘inclusionary’ towards international migrants (Caspersz, 2013). They began to support legal channels
for labour immigration and place more emphasis on the organization of migrants, sometimes through
special offices and structures within the unions and alliances with civil action groups (Connolly et al., 2014;
Milkman, 2013; Tapia and Turner, 2013). Later in this paper, we will encounter examples from countries
as far apart as Jordan, South Africa and Hong Kong. In Western Europe and North America, trade unions
began to see the enforcement of employment standards as a more effective way to protect the labour
market than migration controls. Some unions have been more restrictive than others, for instance when
they advocated and obtained a temporary stop to labour migration from the eight new EU member
states of Central and Eastern Europe in 2004 (Dølvik and Visser, 2009). Nonetheless, unions today focus
more on the situation and treatment of migrants present in the country than on the management of
channels of entry (Krings, 2010). In 2000, the American Federation of Labor and Congress of Industrial
Organizations (AFL–CIO) in the United States adopted a pro-immigrant policy stance, abandoning its
previous support for restrictive measures. It now embraces the cause of immigrant rights and a path to
legalization for undocumented workers from Central and South America (Milkman, 2013). In a number
of European countries including France, Spain, Italy, the Netherlands, Belgium, and the United Kingdom,
trade unions have become vocal supporters of immigrant rights (Connolly, Marino, Martinez Lucio, 2014;
Jacobson and Geron, 2011).
60
50
Union density rate (% employees)
40
30
20
10
00
ia
ce
ain
ria
ep
ce
kia
ia
UK
l
nia
ly
ay
um
en
ga
ar
an
nd
lan
lan
lan
lan
Ita
ton
str
an
ee
rw
hR
ed
lga
va
Sp
ve
rtu
ng
lgi
rm
rla
Po
er
Ire
Fin
Au
Gr
Fr
Sw
Es
No
Slo
Slo
Hu
Bu
ec
Be
Po
the
itz
Ge
Cz
Sw
Ne
Source: ICTWSS Database, calculated from the European Social Survey, adjusted to known average density rates
Figure 9 compares the union density rates of native and foreign-born workers in 2012 in a number of
European countries. Unfortunately, I have no comparable data for non-European countries. The data
shown here is based on labour force or household surveys (Ireland, the Netherlands, Sweden, the United
Kingdom, Estonia) and data derived from the European Social Survey, adjusted to the known average
density rates.19 With few exceptions (mainly Portugal and Slovenia), migrant workers are less unionized
than native workers. Gorodzeisky and Richards (2013) and Kranendonk and de Beer (2016), using
different waves of the European Social Survey, conclude that the lower rate of unionization of migrant
34 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
workers in Europe compared to the rates of native workers cannot, or can only to a very small degree,
be explained by the individual characteristics of migrants, such as the overrepresentation of migrants in
particular industries or occupations that are less unionized. They conclude that the lower union density
rate of migrant or foreign-born workers must be explained by differences in union policies.
Across the range of European countries shown in Figure 9, native workers are on average 1.3 times
more likely to be unionized than foreign-born workers. The largest differences exist in Spain (ratio of 2,3
to 1), Greece (1,9 to 1), Hungary (1,6 to 1), Austria (1,6 to 1), Switzerland, Germany and Ireland (1,5 to
1). In France and the United Kingdom the differences are close to the average of 1,3 to 1. The smallest
differences occur in Belgium, Italy, Finland, Sweden, Denmark (all about 1,1 to 1), the Netherlands,
Norway and Poland (1,2 to 1). Unfortunately, I have no historical data for Spain or Greece that would
make it possible to show the effect of the 2008 recession and the ensuing sharp rise in unemployment.
Were migrant workers more affected? Did they leave the country or stay? Did they abandon the unions
or did the unions abandon them? For Sweden, Denmark, Ireland and the Netherlands, I do have data that
allow a comparison with the late 1990s. It transpires that the union density rate of migrant or foreign-
born workers in Sweden, Denmark and Ireland has fallen more than the density rate of native workers.
In the Netherlands, the decrease was similar for both groups, notwithstanding the organizing efforts of
the Dutch unions towards temporary and migrant workers (Connolly, Marino and Martinez Lucio, 2016).
The disproportionate decline of union membership of migrant workers in Denmark and Sweden might
be explained by political changes that have weakened the voluntary, union-run system of unemployment
insurance funds, with a strongly negative impact on union recruitment and union retention of young
workers, temporary workers and migrants (Kjellberg and Ibsen, 2016). In Ireland, the population of
foreign-born workers, while increasing rapidly in the 2000s, changed from mainly Anglo-Saxon to
predominantly Eastern European. Many migrants bring with them different experiences, both negative
and positive, about trade unions from their homeland, and this is likely to influence their decisions about
joining a union in their adoptive country.
45
40
35
Share in membership (%)
30
25
20
15
10
05
00
Ire l
No ark
Ge way
Au Italy
en
d
Ca m
a
Fr d
Be nds
a, an
Sw gal
De land
kia
M ce
Ko J ia
La a
Ne Po y
ey
Ze d
ec o
Slo ain
Au ia
Slo ary
A
itz ce
ite Fin da
ing nd
Es ia
ia
Hu of
ae
Po om
Lit Rep
the CD
lan
an
tvi
n
ali
w lan
Cz exic
US
str
an
n
ton
u
an
rk
ed
Sw Gree
ala
re ap
na
d K la
Isr
p
va
rtu
nm
Sp
ve
lgi
ng
Ne OE
rla
rm
str
Re
er
hu
Tu
h
Un
Note: The membership share of the self-employed is calculated as a percentage of total (employees and self-employed) membership
in employment; the membership of part-time and temporary workers is calculated as a percentage of the membership of employees in
employment.
Looking at the three groups separately, we see that the highest shares of union members with temporary
employment contracts occur in Turkey and Israel, followed by Ireland, the United States, Italy and Australia.
Unions in the Netherlands, Australia, the United Kingdom, Ireland and Belgium have a high share of
members with part-time jobs. Part-time work is less developed in Central and Eastern Europe and most
unions have yet to start organizing part-time employees. The same applies to agency workers, who only
recently have become identified as a target for union organizing (Bernaciak and Kahancová, 2017). As a
rule, unions start organizing non-standard workers, or any group outside the norm, when they realize
that the group is large enough, not diminishing and vital for their bargaining position or survival.20 Data
on union membership among the self-employed (including freelancers, artists, professionals, students,
own-account workers and gig-workers) is available for only half of these countries. Their share in total
union membership is still small but growing in countries like Israel, Slovakia, Finland, Sweden, Italy and
the Netherlands.
High job turnover is negatively correlated to union membership. If we think of union membership as
keeping with a social custom, reputation or norm that is upheld through peer pressure (Booth, 1985;
Checchi & Visser, 2005; Ibsen, Toubøl, and Jensen, 2017; Visser, 2002), the ‘broken tie’ of losing or
changing the job has the effect of taking that pressure away, and it is one of the most cited reasons of
respondents in survey research answering why they resigned from the union. Research also confirms
the finding that, in the case of Germany, union-dominated works councils play an important role not only
in recruiting but also in retaining members (Behrens, 2009; Goerke and Pannenberg, 2007; Leschke and
Vandaele, 2018).
Besides the lower joining rate and higher exit rate associated with job turnover, the lower union density
rate among temporary workers has also resulted from union neglect. Although unions across Europe
responded to the challenge of contingent labour differently, according to Gumbrell- McCormick (2011)
there was a common element in their approach. Initially, they were less concerned about representation
36 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
than about opposing this kind of work per se and seeking its prohibition. When that failed and the unions
began to realize that contingent work is here to stay, they changed their response, from exclusion to
engagement and representation. The German union IG Metall, for example, traditionally refused to
organize workers dispatched from temporary work agencies, on the grounds that this would give these
agencies legitimacy. Realizing that agency work had become a permanent feature in metal engineering
and undermined the bargaining position of its core membership, the union started a vigorous ‘Equal
Work - Equal Pay’ campaign during which quite a few agency workers joined the union (Benassi and
Dorigatti, 2015). Around 2014, trade unions in the Czech and Slovak car industry, where agency work is
very widespread, hesitantly revised their policies and tried to combine their traditional policy of protecting
their core (paying) membership among workers with permanent contracts with attempts to represent
and improve the position of temporary agency workers (Bernaciak and Kahancová, 2017). More explicitly
inspired by the ‘organizing model’ imported from the United States, many European trade unions engaged
in organizing campaigns among workers with temporary contracts and in precarious positions, some
of which were quite successful: security guards in Hamburg, call centre workers in Austria, cleaners
and meatpackers in the Netherlands, workers in fast food outlets and shopping centers in France,
retail workers in Poland, sales workers in Sweden, hotel workers in Ireland and meatpackers in the
United Kingdom (Berntsen, 2015; Connolly, Marino, and Martinez Lucio, 2016; Czarzasty, Gajewska, and
Mrozowicki, 2014; Holtgrewe and Doellgast, 2012; Murphy and Turner, 2016; Tapia and Turner, 2013).
Some of these campaigns were modeled on the successful ‘Justice for Janitors’ campaign in the United
States (Erickson et al., 2002).
The fact that temporary agency work and temporary employment has become the reality for many if not
most young people is another powerful reason why unions have changed their policies. Given the ageing
of union membership, especially but not only in industry, unions urgently need to recruit more young
people, for instance by paying attention to changes in the school-to-work transition and the increase
in atypical employment patterns. This is one of the reasons why Japanese unions have changed their
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 37
attitude towards part-time workers, most of whom are young, female and with limited employment
protection. Their recruitment campaigns towards part-time workers met with some success, but also
with many obstacles due the enterprise structure of unions, a problem that also comes up in the case
of the Republic of Korea. Enterprise unions often limit their recruitment to regular workers and fail to
contribute to campaigns for more inclusive membership policies of the sectoral union federations to
which they belong (Jeong, 2001; Lee, 2010).
Figure 11: Union density rates, temporary v. permanent, and part-time v. full-time jobs, 2015-16
temporary permanent
90
Union density rate (% employees
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Ja A
Me ce
Fin m
n
Ch d
Sw taly
ec ia
erl a
Tu in
Sl t ria
Ire da
Fr d
No en
Hu p of
ep
Po ia
Ze K
d
Au rk
,R a
Sl nia
Gr ey
itz ael
Ko sta ia
Ca ina
De any
Lit ary
Au u gal
ds
Po ce
Ge land
Be ay
o
US
pa
la n
la n
th aki
n
rea Ric
a li
lan
xic
w U
Cz In d
en
a
an
Co ton
u
a
rk
na
rw
ed
ee
hR
a la
an
Sp
a
Sw Isr
lgi
ng
nm
I
e
st r
rm
Ne ov
hu
ov
er
rt
Es
Ne
part-time full-time
90
Union density rate (% employees
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Ja A
Me ce
Fin m
n
Ch d
Sw taly
erl a
ec ia
Sl t ria
Tu in
Ire da
No en
Fr d
Hu p of
ep
Ze K
d
Po ia
Au rk
,R a
Sl nia
Gr ey
itz ael
Ca ina
Ko sta ia
De any
ds
Lit ary
Au u gal
Po ce
Ge land
Be ay
o
US
pa
la n
la n
th aki
n
rea Ric
a li
lan
xic
w U
Cz In d
en
a
an
u
Co ton
a
rk
na
rw
ed
ee
hR
a la
an
Sp
a
Sw Isr
lgi
ng
nm
I
rm
e
st r
Ne ov
hu
ov
er
rt
Es
Ne
The average union density rate for the countries in Figure 11 is 30 per cent for permanent and 14 per
cent for temporary workers. Across these countries, permanent workers are 4.2 times more likely
to be unionized, with the biggest deficits in unionization of temporary workers showing in Denmark,
Greece, Hungary, India, Lithuania, Mexico, Poland, Slovenia and Spain. The differences are rather small
in countries as diverse as Canada, Ireland, Italy, New Zealand and Turkey. There are many possible
explanations for this, including differences in legal employment protection, union recruitment policies
or the concentration of temporary workers in particular sectors or among young people, who are less
unionized. But why is Denmark – with its famous ‘flexicurity’, relatively flexible open-ended employment
contracts and inclusive collective bargaining structure – in the first group? The answer may be found in
changes in the country’s unemployment insurance system.
The exceptionally high union density rates in Denmark, Iceland, Finland and Sweden (but not Norway)
have been attributed to a particular form of voluntary unemployment insurance known as the Ghent
system. Heavily subsidized by the state and administered by union funds, it strongly motivates workers
to join a union. Belgium has a partial Ghent system: while unemployment insurance is compulsory, trade
unions have retained an important role in the provision of benefits (Van Rie, Marx and Horemans, 2011;
Vandaele, 201). Contrary to the negative association between unemployment and union membership
in most countries, unionization in these Ghent countries tends to increase under conditions of rising
unemployment (Checchi and Visser, 2005). Western (1997) has shown that the Ghent system is particularly
beneficial for unions representing manual workers.
38 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
Recent reforms have weakened the link between union-provided unemployment insurance and union
membership. Governments have created ‘open’ unemployment funds, not linked to the unions in Finland
(1992), Denmark (2002), and Sweden (2005). These funds tend to be cheaper and attractive to younger
workers, especially in Finland (Böckerman and Uusitalo, 2006), whereas in Denmark they have created
space for new kinds of ‘cheaper unions’ outside the mainstream and not involved in collective bargaining.
In Sweden, the government has raised unemployment insurance contributions and introduced experience
rating, impacting blue-collar union members in particular. Tax rebates on fund fees were abolished or
capped, again hitting those unions with lower-paid and manual workers the most (Kjellberg and Ibsen,
2016). Many funds charge the same fees whether workers are part-time or full-time, temporary or
permanent. It is therefore plausible that part-time and temporary workers in particular, usually with
lower pay, are ‘priced’ out of fund and union membership. In Belgium, unemployment insurance reform
is on the government’s agenda, but has been blocked (Vandaele, 2017).
Kjellberg (2018) gives the example of Sweden’s hotel and restaurant workers’ union. After reforms and
the abolishment of tax rebates, the monthly fund fee increased from 58 Swedish kronor (SEK) in 2006
to SEK 430 in 2009. In the hotel and restaurant sector, many workers have part-time or fixed-term jobs,
many are young and foreign-born, and labour turnover is very high. It comes as no surprise that many
save on union membership. Union density among hotel and restaurant employees fell from 52 per cent
in 2006 to 40 per cent in 2008, and 27 per cent in 2017. We see similar decreases among temporary and
part-time workers in Denmark and Finland.
Overall, the gap in union density rates between part-time and full-time workers has become smaller
in most countries. Currently, full-time workers are twice as likely to join a union as part-time workers,
but this difference becomes smaller if we leave out people working very few hours per week, i.e. fewer
than 12 hours. It is not clear why somebody working 20 or 24 hours per week would be less inclined
to join a union than somebody working 36 or 40 hours, supposing that fee payments and benefits are
prorated based on the number of hours worked. Not all unions have implemented such an approach.
Another hypothesis is that part-timers give priority to a different set of life-interests, in which unions do
not figure. Lastly, some unions have been late in discovering part-time work. For instance, in Estonia or
Poland, part-time work is still rather new, often involuntary and marginal, and unions have no tradition
of recruiting part-time workers. Comparing Greek and Italian trade unions in the telecom industry, which
employs many temporary, part-time (‘on call’) workers, Kornelakis and Voskeritsian (2016) found quite
different approaches, with Italian unions in a successful bid to include part-time workers and Greek
unions struggling to retain to workers with regular and full-time contracts.
In the OECD area, employers and own-account workers made up 13 per cent of all formally registered
jobs in 2016, compared with 85 per cent held by employees and 2 per cent by unpaid family workers. Since
2000, self-employment has increased modestly, though in some countries there has been a spectacular
rise of ‘own-account’ work – 25 per cent in Estonia and the Czech Republic, 33 per cent in France, 40 per
cent in Chile, 46 per cent in the United Kingdom, 55 per cent in Israel; 69 per cent in the Netherlands
(OECD, 2018). This includes jobs in construction, road haulage and commercial services, especially jobs
in financial services, business consulting, and organization advising. It is tempting to link some of these
jobs to Internet-based forms of work and contracting. However, most growth in self-employment took
place in the years before 2008 and was nearly wiped out during the Great Recession.
In addition to greater job and income insecurity, self-employed workers are likely to receive fewer work-
related benefits than most employees. This is the case notably for unemployment benefits, eligibility for
work injury benefits, as well as for sickness and maternity benefits (OECD, 2018). Less than 5 per cent
of the self-employed in the European Working Conditions Survey describe themselves as ‘dependent’
self-employed (Williams and Horodnic, 2018), but the extent to which these answers are actually wishful
thinking, we will never know. A group of labour experts in the EU concluded that after undeclared work,
dependent self-employment is the second most common form of work associated with precarious work.
Kalleberg (2018) defines ‘precarious work’ as “work that is uncertain, unstable, and insecure,” in which
“employees bear the risks of work … and receive limited social benefits and statutory entitlements”. Lack
of control, individually or collectively, over working conditions, wages, working hours or pace of work;
the absence of protection by law or collective agreements regarding occupational health and safety and
discrimination or denial of rights normally available to workers in an employment relationship contribute
to precariousness. There is a large overlap with what has been described as informal work, but there is
also precarious work in the formal sector and among employees (Mosoetsa, Stillerman and Tilly, 2016).
Examples include hospital nurses being re-classified as independent contractors in Poland in order to
circumvent the European Working Time Directive (Kaminska and Kahancová, 2017), and Polish Ryanair
pilots who, like the pilots of the national airline LOT, are being subcontracted as self-employed, working
variable hours without the rights accruing to workers under the law.21 In Poland, the self-employed
cannot form or join a union. However, following a 2015 ruling of the Polish Constitutional Tribunal, the
law will be amended to the effect that individuals working as self-employed or with service contracts for
defined tasks will gain the right to found and join trade unions (Kaminska, 2018).
Self-employed professionals, working alone or with staff, are also represented through business
associations, commercial chambers and professional associations of all kinds. Some groups (freelance
journalists and artists, semi-independent doctors, lawyers or architects) may be quite well organized,
others (independent building contractors, IT specialists, business consultants, drivers, platform workers)
much less (Ackers 2015). In Northern Europe, there has always been a strong element of unionism among
professionals. Naturally, unions tend to concentrate on the ‘dependent’ or ‘disguised’ self-employed,
those without other people working for them and dependent on one or very few contract sources. Trade
unions have responded to the rise of ‘atypical workers’ and new ‘dependent independent workers’ in
construction, transport and trade by setting up special unions or sections within unions, for instance in
Italy, the Netherlands, Austria and Cyprus (Pernicka and Blaschke, 2006; Benassi and Vlandas, 2016;
Pulignano, Gervasi and Franceschi, 2016). Some of these initiatives date from the mid-1990s.
Generally, these initiatives have met with rather modest success in terms of membership (Pedersini,
2010), but they are important symbolically, because they signal that the unions are open to change. Some
of the new self-employed are in vulnerable positions, under-insured and with unstable income, as was
revealed in the 2008 recession when many contracts suddenly ended and were not renewed. But there
were also those that did quite well and might be described as people who are “proud of their skills (…)
who want to develop themselves” and only join if “the union adopts the attitude to support them in their
aspiration” (Dutch union leader, cited in Schulze Bischoff and Schmidt, 2007). Moving from an “it should
not be allowed” attitude to a “how can we help you?” approach is a big step for many unions.
40 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
workers (ALRN, 2003). In recent years, unions have made an effort and there are encouraging examples,
especially but not only in Africa, of unions finding ways to organize or help organize workers in the
informal sectors, especially in transport, tourism and security (LO/FTF, n.d.). Organizing informal workers
was never going to be easy (Bonner and Spooner, 2011). Without a standard workplace around which
the organization process can coalesce, many informal workers are situated in scattered, individualized
workplaces or homes, or they are on the move (street hawkers, waste pickers, bikers and taxi drivers).
In the absence of an employment relationship or where that relationship is disguised, most of them
fall outside the legal framework for labour and union rights. Furthermore, often there is no employer
with whom to engage for collective bargaining purposes. Where an employment relationship does exist,
for instance for day-labourers in agriculture or construction, or home-based garment workers, the
workplaces are often so scattered, small or ‘hidden’ in individual households that workers lack the power
to confront employers, who often operate through harsh ‘middlemen’.
Solidarity does not come easy to own-account workers who are in competition with each other over
contracts and clients. They may come together for specific reasons, for instance when they want to
challenge the authorities in crisis situations, but unity of purpose and collective action is often short-
lived and fragile. Building a lasting organization usually requires the help, leadership and subsidies of
established trade unions and sponsors. Migrant workers form another large group of informal workers.
Often undocumented and wanting to operate ‘under the radar’, they are particularly insecure and
vulnerable to exploitation and harassment and do not always fit in with traditional union culture. Finally,
failing attempts to collect dues from people who have little to spare is a recurrent issue in organizing
workers in the informal economy. A strategy of cross-subsidizing within the broader union movement
has its limits, although there are remarkable examples of teachers’ unions, often the best endowed,
engaging in helping to establish unions in the informal sector, for instance in Ghana or Sierra Leone (LO/
FTF, n.d.; Schurman and Eaton, 2012). The problem of sustaining membership exclusively through a dues
system among workers who never have sufficient income to live on impedes union growth and leads
to a reduction of appropriate services or, if a strategy of fundraising is adopted to pay for this, excessive
donor dependency.
Gallin (2001) distinguishes between two approaches to organizing informal sector workers: either unions
expand their domain, or informal sector workers form their own union-like associations or cooperatives.
The Self-Employed Women’s Association (SEWA) of India, founded in 1972 and the largest organization
of informal workers with nearly two million registered members in 2013, is the most prominent example
of the second approach. In the first approach, trade unions extend their field of activity to include informal
sector workers, as did the TUC in Ghana or COSATU in South Africa in 2000. Around the same time, unions
in the clothing and garment industry in Australia and Canada began to organize home-workers. There
are also examples of union confederations setting up a special association or union for informal sector
workers, as in Senegal (transport) or Hong Kong, where the main union assisted in the establishment
of the Federation of Asian Domestic Workers Unions (FADWU) with mostly Filipino and Thai women
(Swider 2000). Unions in Sierra Leone, with the help of the teachers’ unions, promoted several bikers’
unions. In Kenya, after decades of union decline and a shrinking formal sector due to massive lay-offs,
outsourcing and casualization, the strongest and best organized union confederation in the region has in
recent years refocused on the informal sector. It has gained seven new affiliates since 2015 and expanded
to include 2.7 million members, just 650,000 of whom are in the formal, mainly public sector. To sum up,
in recent years there has been impressive membership growth among workers in the informal sectors,
especially in Africa, among bikers, taxi drivers, street vendors and among garment workers, for instance
in Nigeria and several South-East Asian countries. Other examples include agricultural workers and day
labourers in Nepal, Honduras, the Dominican Republic, Bolivia, Colombia and Paraguay. Figure 12 shows
how in some countries (Kenya, Burundi, Swaziland, Togo, Sierra Leone) informal sector workers make
up the majority of union members.
Not all attempts to organize informal workers go smoothly. Experiences in South Africa and Brazil are
mixed, and in India organizing has mostly come from outside the union movement. In South Africa, the
42 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
initially successful campaign of the transport workers’ union to organize minibus drivers – a critical
element in the failing public transport system – collapsed under fierce intimidation by employers. The
textile workers’ union, having lost thousands of members due to factory closures after tariff reductions,
has extended representation to home-based workers. The Mining Union is active in organizing informal
contract workers in the building industry. Xenophobia and violence against migrants have been the ugly
companions to the unions’ struggle to organize street vendors and security workers (Gordon and Maharaj,
2014). In the 1990s, some Brazilian unions attempted to organize informal workers, but their efforts were
rather ineffective, characterized by a marginal organizational and financial investment (Ramalho, 2010;
Frangi and Routh, 2014).
80
70
Share (%) of total membership
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
rra ya
e
ay
ia
Co ras
ini bia
ep
ilip ia
es
ia
ia
a
bia
da
Zim ger
Ma e
za wi
Rw e
da
nin
Sw ndi
nd
go
pa
on
gu
an
bw
u
liv
es
Ind
an
Sie Ken
gu
Mo la
pin
an
an
nR
ila
biq
To
Do lom
ru
Be
Ne
u
Ni
Gh
Le
ra
Bo
on
nz
ba
nd
ra
az
Ug
Za
Bu
m
ca
ca
Ta
Ind
Pa
Ho
Ni
Ph
m
In many countries there are legal bans on organizing workers in the informal economy, such as
home-based and domestic workers or workers in agriculture, for example in Pakistan. There are also
encouraging developments. In Jordan, legal changes in 2010-11 ended the prohibition for migrant
workers to join a union, and migrants now make up 12 per cent of total union membership. In 2015 the
first official migrant domestic worker network, with its main basis in the garment industry and nearly
half its membership female, was formed to advocate for full rights for home-workers. In Lebanon,
domestic workers, whether nationals or migrants, are excluded from coverage under the labour law
and are vulnerable to rights violations. After years of campaigning, the National Federation of Workers’
and Employees’ Unions in Lebanon (FENASOL), with the assistance of NGOs and the ITUC, created a
Domestic Workers’ Union, which is described by the ILO’s Bureau of Worker Activities (ACTRAV) as an
“excellent example of workers of various nationalities coming together in a restrictive legislative context.”
There has been a gradual rapprochement between the many hybrid forms of informal workers’
organizations and the official trade union movement. Many union confederations have opened up to the
affiliation of informal sector workers and their organizations. This process was encouraged by the ITUC
when it was founded in 2006. SEWA has been the trailblazer and is now a full member of the ITUC. While
autonomous organizations of informal workers may or may not self-define as trade unions, trade unions
and union confederations have taken an increased interest in the organization and representation of
workers in the informal economy, directly or by building alliances and helping to build sustainable unions.
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 43
the world and online (for instance, editing or graphic design), others are local or require physical presence
(food delivery, housecleaning, taxi driving or photography). What all these forms have in common is that
they enable individuals to operate with relative autonomy outside traditional structures defined by labour
law, without working time limits, minimum wages or defined liabilities.
Employers need not invest in a workplace or provide any tools. Unlike the loss of supervisory capacity
that resulted from putting-out, in online networks performance can be rendered transparent and
workers subject to electronic oversight (Finkin, 2016). In particular, platforms that specialize in work
that can be done remotely, with jobs broken down into a series of tasks or assignments, are a further
potentially revolutionary step in the rise of a global labour market for online work and “a new strain of
globalization in its rawest form”.24 Online crowdsourcing for activities that can be executed anywhere
can draw from a global pool of workers, with the possibility of pitting national labour laws against each
other and putting participants from high-wage economies in direct competition with those accustomed
to wages and working conditions that would be unacceptable in any domestic employment relationship.
Crowdsourcing that requires local and physical performance shares many of the above features, but here
the application of national labour regulations is possible, as Uber, the best-known company of this type,
has discovered.
The potential disruptive effects of platforms on labour markets are large and outweigh their importance
as a current source of employment. Amidst various attempts to come to grips with platform work through
unions, cooperatives, works councils and Internet tools, we are only at the beginning and much has yet
to be invented. Advocates contend that platform work can economically benefit socially marginalized
groups including the unemployed, geographically isolated, and refugees, although this does not seem
to have been important in the case of Uber (Hall and Krueger, 2018). However, if relied on for one’s main
income, jobs in the platform economy come without a guaranteed living wage, paid holidays, access to
pensions, insurance or healthcare schemes, minimum or maximum working hours or the security of a
steady salary (De Stefano, 2016).
From the perspective of organizing platform workers, it is useful to draw a parallel with own-account
workers, temporary employment (OECD, 2016) or work in the informal sector. Most platforms classify
workers as independent contractors. In many jurisdictions, this classification precludes workers from
forming or joining a union and engaging in collective bargaining. Even where unionization is possible, the
predominance of non-standard work arrangements may present challenges to achieving effective union
recognition and bargaining. Thus, platform workers experience myriad challenges when attempting
to build a collective voice and structure and create lasting and enforceable employment regulation.
The ways in which many platform markets currently function raise issues with regard to fundamental
workers’ rights (De Stefano, 2017). Some platforms like Uber deny a role as employer, whereas others
like Hello Alfred (chores), Shyp (shipping), and Muchery (food delivery) recognize providers in their
markets as employees. In the United States, there is an ongoing legal battle over whether Uber drivers
should be considered as employees or independent contractors. In 2016 in the United Kingdom, two Uber
drivers took the company to court on behalf of a larger group, arguing successfully that Uber’s 40,000
drivers were not self-employed and should receive the minimum wage and paid holidays. Although Uber
classifies its drivers as self-employed, drivers complain that the company nonetheless treats them like
regular employees, seeking to control their working patterns and remuneration. In 2017, a protest by
platform workers in Switzerland, backed by the unions, resulted in improvements in wages and working
conditions, and recognition that they were not ‘independent contractors’ (Vandaele, 2018). In Bologna,
Italy, a charter has been signed between the local riders’ union, the three main trade union confederations,
the city council and the local food delivery platforms Sgnam and MyMenu, establishing a framework of
minimum standards for remuneration, working time and insurance. As platforms like Deliveroo, Foodora
and JustEat have not signed the charter, the mayor of Bologna has called on customers to boycott them
(Vandaele, 2018). However, a recent case in Italy brought against Foodora confirmed the self-employed
status of its gig-workers (Eurofound, 2018).
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 45
Reclassifying independent contractors as employees has been one of the classic union responses to
the spreading platform economy (Johnston and Land-Kazlauskas, 2018), but it is already clear that this
will not always work and not every gig-worker will be convinced. Another approach is to ensure that
all workers, whatever their status, are brought under the basic provisions of labour and social security
law, and have the same social and fundamental organizing and collective bargaining rights (Adam and
Deakin, 2014). This would reduce the incentive for companies and platforms to push workers out of the
most expensive employee classification and into independent contractor status. In order to achieve this,
independent contractors must be permitted to self-organize, affiliate with unions and negotiate without
being accused of violating anti-trust legislation.
These parallels can also be seen in the myriad of organizing responses, from worker and community
centers to works councils, cooperatives and proper trade unions. The development of ‘workers’ centers’
in the United States – in some cases incubated by labour unions and in others launched by advocates
and activists who viewed conventional unions as poorly suited to organizing or representing excluded
workers – is an example (Fine, 2006; Milkman, 2013). While the gains that worker centers have achieved
are not specific to the platform economy, the approaches used for non-standard worker organizing have
potential applications relevant to platform workers. The National Day Laborers Organizing Network in
the United States stresses the similarities between the work of day labourers and platform work. As a
matter of fact, day labourers have begun to see their jobs move to online platforms through apps like
Taskrabbit and Handy. The Independent Workers’ Union of Great Britain (IWGB) is another example of a
cross-over. This organization operates outside the Trade Union Congress (TUC) and was founded for the
purpose of supporting and organizing low wage and immigrant workers. In August 2016 when Deliveroo
informed on-demand delivery workers in an email that their pay rates would be lowered, workers
protested in front of its head office. The Workers’ Union attended the protests and has been organizing
alongside the workers ever since. In considering a move toward formal union recognition, the union has
taken a geographic approach to organizing workers in certain areas of London, delineating job sites by
the delivery zones built into Deliveroo’s app.
Some unions are offering dedicated services to self-employed workers in platform markets. For
example, the Freelancers Union in the United States, with 275,000 members, acts as an advocacy group
and provides insurance schemes to its members, which include traditional freelancers and gig-workers.
As a so-called ‘minority union’ it does not have bargaining rights under the National Labour Regulation
Act. The New York Taxi Workers Alliance of 2011, the first AFL-CIO affiliate of non-standard workers, is
another example of a non-certified minority union without collective bargaining rights.
Germany’s IG Metall union has launched a crowdworker website (www.faircrowdwork.org) and another
big German union, Ver.di, is developing legal and support services tailored to platform workers.
FairCrowdwork.org asks workers what they like and don’t like about the platforms through which they
work, and make that information public. With the resources and backing of IG Metall, the concept of an
online forum and employer rating system can be scaled up to provide insight about what it is like to work
for different platforms. The union has also developed a code of conduct signed by eight Germany-based
platforms, in which they pledge to adhere to local wage standards (Vandaele, 2018). IG Metall’s initiative is
given greater weight through its cooperation with various European unions. One such partner is Unionen,
Sweden’s largest union. Unionen has about 10,000 independent contractors or self-employed workers
among its 660,000 members. This union sees nothing wrong with the idea of online labour platforms, but
believes they need standards and envisions creating a new type of institution, jointly owned by the social
partners and tasked with designing and enforcing industry standards. In order for firms to participate in
this institution, they must have a collective bargaining agreement in place.
In Austria, Foodora’s app-based delivery workers have recently come together to form a works council
with the support of Vida, the union representing workers in transport and services. Deliveroo workers
in Germany (Cologne, Berlin) have taken a similar approach, in this case with the help of the union
for food and restaurant workers. Collective agreements with platforms have been signed in Sweden,
46 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
between Bzzt and the transport workers’ union (Johnston and Land-Kazlauskas, 2018). In Denmark,
Hilfr.dk, a platform for cleaning in private homes, signed a collective agreement in April 2018 with 3F,
a Danish trade union. The new collective agreement will guarantee people who work on the platform
sick pay, holiday allowances and a contribution to their pension. It also lets workers opt for employee or
independent status.
A challenging experiment for the unions is provided by SMart (Société mutuelle pour les artistes), the
largest actor providing services to project-based workers in Belgium. Launched in the early 2000s as a
multi-purpose organization (work agency, cooperative, union, employer) that managed the paperwork
and contracts of a few hundred artists and freelancers, Smart had grown into an organization of nearly
80,000 project-based workers in 2015, amidst the misgivings of the Belgian trade unions that Smart
facilitated ‘social dumping’ by normalizing a new kind of casual work (Vandaele, 2018; Xhauflair et al.,
2018). Having transformed from a not-for-profit company into a cooperative, Smart now claims to act
as an employer for its members. Its biggest deal came in 2016, when it signed a joint protocol with two
food delivery platforms, Take Eat Easy and Deliveroo. The protocol guaranteed a minimum number of
hours paid after the first call, insurance packages for bike couriers and reimbursement of professional
expenses. A few months later, when Take Eat Easy went bankrupt and left hundreds of bike couriers
unpaid, SMart managed to reclaim the last (post-bankruptcy) payment for those bikers who had become
its members, enabling SMart to show how seriously it took its employer’s responsibility (Xhauflair et al.,
2018). In November 2017 Deliveroo unilaterally cancelled the agreement, which led to a union-supported
response of a new ‘couriers collective’, which organized a protest rally in Brussels and, in January 2018,
a strike which drew the attention and support of several other unions and courier organizations in Europe
(Vandaele, 2018).
I. THE STATE OF THE UNIONS AND THE FUTURE OF WORK 47
4 / Summary
Since 2000, unionization trends have declined in all but two world regions, North Africa and South
America. There are large differences in unionization across the world if we consider the total employed
labour force, including persons working as informal workers. The lowest unionization rates are found
in the poorest regions (Sub-Saharan Africa, South Asia), but there are exceptions, for instance the
extremely low unionization rates in rich Arab countries. De-industrialization of the economy has been
a two-fold process that translates into fewer jobs in industry and fewer union members in the jobs that
remain. This process affects all countries, albeit from different starting levels and with different intensity.
Since new entrants or those losing their job in industry are more likely to find employment in commercial
services, the gap in unionization rates between industry and commercial services foreshadows further
union decline and a structural challenge for the unions.
In the past thirty or forty years, de-unionization in developed countries has been marked by a generational
change of less unionized but better educated younger workers replacing an older and much larger
cohort of unionized workers. The data for examining this process in developing and emerging countries
is lacking, but surely missing from these countries is the demographic pressure of an ageing society,
like in Europe or Japan. Since the 1980s there has been a move away from the standard employment
relationship. This decline, as a norm and pattern-setter for non-unionized firms as well, has a parallel
in the shrinkage of the formal sector in Africa, Asia and Latin America. Young people everywhere are
more likely to find themselves in temporary and part-time jobs, or in informal and casual jobs. Part-time
and temporary workers are less unionized everywhere compared to workers employed full-time and
with open-ended contracts. The shrinkage of the formal (public) sector has led to steep de-unionization
in many developing and emergent economies, creating an urgent need for unions to seek a broader
membership basis by expanding into the informal sector. Recently, many unions have started to organize
informal sector workers or stepped up cooperation efforts with informal workers’ associations outside
the union movement. Many unions in developed countries have increased their efforts to organize
temporary, part-time, and work agency workers, and opened their ranks to own-account workers.
Arguably, together with the decline of industrial membership, the biggest change in trade unions during
the past decades has been the rise of female membership.
Globalization has generated millions of industrial and service jobs in the Global South, but it has not
created an upsurge in unionization in these countries. It has also put pressure on workers and unions in
their traditional industrial strongholds in developed countries. Labour migration has increased and unions
have become more open to migrant workers, but the challenge of integration remains. Platform work
organized through digital intermediaries is still limited as a source of employment, but is growing rapidly
and transforming the employment relationship. Amidst various attempts to come to grips with platform
work through unions, cooperatives, works councils and Internet tools, this trend has only just begun and
much has yet to be invented. Platform work is mostly found in commercial services – retailing, hotel,
restaurants, catering and tourism, private road transport, business services, rentals and work agencies,
communication, financial services, security, and administrative services – where even among workers
with standard employee contracts, union density rates are usually very low.
48 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
II. Explaining the
Differences in Unionization
In the previous section, I discussed changes in union membership and union density related to changes
in the structure of employment and the nature of the employment relationship, together with pressures
that can be attributed to technological change, digitalization, globalization and migration. In this
section, some additional factors are explored that may help explain why unions have fared better in
some countries than in others. I begin with looking at development, income and urbanization levels,
then examine some features of the labour market such as the share of agriculture or industry and
the size of the informal sector. I then move on to look at factors that might affect the social fabric and
political context in which unions operate, like ethnic strife and labour rights violations, and conclude by
considering some institutional features related to collective bargaining, union recognition, workplace
representation and insurance delivery, as well as the unity or fragmentation of unions themselves. I will
present these factors one by one and consider how they are interrelated. I have taken the union density
rate calculated over the entire employed population as the variable to be explained, as this turns out to
be the most reliable measure in low- and middle-income countries, with the lowest risk of error due to
misclassification of worker or employee status.
as well as to unions, since workers in the informal sector have far fewer resources and opportunities to
organize and engage in social dialogue, and are less likely to benefit from job security, regular income
and access to social protection than their wage and salaried counterparts. In studies using time-series
data, it has been shown that the rise of labour market participation with a growing share of temporary
jobs is contributing to a decline in unionization (Checchi and Visser, 2005).
70
60
Union density (% total employment)
50
40
30
20
10
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
% employment in informal economy
2 / Ethnic diversity
Ethnic diversity and conflict have been studied in relation to economic growth, civil organization, trust
and social capital. This concept can range from extreme manifestations of civil war and genocide to
periodic ethnic riots to everyday diversity, ethnic allegiances and integration of minorities and migrants
(Kanbur, Rajaram, and Varshney 2011). It is a topic that has gained in importance with the surge of global
migration flows. Horwitz and Horwitz (2007) note that in any circumstance, ‘diversity’ is a double-edged
sword: it creates a richer pool of expertise and experience, and thus potential for innovation and growth,
but it raises the costs of coordination and leads to problems of trust, and thus potential for irreconcilable
divisions and conflict. Applied to trade unions, one can see both sides of the coin: the experiences that
migrants bring with them – crucial in the early days of unionism, and potentially even today – and the
problems of mutual understanding and competition over jobs and wages.
II. EXPLAINING THE DIFFERENCES IN UNIONIZATION 51
Presumably, trade unions in ethnically diverse societies face a more challenging task than unions in more
homogenous societies. The various waves of migration and resulting ethnic diversity have often been
cited as one of the reasons for the comparably low level of unionization in the United States. Clearly, there
must be other reasons as well, given the consistently higher unionization rate of its Northern neighbor
Canada, or in immigration societies like New Zealand and Australia. To be sure, ethnic diversity captures a
wider source of native or domestic cleavages and potential conflict unrelated to migration. Here, I simply
wanted to check whether such cleavages have reduced union success in organizing workers. Before
proceeding with the result, I should add that countries currently or recently in a state of (civil) war are not
included. In Afghanistan, Iraq, Syria, Yemen, Sudan, South Sudan, Somalia, Libya, Chad, the two Congos
and Haiti it was impossible to verify union membership data.
60
50
Unionization lavel (total employment)
40
30
20
10
There appears to be a strong negative association between the mean level of ethnic diversity and the
mean level of unionization (red=-0,61, N=18) across world regions (Figure 14). Across countries, the
relationship is weaker (red=-0,37, N=125) due to within-region variations. Rather than diversity, it is
conflict which hampers union development. In fact, the negative relationship between ethnic diversity and
unionization is mostly driven by the twenty or thirty poorest countries, where strife curbs both economic
development and unionization. These countries are located in the regions where ethnic strife is most
intense: sub-Saharan Africa, the Middle East and parts of Asia. Clearly the highest levels of unionization
are reached in the most ethnically homogenous regions and countries: northern Europe, followed by
western and southern Europe. No association is perfect, however, and there are ethnically or linguistically
diverse countries with rather high levels of unionization (South Africa, Belgium, Brazil) and relatively
homogenous countries with low levels of unionization (Germany, Portugal, Poland). Moreover, ethnic
diversity, although changing as a result of demographics and migration, is not a promising candidate for
explaining changes in unionization over time.
52 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
70
60
Union density (% total employment)
50
40
30
20
10
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Index of Labour Rights (Kucera index)
II. EXPLAINING THE DIFFERENCES IN UNIONIZATION 53
with centralized, partly centralized and decentralized bargaining, there is a reasonably equal distribution
of countries at different levels of development. This gives some confidence that we actually identify the
effects of institutions on the level of unionization.
Centralization lowers the organizing costs of trade unions. Industry-wide bargaining allows unions
to establish sector-wide wages and limits the risk that ‘bad’ employers drive out ‘good’ employers. It
also alleviates the need for unions to seek and gain recognition in each firm, and makes unionization
of workers in small firms more feasible and less necessary. Under centralized bargaining conditions,
unions need only to organize and mobilize workers in large or strategic firms in order to set the pattern
for the entire industry. Unions can therefore worry less about the unionization of workers in small firms,
as long as these firms stay members in the employers’ federation that sign the national or sectoral
collective agreement, or as long as these agreements are legally extended to them (Hayter and Visser,
2018). This is one of the reasons why bargaining centralization and bargaining coverage rates are much
more strongly correlated (rcent/cov=0,78) than centralization and union density (rcent/dens=0,51) and also why
the gap between unionization in large and small firms can be significant under conditions of centralized
bargaining, an issue to which I shall return in the final section of this paper.
The second institution of importance is union recognition and union access to workplace representation.
This is often found to be the decisive factor, together with union involvement in the provision of
unemployment or health insurance. Uncontested workplace representation allows unions to concentrate
on issues of productivity, pacify employers, and police the ‘social custom’ of membership through direct
benefits and contacts in the workplace. This can be regulated in different ways. In some countries like
the United States or the United Kingdom, trade unions must fight for recognition on a firm-by-firm basis,
showing that they represent a majority among the workers they claim to represent. In other countries
such as Germany or Austria, workplace representation is indirectly guaranteed as a statutory right
through the mandated works council. Recognition can also be guaranteed by nationwide agreement
between the main union and the employers’ organization, as in Scandinavia. Compared to a statutory
obligation on employers, a central agreement signed by employers raises fewer issues of compliance
and may therefore be considered a stronger guarantee of union recognition and access rights. Using a
simple ‘0’ (firm-based), ‘1’ (statutory) and ‘2’ (agreement) coding, it turns out that recognition of union
representation rights is strongly correlated to the union density rate, raccess=0,69.
Centralized bargaining and guaranteed recognition and access reduce the organizing costs and pressure
of ‘non-union’ labour in negotiations. However, when wages, rights and conditions are guaranteed
equally to union members and non-members, unions are faced with a free-rider problem. In this case,
it is important that unions are able to put pressure on workers to contribute to the common cause,
through ‘closed shops’ or other forms of compulsory membership or the help of ‘members only’
benefits. As most forms of compulsory membership – as found in New Zealand or Australia for instance
– have been discontinued or declared unlawful, other policies that tie members to the union may have
become more important, for instance unions that offer unemployment insurance, health insurance, or
job counseling to their members. As was discussed earlier, examples of government sponsored union-
based unemployment insurance funds can be found in Sweden, Finland, Denmark and Iceland, in a
modified form in Belgium, in Italian agriculture or in the Dutch building industry; or, relating to health
insurance coverage, in Argentina, Israel or Taiwan until 1995; and for some elements of social insurance,
pensions and firm-related benefits, in Tanzania, Egypt and North Africa; and before 1989 in unions under
Communism. The fact that membership levels drop rapidly once state support for such benefit systems
are withdrawn, as happened in Israel in 1995, proves that they work as a powerful incentive for joining the
union and retaining membership. Across countries there is a very clear positive relationship between the
existence of union-related unemployment or health insurance and union density (rins=0,67).
II. EXPLAINING THE DIFFERENCES IN UNIONIZATION 55
Finally, I have looked into the effects of tripartism, defined as the existence of tripartite social and economic
councils and regular consultations between unions, employers and government over (minimum) wages
and social policies, in addition to bipartite social dialogue and central-level coordination of wage policies
between central unions and employers’ federations. It turns out that tripartism is not (rtri=0,09) and bipartite
coordination is (rbi=0,51) correlated with union density. Bipartite coordination is strongly interrelated to
employer recognition of workplace access rights of the unions and with bargaining centralization, while
tripartism is unrelated. Admittedly, tripartism is very difficult to measure, and formal features (whether a
council exists, its membership, number of consultations) may hide different practices.
Since the aforementioned institutions work together as a package, it is problematic to include them in a
multivariate analysis. Instead, I have chosen to build a simple additive scale or index of institutional union
security based on four features (centralization, recognition, insurance, and bipartite coordination), each
with a possible score ranging from ‘0’ to ‘2’, and starting from a base value of ‘1’. This yields a total score
that can range from 1 to 9. Figure 16 shows how this index is related to union density for 96 countries
(R2index=0,62). All other things being equal, each one-point increase on the index increases the average
density rate by nearly four percentage points.
60
Union density rate (% of employed labour force)
50
R² = 0.6162
40
30
20
10
00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10
Index of instituonal support for unions (0-10)
An institutional explanation as good as this one still leaves many unsolved issues. At any level of
institutional union security, a wide range of outcomes is possible, as illustrated by Figure 16. For instance,
with no institutional security for the unions, the United States union density level is 10.4 per cent and that
of Canada, 28.4 per cent. Are there other unmeasured institutional features that are important for unions,
for instance the degree of employer hostility towards unions, political support or legal culture? There
are all believed to different between Canada and the United States, but are not picked up in the indicator.
At the other end, with much higher albeit different levels of institutional security, why are union density
rates in France, Germany and the Netherlands so much lower than the rate ‘predicted’ by the degree of
institutional security? Finally, it is important to stress that institutions are not exogenously given, but also
the outcome of union choices and policies, past and present.
56 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
organizing efforts are non-linear, that is, they are weakest when the union density rate is very low or very
high. The reason is that at very low density levels, unions lack the resources to mobilize (they need others
to help them, as we have shown in the case of African unions). At very high levels of union density, the
unions may think that the market for members is ‘saturated’ and that extraordinary efforts are needed
to convince the few remaining non-members who may be difficult to reach, have strong ideological or
religious convictions of not joining a union, or already benefit from the union through spill over-effects
(guaranteeing higher wages and better working conditions than would have been the case without
the union). What we can observe from the cross-national data is that there has been a slight tendency
(r=0,31) toward more union growth since 2000 (expressed as percentage increase in union density rates)
in countries where the density rate in 2000 was lowest. This is mainly the effect of the turnaround in union
organizing towards the informal sector in many developing countries. In developed economies, there is
no relationship between the level of unionization in 2000 and the extent of union growth or decline in the
following years.
Fragmentation and intense rivalry between trade union centers competing for members, influence and
attention are often associated with very low levels of unionization. Examples are found in the Philippines,
Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, Peru, Mexico, Chile, Poland, Hungary and France. At the opposite end there
are examples of impressive spurts in union growth following the (re-)unification of, or close cooperation
between different union centers, for instance in recent years in Tunisia and Uruguay, or half a century ago
in Finland and Italy. Too much competition – whether from tough employers or from rival unions or union
confederations that defend their respective ideologies in a fragmented union landscape – has debilitating
effects not only on union power but also on recruitment. In such a situation, unions typically concentrate on
vying for support from politics rather than building solutions together, and this discourages membership
because unions have little to offer. But union monopolies (of the old Communist kind, but also found
elsewhere) can be deadly for renewal and become associated with long-term decline.
Social movements, cooperatives, worker centers, minority unions and union-like organizations can be
the motor for organizing workers in the informal sector, platform-workers, women, young people and
precarious workers. The ‘forward momentum’ of women in unions, for instance, was due in large part to
the women’s movement in the 1960s and 1970s (Cook et al., 1984). Mainstream trade unions sometimes
need a ‘thorn in the flesh’ – small, independent or alternative organizations or movements that address
new issues and pioneer new approaches. Different unions specializing at organizing and representing
different segments and interests can raise the general level of unionization, as appears to have been
the case in Scandinavia where unions and union confederations of blue-collar workers, white-collar
workers, professionals and academics have existed and cooperated with one another for a long time.
58 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
III. Four possible futures
So far this paper has been devoted to the past and the present: the current state of the unions; how the
developments of industrial decline, technology, digitalization and globalization have changed employment
relations and trade union membership; and how current differences in union density and union organizing
can be explained. It is now time to look to the future. Where are trade unions heading? Will past trends
continue, worsen, or be reversed? As announced in the introduction, I will explore four scenarios or
possible futures for trade unions: marginalization, dualization, substitution, and revitalization. Each of
these futures is based on a selective and inevitably biased view of present and past developments. I shall
present the arguments in favor of a particular development or future, followed by the counterarguments.
In the concluding paragraph, I shall try to weigh the likelihood of each of these four scenarios.
1 / Marginalization
The idea that trade unions will gradually fade away and lose their relevance for regulating labour markets
is based on the extrapolation of current trends. If the decline of the past twenty to thirty years continues,
the survival of trade unions will be at risk by the middle of the century in many countries. Unions may fall
below a particular threshold – 10 per cent, 5 per cent, 2 per cent – after which sustainability will become
problematic.
After showing that the rate of decline in Australia has actually accelerated in the last decade, Gahan et al.
(2018) conclude that “if this rate of membership decline continues, by the end of the next decade unions
will represent just a few per cent of the Australian workforce, with most membership concentrated in
fewer industries.” This is followed by lower bargaining coverage and wage growth at historically low
levels. According to Pernot (2010), without a revival of unions among private sector workers, “unionism
in France is condemned either to resigning into playing a marginal role or into managing ever smaller
fringes of the public and administrative sector, decorated with some days of spectacular manifestation
without a follow-up”. Milkman (2013) argues that labour unions in the United States are back to where
they were before the 1930s and Roosevelt’s New Deal policies and the upsurge in industrial unionism.
With the level of union density in the private sector, at 6.4 per cent, as low as the union density rate in 1901
when there were no union members in the public sector, “the private sector in this country is now nearly
union-free, to a degree not seen in a century” (Rosenfeld, 2014). Based on this measurement, United
States unions are no stronger than many unions in developing countries, if we count, as we should, the
informal sector as (the largest) part of the private sector in these countries. But also in many developed
countries, for instance in Central and Eastern Europe, private sector union density rates are currently so
low that it means that unions have disappeared from large swatches of the economy.
Donado and Wälde (2002) claim that the long-term trends in unionization, as shown in Figure 17, follow
an inverse U-shape everywhere, even though in some countries union density rates peak later (Europe
versus the United States and Japan) and at higher levels (northern Europe versus the rest). One can
quarrel about ‘everywhere’, but the general picture shown in the eight panels of Figure 17 is one of
decline. Donado and Wälde interpret this as proof that trade unions have outlived their function as a
market-correcting institution and that the welfare state, international standard-setting bodies, education
and modern science have taken over. As I have shown in the preceding pages, the decline of the type
of collective voice and collective action embodied by trade unions is probably caused more by global
and technological changes in labour markets and in social and political institutions. In some cases, this
decline was exacerbated by trade unions’ belated response to the changes they were facing.
60 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
The Product Life Cycle theory offers another account of the rise and decline of unionism (see Bryson,
Gomez and Wilman, 2018). These authors start from the observation (in the United Kingdom) that, over
time, the share of workers demanding ‘voice’ has remained more or less constant, but that there has
been a huge shift from union-provided voice to employer-provided voice. They argue that ‘voice’, or some
mechanism to comment on and correct employers’ decision, is a generic need or ‘good’ that is demanded
by workers at all times and all places. Trade unions offer one particular solution to satisfy this need. In
so doing they always competed with other solutions or methods to provide voice to workers. Alternative
solutions may develop and take over. I will return to that possibility – replacement or substitution – in my
third scenario.
One of the specifics of trade unions is that they can organize and sustain strikes of a longer duration,
beyond walkouts, sit-ins, protests and rallies. However, as Milkman (2013) has pointed out, with the
decline of private sector unions, large industrial strikes have become rare. This trend began in the 1980s
(Shalev, 1992) and has been observed in nearly all developed countries. Striking has moved largely to
the public sector, but even where public sector strikes attracted large-scale participation and expressed
the frustrations of private sector workers as well, as in France, they did not translate into an upsurge
in unionization the way the large industrial strikes had in the past (Pernot, 2010). This is not unique to
France; similar large protests occurred in the Netherlands in 2004, in Greece in 2010 and in following
years, in Portugal in 2011 and 2012 and in Poland in 2013. This is not to say that all recent strikes failed.
There are also many examples of well-targeted strikes that spurred successful organizing campaigns,
and it is difficult to give a general recipe.
Probably the most alarming sign pointing towards further membership decline is the ageing of trade
union membership. Union ageing has been observed in nearly all developed countries. This is the effect
of lower unionization rates among young people compounded, in Europe or Japan, by demographic
change, with increasingly smaller cohorts of people entering the labour market. Earlier, I showed that
the ratio of the entrants’ rate of unionization compared to those close to leaving the labour market has
changed from 1:2 in the 1970s and 1980s to 1:4 in the 2010s, meaning that today, workers who leave the
labour market are four times as likely to be unionized than those who enter, if they find a job. On average,
in developed countries, of all employed union members, one in five is over 55 years old, whereas just one
in twenty is under 25. In some countries, for instance Denmark, Ireland or Belgium, the distribution is
less extreme, but the general picture is clear. In order to maintain current membership levels, unions in
developed countries must replace an estimated 3 to 4 per cent of their members each year – which would
still mean that unionization rates, set against and expanding working population, decrease. Membership
growth would require that unions somehow replicate the unionization rates among young people of the
1970s.
III. FOUR POSSIBLE FUTURES 61
Japan Korea Malaysia Philippines Turkey Russia Poland Czech Rep Hungary Slovakia
62 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
This is not likely, because new workers are increasingly less exposed to trade unions through social
networks at an early enough stage in their lives and careers. Early exposure is crucial because many of
the benefits that unions provide operate as an insurance and reveal themselves later, long after joining.
In this sense, unions are akin to what is known in consumer theory as an ‘experience good’ (Gomez and
Gunderson, 2004). This makes contact with colleagues, friends and parents who are themselves union
members very important. British and Dutch research has shown that if parents are union members, this
increases the likelihood that their children will also join a union (Bryson and Davies, 2018; Visser, 2002).
There is also ample evidence that ‘members make members’ (Waddington and Kerr, 2002). To encourage
and endorse union membership and maintain a ‘good’ reputation of taking part and contributing to the
collective effort, contact with colleagues who themselves are (visible) union members is crucial (Ibsen,
Toubøl and Jensen, 2017; Visser, 2002). But the likelihood that young people will find employment in
firms and workplaces where there are many union members, or where the union is highly visible, has
dramatically decreased. With declining unionization rates, there are fewer parents in each generation
who can transmit the benefit and values of belonging to a union to their offspring. Lower unionization
rates among young people mean that in each cohort, the share of workers who will never have first-hand
experience with a trade union increases. Booth, Budd and Munday (2010) found that in the United States
in the mid-1980s, 58 per cent of 23-year-olds had never been unionized. Roughly 20 years later, this
figure had increased to 71 per cent. The data for the United Kingdom show that never-membership has
increased from 23 per cent in the mid-1980s to over 50 per cent in 2005-6 (Bryson et al., 2017). Bryson
and Gomez (2005) have shown that it is this reduced likelihood of ever becoming a member, and not the
loss of existing members, which accounts for the United Kingdom’s decline in overall union membership
since the 1980s.
Emigration does not help. In Central and Eastern Europe, unemployment, low wages and emigration
have drained the unions of young people. In some countries like Estonia, Latvia or Hungary, there
are hardly any young people left in the unions. Korkut et al. (2017) point out that instead of increasing
union bargaining power by limiting supply, the departure of the more entrepreneurial young people has
stalled union renewal and threatens the intergenerational continuation of union activity in many sectors.
A joint study by the Friedrich Ebert Stiftung (FES) and the ILO makes the same point about the negative
consequences of emigration for unions in Lebanon.26 The departure of young people might become a
threat to trade unions in some African countries as well.
2 / Dualization
Like the marginalization scenario, dualization predicts that the trend towards more unstable and
precarious work in both the old and new platform economy will continue or even accelerate. The key
argument is that by acceding to employer demands, unions end up promoting the job security of their
‘insider’ members – professionals and workers in large firms with permanent contracts – potentially at
the expense of ‘outsiders’, those with temporary, casual or no jobs.
Although labour movements typically expound an ideology of ‘equal rights’, they sometimes have
little choice but to accept policies, reforms, compromises, productivity or job preservation coalitions in
defense of their core membership, which may weaken the position of outsiders (Emmenegger, 2014).
By means of illustration, without being very explicit about it, unions sometimes agree to deregulation in
low-skilled service sectors as a way to lower costs and defend the firm’s competitive position (Hassel,
2014). By implication, trade unions are accused of neglecting the plight of vulnerable workers (Standing,
2011). These arguments have been developed, in particular, to analyze the strategy and predicaments of
trade unions in Germany and France (Palier and Thelen, 2010), Japan (Song, 2014) and the Republic of
Korea (Shin, 2010).
III. FOUR POSSIBLE FUTURES 63
One important dimension where a dualist cleavage develops is between large and small firms, both
as the precondition and outcome of dualist union policies. Another dimension, obviously, is the one
between ‘permanent’ and ‘temporary’ workers, between natives and foreigners, old and young workers,
and, in developing countries, between the formal and informal sector. These dimensions are closely
interrelated, as small firms often obtain exemptions in employment protection laws and foreigners end
up in temporary jobs. Lee (2010) writes about the ‘double dualism’ of Japanese and Korean enterprise
unions which, by excluding small firms, also exclude temporary workers and foreigners. The extent to
which unions neglect small firms and organize only or mostly workers in large firms might therefore be
used as circumstantial evidence of dualist union policies.
The OECD overview of 1990 cited surveys and studies from Japan, Germany, Switzerland, the
Netherlands, Norway, France, Spain, the United Kingdom and the United States showing that union
density rates rise with firm size (except for the very largest). That overview also noted that trade unions
in Belgium, Denmark and Italy did exceptionally well in organizing workers in small and middle-sized
firms (Visser, 1991). In the public debate over how to stimulate more job creation, SMEs have steadily
gained influence and been showcased as job engines. Although definitions vary, estimates are that SMEs
contribute between 53 per cent of all jobs in the United Kingdom and 86 per cent in Greece (OECD,
2017b). In emerging-market economies, these shares are lower, at least in the formal sector. The ILO, for
instance, puts the employment share of SMEs at 34.8 per cent in 2016, up from 31.2 per cent in 2003 (ILO,
2017). With the informal sector, small and micro-firms employing one to five persons gain in importance
and account for up to 90 per cent of total employment.
Recent data, unfortunately only for developed economies, show that, on average, 62 per cent of all union
members work in large firms with more than 100 employees, 27 per cent in small or medium-sized
firms (10-100 employees) and 11 per cent in small or micro firms (fewer than ten employees). In Japan
and the Republic of Korea nearly all union members work in large firms; in Germany, France and the
Netherlands, this figure is well over 70 per cent. I have no data for the United States; in Canada the
large firm share is over 50 per cent. In Belgium, Denmark, Switzerland, Greece, Portugal and Spain,
the presence of large firms is less prominent, and there is a greater share of workers from SMEs in the
unions. Obviously, such variations reflect differences in the structure of the economy across countries
and the presence or absence of large multinational firms. To find out whether unions concentrate on
representing workers in large firms to the extent that they neglect or fail to reach workers in small firms,
we must look at the gap in union density rates of workers in large and small firms (Figure 18).
In many countries, from Japan, the Republic of Korea and Australia to France, Poland, Germany and
Spain, trade unions are hardly present in small firms with fewer than ten workers. Whether this is
true for developing countries, I do not know, but my suspicion is that it is, unless unions have started
organizing own-account workers in the informal sector. There are many reasons for this absence of
unions in small firms. Working alongside the owner may prevent workers from joining a union. From
the union’s point of view, setting up and maintaining a union in small firms is costly. In many countries
there are legal obstacles and thresholds. In Poland, for example, any starting union needs ten members.
Intended to forestall union fragmentation, this excludes many workers from union representation. In
Thailand the threshold lies at tens employees, in Romania at 15, in Honduras or Peru at 20, just to give
some examples. Such exclusionary thresholds can have a huge effect. In Poland, 30 to 40 per cent of
all employees, including some categories in the public service, are de jure excluded from joining or
forming a union. In Thailand, about 15 per cent of all workers, employed in over a quarter of a million
industrial enterprises, almost three-quarters of the total number of registered companies, are barred
from union representation (Brown, 2016). Milkman (2013) cites data for the United States showing that in
the 1990s, 22 per cent of private sector workers were excluded from the protections of the (‘New Deal’)
National Labour Relations Act. Among them are managers, independent contractors, micro businesses,
agricultural and domestic workers, and temporary agency workers. Thresholds for mandated employee
representation like works councils are also relevant, as there is much research evidence that workplace
64 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
institutions, like works councils, help unions to recruit and retain members (for evidence on Germany:
Behrens, 2009; Goerke and Pannenberg, 2007). Small firms with fewer than 10, 20 or even 50 employees
are usually excluded.
Comparing the union density rates of medium-sized (10-99 employees) and large (100 or more
employees) firms, we find the largest differences in Japan, The Republic of Korea, Germany, France,
Poland and Mexico (Figure 18). There is little or no difference in Switzerland, Greece, Denmark, Finland,
Sweden and Norway, whereas the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, Italy, Spain, Ireland and Israel are
in between. The Belgian data even suggest that unions are better organized in small firms than in large
firms.
A large divide in the unionization rates of workers in small and large firms is circumstantial evidence, not
proof, for the presence of dualist union policies. Large firms are of strategic value to the union as they
can be used to put pressure on other employers or on politicians. By organizing workers in large firms,
sectoral unions can set the trend for improving wages and working conditions throughout an entire
industry, including small firms. This has long been the model for trade unions and collective bargaining in
Germany, Sweden and many other countries. If the result is that average productivity, working conditions
and pay are leveled up and the redundant workers of unproductive small firms are helped to find a new
job, all is fine and we have the opposite of dualism. However, extending the more expensive agreements
of large firms to small firms, without due consideration of their capacity to pay, brings a risk and may
drive up unemployment. Decentralizing collective bargaining to the firm level may carry fewer risks of this
type, but at the cost of increased pay level discrepancies, rising inequality across firms, and lower levels
of unionization and bargaining coverage. Dualism has many facets and may become institutionalized
both through excessively centralized and excessively decentralized bargaining, illustrated either by a
large difference in the risk of job loss or in a large difference in pay, working conditions and career
opportunities. Japanese-style enterprise unionism is probably the surest way to institutionalize dualism
between insiders and outsiders. Works councils, if they can direct wage negotiations, as in Spain, have
many similar features.
90
80
70
60
Union density rate (% enployees)
50
40
30
20
10
0
Ko Es an
a, ia
hu of
Me ia
P co
st d
ec ca
Gr ep
Slo ece
Au enia
Fr lia
S e
Bu pain
Po aria
rm l
So ung ny
A y
Slo frica
La ia
ite Is ia
ing el
Ro dom
ia
Ca ly
Ire da
Ne Aus nd
Sw rla a
itz nds
Lu Cro nd
m ia
Cy rg
No rus
Sw way
De eden
Fin rk
Be and
um
Ge uga
uth ar
c
Co olan
the tri
Ita
re ton
an
k
tv
an
xe at
d K ra
a
u
Cz a Ri
an
xi
H a
a
na
hR
p
la
la
Lit ep
va
nm
lgi
bo
e
str
l
Ja
lg
r
v
er
rt
R
Un
III. FOUR POSSIBLE FUTURES 65
Two examples may clarify the dilemmas in union bargaining policy. Doerflinger and Pulignano (2018)
compare concession bargaining during the 2008 recession in two multinational companies in Belgium
and Germany. In Belgium, bargaining over pay, working time and jobs is spread between the national
(sectoral) and the local (enterprise) level, and the unions’ centrally decided priorities weigh strongly in
negotiations. In Germany, union company representatives had the power to set their priorities through
the use of opening clauses within a sectoral agreement. The authors conclude that the unions in both
countries were pushing for job preservation, but that the Belgians were more successful in pursuing an
inclusive strategy and keeping temporary and agency workers on board. They add, cautiously, that they
cannot predict the long-term effects of such different strategies on investment and employment.
In a study comparing Italian and Korean unions, Durazzi, Fleckenstein and Lee (2018) highlight the
importance of public opinion dynamics. With more workers pushed into non-standard employment after
the 1997-8 Asian crisis, Korean unions faced mounting public criticism that they gave priority to insider
interests and ignored workers and job seekers at the margins of the labour market. Combined with the
drop in membership around the same time, this was perceived by union leaders as a potentially existential
crisis. Leaders of the weak labour federations (effective power in the Republic of Korea rests within
enterprise unions) feared further delegitimization of the trade unions unless they started to recognize
and organize outsiders. The emergence of the Alliance for Nonstandard Workers, combining union and
civil society forces, was another push factor. The policy U-turn revealed deep divisions, and the Hyundai
company union was expelled from the metal workers’ federation for its discriminatory stance toward
non-standard workers. Later, when the shipbuilding industry faced severe corporate restructuring due to
increasing competition from China, enterprise unions in shipbuilding and other metalworking industries
started to represent the interests of outsiders in recognition that cheap irregular employment and the
widening gap between insiders and outsiders ultimately presented, as one union leader stated, “a barrier
to achieving standard workers’ demands for better wages and working conditions.” Enterprise unions
did not give up their prioritization of insiders; they did, however, begin to perceive an overlap of insider
and outsider interests.
The point of these two examples is not that dualism has no future in the unions. It remains a strong
probability, owing much to the present decentralization tendency (enterprise bargaining, ‘opening clauses’,
local partnerships) in collective bargaining, which gives a much louder voice to local job preservation
interests and, potentially, disregards the interests of others. But there are counter- tendencies even in
countries where dualism is most pronounced. Marx and Starke (2017) use the example of the introduction
of the national minimum wage in Germany in 2014, where the unions, after years of internal disputes and
opposition from the unions in export industries, united in a pro-minimum wage coalition. Institutions,
like the mandatory extension of sectoral collective agreements and the mandatory national minimum
wage, benefit workers in precarious jobs with little bargaining power or coverage and take some of the
sharper edges out of dualism (Hayter and Visser, 2018; Trygstad, Larsen and Nergaard, 2018). Many
trade unions in Africa, Asia and Latin America, motivated by genuine feelings of solidarity or an interest
in self-preservation, have started to address the concerns of informal and precarious workers. Many
unions in developed countries have changed their policies towards temporary workers and migrants.
According to Doellgast, Lillie and Pulignano (2018), trade unions in Europe “increasingly seek to
regulate precarious work and represent precarious workers”. They do this, in their words, “both to
protect their members from low-cost competition and following from broader commitments to equity
and social justice.” Presenting nine comparative case studies in industries and occupations such as
metal manufacturing, chemicals, retail, cleaning, local government, freelance music, logistics and
slaughterhouses in 14 countries (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany,
Greece, Hungary, Italy, Poland, Slovenia, Sweden, and the United Kingdom), the authors observe both
inclusionary and exclusionary (dualist) strategies. In their studies, dualism is not the dominant union
response to the rise in job instability and precariousness. For the alternative response, however, unions
need the support of inclusive institutions “deriving from some combination of state and union power to
extend institutional protection from stronger to weaker groups” (Doellgast, Lillie and Pulignano, 2018).
66 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
Their case studies give some impressive examples of unions in Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Italy and
Sweden that did mobilize successfully for inclusionary policies thanks to the combination of institutional
and associational power. That raises the question of whether for weak or weakened unions without
institutional and political support, the only alternative to dualism is marginalization, and the only answer
to marginalization dualism, however futile in the longer term.
3 / Substitution
My third scenario for the future explores whether trade unions will be replaced by other forms of social
action and representation. The decline of many traditional trade unions and the rise of new forms of
unstable and non-standard employment (platform work, dependent self-employment, domestic and
own-account work in the formal and informal sectors) have opened up opportunities to experiment with
new forms of worker voice and representation. These, in turn, have led to a discussion on whether some
of these new forms will be large enough to fill the void left by the unions, and whether these new forms
will have sufficient power to be effective.
Tapia, Ibsen and Kochan (2015) discuss four of these new forms: direct employee participation and
employer-provided voice, like quality circles; voluntary employer commitments to labour standards as
with Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR); International Framework Agreements (IFAs) negotiated with
international unions, and Civil Society Organizations (CSOs). They conclude that the effectiveness of such
new devices cannot be measured independently from the unions. The presence and design of labour
provisions in preferential trade agreements, for instance, tend to be directly correlated to the strength of
trade unions (Raess, Dürr and Sari, 2018).
This conclusion is in line with the findings of a study for the National Bureau of Economic Research on
“emerging labour institutions for the 21st century” (Freeman, Hersch and Mishel, 2005). They ask whether
what they call non-membership institutions – human rights and labour advocacy groups, vigilantes,
NGO-led living wage campaigns, labour inspectorates, professional associations, training intermediaries
and worker-management partnerships – will replace declining trade unions. The question can be split in
two: (1) Can these non-membership institutions provide services and worker representation comparable
to those of the unions? (2) If so, will they expand their reach and serve as large a proportion of the work
force that traditionally relied on unions? The detailed case studies in the NBER study, aimed at the United
States situation, answer both questions with a firm ‘no’. “The new institutions have a long way to go
before they will be able to provide remotely comparable economic benefits to unions” (Freeman, Hersch
and Mishel, 2005). Even where labour unions are as weakened as they are in the United States, they still
fare better than non-membership institutions, which have been unable to expand beyond small niches in
the labour market and tend to rely on the pressure of unions to be effective.
Based on the Workplace Employment Relations Survey spanning three decades and focusing on voice
mechanisms in British workplaces, Bryson, Gomez, and Willman (2018) reach a different conclusion.
They document a remarkable shift from union to non-union voice. The share of workplaces with no voice
has stayed roughly the same at about one-quarter. But both the dual channel system where union and
non-union voices co-exist (as in many continental European countries) and single union or union-only
systems (the traditional British, American or Scandinavian model) have sharply contracted: from 30 to
14 per cent in the case of dual (union and works council) voice, and from 18 to 3 per cent in the case of
single union voice. Over the same period, however, employer-provided voice, based on consultation and
participation which is not intermediated through the union, has more than doubled, climbing from 25 to
58 per cent of all workplaces. Employer-provided voice is therefore no longer a niche, but a majority. The
authors show that union voice is more present among more established workplaces, and that newly
established workplaces adopt other non-union-based models of voice. Research strongly suggests
that union-supported voice is more effective than the alternatives, particularly under circumstances of
III. FOUR POSSIBLE FUTURES 67
business adversity, when it is most needed. Moreover, where there is no on-site union representation,
workers often have no choice but to accept what is available to them. Often, it is the employer who
chooses for them, the only alternative being to quit the firm or the job.
Voice mechanisms provided by the employer and filling in for absent, weakened or de-recognized unions
are directed at workers with more or less permanent jobs in ‘regular’ workplaces. Worker centers and
community-based organizations are directed at workers without regular workplaces. Their support
comes, if not from the unions, from human rights activists and labour advocates. Worker centers in
the United States typically represent low-wage and immigrant workers in industries or occupations
where unions are absent and under United States law prevented from collective bargaining (Fine,
2006; Rosenfeld, 2014). Fine has questioned the sustainability of worker centers given their limited
geographies, fragmentation and small memberships. After initially being rather skeptical about their
durability and reach, more recently she has observed an evolution in perspective, noting the increased
collaboration between worker centers and labour unions (Fine, 2011). Temporary workers’ alliances
and community-based unions have also formed in the Republic of Korea and Japan to assist workers,
especially women, employed in industries where union organization is absent or weak or where women
are or feel excluded from the mainstream enterprise unions. Research demonstrates the important role
NGOs play in organizing women in low-skilled and low-wage work and the important function of women-
only organizations as an alternative to unions in defending the rights of female workers (Broadbent and
Ford, 2008). Crinis (2008) notes that as a result of the lack of union activity to protect women workers in
Malaysia, women unionists have joined forces with NGOs to raise community awareness about women’s
labour rights, domestic violence and sexual harassment.
Industrial cleaning is one of the sectors that have gained visibility in recent Living Wage campaigns.
Emerging in the 2000s, the British Living Wage campaign aimed to change customer behaviors,
introduced sustainable working practices and embraced CSR within supply chains. By bringing together
community groups and trade unions, the campaign initially focused on cleaning workers contracted to
the large companies based in London’s financial district. Following a number of successes, in which
targeted employers committed to paying contracted cleaners a voluntary living wage above the national
mandatory minimum, the campaign spread across London and other cities. There are similar examples
of Living Wage campaigns in various cities in the United States.27
Such community initiatives offer a substitute for unions. They are particularly relevant for the organization
of informal workers, like street vendors and waste pickers in Ghana, India, Peru and Thailand, as
discussed in the comparative study of Chen, Madhaw and Sankaran (2014). The critical issue is
whether such initiatives can turn into permanent organizations with the power to negotiate and enforce
agreements with local or national authorities and, possibly, employers. Here, the experience, skills and
professionalism of trade unions may still be in demand. Holgate’s (2015) work on community unionism
is particularly significant in this regard, as she shows how unions in some big cities have tried to shift the
locus of their activity from the workplace to the local community and have started to participate in and
help sustain citywide coalitions in London, Sydney and Toronto. Along this route there has been a dual
expansion of the union, extending organization from the workplace to the community and extending the
focus of union activity from employment rights to citizen rights.
Identification of the differential capacities of social movements and trade unions has been the focus of
recent work by Heckscher and McCarthy (2014). They argue that traditional forms of labour solidarity
are in decline and being replaced by single-issue protests and movements like Occupy, the Mozilla
movement for a free Internet or student campaigns for labour standards. The ‘collaborative solidarity’
that lies at the heart of these movements is based on ‘weak ties’, often established via internet platforms,
and relies on shared values and empathy rather than the common experience of work and membership
that characterized the trade union. Fragile ties of this kind can nevertheless support collective action,
which takes the form of ‘swarming’: multiple actions organized independently by groups of movement
supporters in pursuit of a common goal and perhaps making use of common resources made available
68 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
through an Internet platform. Collective action of this kind, according to Heckscher and McCarthy, is the
promise of the future, attuned to the Internet age, and they suggest that the future of the labor movement
depends on its ability to learn from these examples and embrace the seemingly weak, collaborative
solidarity on which they were built. Surely, social media and information and communication technologies
can become a tool for workers to share experiences and express voice in the absence of trade unions and
build ‘online communities’ even within the workplace. These methods can fill a void where there are no
recognized or visible unions or where workers are scattered across different geographies, occupations
and platforms. Bryson et al. (2017) give the example of OUR.Wallmart, in which a small group created
a Facebook-based strategy and app for campaigning within this notorious anti-union company with
1.5 million employees.
Unions, rather than being replaced by non-member organizations, may themselves turn into something
resembling action or lobby groups or community organizations, engaging in public protests, legal and
political campaigning and other forms of pressure politics that do not rely on collective bargaining or
the capacity to organize and sustain a strike. There are examples of this kind of change or innovation
in Slovakia and other Central and Eastern European (CEE) countries where union density rates have
continuously decreased and unions’ only remaining strength is in the declining public sector. Rather
than being pushed out by civil rights organizations, unions join or take over what they cannot beat.
Interestingly, this ‘innovation’, which is based on the idea that ‘membership’ is no longer a core resource,
has brought increased focus – in political and social campaigning but not in collective bargaining – on the
problems expressed by or attributed to vulnerable and precarious workers (Bernaciak and Kahancová,
2017). Another feature is that union activities become more organized as campaigns or projects, similar
to ‘union organizing’ but without the explicit aim of recruiting members. This has made these unions, like
many unions in developing countries, which focus on the plight of informal workers, more dependent on
outside funding from NGOs, international organizations, development aid programs of richer countries
and trade unions and international union federations.
4 / Revitalization
The final and fourth scenario for the future is that the trade unions regain their vitality and youthfulness,
find ways to expand beyond their current membership base and succeed in organizing parts of the ‘new
unstable workforce’ in the digital economy. I have presented some evidence for this: unions or union-like
organizations that have started to make inroads into the informal economies of Africa, Asia and Latin
America and unions in developed countries which are inventing smart ways to use the Web as a tool to
communicate with and organize platform workers and extend membership to ‘own-account’ workers in
both the traditional and digital economy.
Optimism about the unions’ future can also come from the increased diversity of union membership,
the tremendous progress made by women in the unions, the rising level of education of union members
and, not least, the new energy that has been injected into the unions by many organizing campaigns and
union renewal initiatives since 2000. Today, more union leaders see the urgency of renewal. Innovation
is also a matter of resource crossover within the union movement. Unionization among employees and
professionals in public administration, social insurance, education and health services is still high in
many of the countries where private sector unionization is at an all-time low. This raises the issue of how
to best spend and share these resources.
Getting more young people into the unions is key to any strategy of union renewal. Revitalisation requires
that, as a minimum, unions must aim the double the current union density rate of young people, until
the age of 30, raising the average from the present 11 to 22 percent. There may be several ways to
achieve this. Union recruitment in an early stage, in vocational schools and at universities, and during
the transition from school to work, requires that unions introduce special membership programs,
III. FOUR POSSIBLE FUTURES 69
with reduced dues and targeted benefits that help young people at this stage of their live. It inevitably
requires that unions shift some of their resources, benefits and policies from older to younger workers.
Leadership change is an aspect of this, but surely it would help to see more young people in the top
leadership of the unions and confederations. The Italian General Confederation of Trade Unions (CGIL)
has made a start with setting a quota of 20 percent for workers under the age of 30 years for elected
union officials. Similar but much higher quota in the case of women have worked to bring more women
in union leadership positions and it is plausible that together with a change in policies this has made the
unions more attractive for women.
Trade unions often enjoy support from society at large, far beyond their declining membership share. The
importance of unions’ image in society is not to be underestimated. Two opposing examples, one from
India’s IT sector, the other from Germany’s car industry, illustrate this. Noronha and D’Cruz (2017) claim
that “over the years, Indian trade unions have acquired an unfavorable perception of behaving irresponsibly,
catering to vested interests, adopting disruptive tactics, neglecting the concerns of members and ignoring
the welfare of society at large”. They show that this negative image is used by employers in the IT industry
to prevent or disrupt organizing efforts by portraying the trade unions as backward, unhelpful, irrelevant
or dangerous. Consequently, organizing attempts among IT professionals must avoid all association
and contact with the unions to be even halfway successful. Successful organizing must stress the
professionalism and competencies of unions as skillful negotiators. The German example refers to the
use by IG Metall of opportunities offered by the 2008 financial crisis. At the time, the union proposed and
successfully negotiated a car-wrecking and short-time working scheme that kept the car industry afloat
and skilled workers in their jobs. This feat, which was widely advertised in the media, added influence and
prestige to the union’s undeniable power and helped to improve not only the union’s standing in society
but also its membership statistics (Schmalz and Thiel, 2017).
70 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
Frangi, Koos and Hadziabdic (2016) show that a considerable part of European public opinion considers
trade unions as a relevant social institution and that this has remained true over time despite declining
union density levels. Moreover, a rather high level of ‘confidence in the unions’ is expressed by social
groups that are particularly vulnerable: people with low income, younger people and migrants – groups
who themselves are under-represented in trade unions as well as in politics and most other societal
organizations and institutions. In October 2015 when the Australian Bureau of Statistics announced that
union membership had fallen to just 14.4 per cent of all employees, its lowest level in 25 years, the
country’s main polling company released figures showing that 62 per cent of Australians believe unions
are important and that this belief has actually grown since 2012. Only 21 per cent of those polled believed
that unions were not very important, down from 27 per cent in 2012. Even more at odds with the low
density figure is that 45 per cent of Australians believed that workers would be better off if the unions
were stronger.28 In short, it appears that there is still a large ideational and social space for the trade
unions.
Union revitalization does not mean a return to the past, either in its forms or numbers. Revitalization
means doing things differently with less. What needs to be done differently, most likely, is membership
itself and what it implies in terms of commitments, rights and obligations. Membership will probably be
more fragile and temporary and less based on a permanent and ‘open-ended’ commitment, much like
the changes in today’s employment relationships. Especially for the current and next generation of young
people entering the labour market, engagement with the unions might involve new, Internet-based
forms of engagement including crowd financing and small fees for specific projects, voting rights in union
elections, collective agreement ballots, social pacts and striking. All of this requires new thinking and
experimenting, especially in connection with what must remain the core business of unions: organizing
and expressing solidarity among workers in pursuit of negotiating agreements that bind employers
and governments. Collective bargaining presupposes the capacity to call strikes and commit one’s
constituency to the results – whether both are possible with looser, less binding forms of membership is
a big open question that also has legal ramifications.
Lastly, revitalization involves cooperation and alliances with other social organizations and social forces.
The success stories told in a recent collection by Germany’s FES – of Ugandan transport workers,
Kenyan security guards, Nigerian textile workers, Indian street vendors and South Korean cleaners –
show how workers in non-standard forms of employment eschewed traditional forms of trade unionism
and created new coalitions or hybrid organizations in which a crossover from the informal to the
formal sector, and vice versa, was possible. Organizational flexibility combined with a more inclusive
understanding of solidarity and of who is a worker enabled unions to approach workers in informal
arrangements and come up with innovative ways of collaboration and interest representation (Herberg,
2018). There are other encouraging examples of revitalization from developing countries: how unions
take on multinational companies using IFAs, preferential trade agreements or monitoring mechanisms
from international institutions like the ILO or the OECD; how they have been building political and social
alliances for the defense of democracy, civil rights, and health provisions (Karreth, 2018), and how they
have brought more diversity and more attention to minority rights into their ranks and into their policies.
Conclusion
Each of the four futures painted in the preceding pages is possible, but which one is most likely? Maybe
the answer depends on where in the world you are and there is no universal, let alone exact answer.
Marginalization is most likely where decline and ageing have reached extremes and where unions lack
the backing of legal and social institutions and are confronted with a political and social climate of hostility
or indifference (parts of Central and Eastern Europe and the United States). Dualism is a possibility both in
developing countries, unless a bridge is built to encourage self-organizing among informal workers, and
in developed economies if unions remain locked up in their present stronghold in public services, large
firms and a handful of manufacturing sectors. Substitution will spread where there are latent needs for
representation and voice, but no unions to provide (British or American workplaces, The new platform
economy, Own-account workers in the informal sector in South Asia and Central America). Revitalization
is happening everywhere, but its success will depend on whether unions have enough resources to
ensure its endurance, connect with young people and find effective ways to build coalitions with other
organizations and movements.
The main point I want to stress is that the four futures of trade unions are happening at the same time,
sometimes in the same countries but in different sectors (public/private; industry/services; employees/
self-employed; alt-economy/platform work), with particular combinations: dualism as a holdout against
marginalization; substitution as a source and inspiration for revitalization; revitalization as the ‘opening
up’ of dualist practices. The bottom line for trade unions and union leaders is that adding new members,
both in the old and in the new economy, has become more difficult than maintaining existing ties and
that adding new members or creating some other form of engagement involves doing things differently,
albeit for the same old purpose: organizing and expressing solidarity among workers. It is the means
that need to change, not the objectives.
References
Ackers, P. 2015. ‘Trade unions as professional Bernaciak, M.; Kahancová, M. (eds). 2017. Innovative
associations’. In: S. Johnstone, and P. Ackers, union practices in Central Eastern Europe. Brussels:
ed. Finding a voice at work? New perspectives on European Trade Union Institute.
employment relations. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
Berntsen, L. 2015. ‘Precarious migrant workers in the
pp. 95–126.
Dutch construction and meat processing industries’,
Adams, Z.; Deakin, S. 2014. ‘Institutional solutions to International Journal of Comparative Labour Law and
precariousness and inequality in labor markets’, British Industrial Relations, 31 (4), pp. 371-89.
Journal of Industrial Relations, 52 (4), pp. 779–809.
Bonner, C.; Spooner, D. 2011. ‘Organizing in the informal
Afonso, A.; Devitt, C. 2016. ‘Comparative political economy: A challenge for trade unions. https://library.
economy and international migration’, Socio- fes.de/pdf-files/ipg/2011-2/08_a_bonner.pd
Economic Review, 14 (3), pp. 591–613.
Booth, A. L. 1985. ‘The free rider problem and a social
ALRN. 2003. Trade Unions in Africa. African Labour custom model of trade union membership’, The
Research Network. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100 (1), pp. 253-261.
Arnholtz, J.; Ibsen, C.L.; Ibsen, F. 2016. ‘Importing Booth, J. E.; Budd, J.W.; Munday, K.M. 2010. ‘Never say
low-density ideas to high-density revitalization: never? Uncovering the never-unionized in the United
The “organising model” in Denmark’, Economic and States’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 48 (1), pp.
Industrial Democracy 37 (2), pp. 297–317. 26-52.
Antentas, J.M. 2015. ‘Spain: The Indignados rebellion of Brady, D. 2007. Institutional, economic, or solidaristic?
2011 in perspective’, Labor History, 56, pp. 136–160. Assessing explanations for unionization across affluent
democracies, Work and Occupations, 34 (1), pp. 67-101.
Autor, D.; Levy, F.; Murnane, R. 2003. ‘The Skill
content of recent technological change: An empirical Breman, J. 2010. Outcast Labour in Asia. Circulation
exploration’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118 (4), and informalisation of the workforce at the bottom of
pp. 1279–1334. the economy. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Autor, D.; Dorn, D.; Hanson, G.H. 2016. ‘The China Broadbent, K.; Ford, M. (eds). 2008. Women and labour
Shock: Learning from labor market adjustment to large organising in Asia: Diversity, autonomy and activism.
changes in trade’, Annual Review of Economics, 8, pp. Abingdon: Routledge.
205–240, http://economics.mit.edu/files/11675
Brown, A. 2016. ‘Political regimes and employment
Avdagic, S.; Baccaro, L. 2014. The future of employment relations in Thailand’, Journal of Industrial Relations, 58
relations in advanced capitalism: Inexorable decline? In: (2), pp. 199–214.
Wilkinson, A. G. Wood, and R. Deeg, eds. The Oxford
Bryson, A., Davies, R. 2018. ‘Family, Place and the
Handbook of Employment Relations, Oxford: Oxford
Intergenerational
University Press, pp. 701–726.
Transmission of Union Membership’, British Journal of
Behrens, M. 2009. ‘Still married after all these years?
Industrial Relations, 56(3), pp.1–27.
Union organizing and the role of works councils in
German industrial relations’, Industrial and Labor Bryson, A.; Gomez, R. 2005. ‘Why have workers
Relations Review, 62 (3), pp. 275–293. stopped joining unions? The rise in never-membership
in Britain’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 43 (1),
Benassi, C.; Dorigatti, L. 2015. ‘Straight to the core—
pp. 67-92.
explaining union responses to the casualization of
work: the IG Metall campaign for agency workers’, Bryson, A.; Gomez, R.; Wilman, P. 2016. ‘Voice in the
British Journal of Industrial Relations, 53 (3), pp. wilderness? The shift from union to non-union voice
533–55. in Britain’, in A. Wilkinson et al., ed. Participation in
organizations. Oxford: Oxford University Press, chapter
Benassi C.; Vlandas, T. 2016. ‘Union inclusiveness
16.
and temporary agency workers: The role of power
resources and union ideology’, European Journal of Bryson, A.; Freeman, R.B.; Gomez, R.; Willman, P. 2017.
Industrial Relations, 22 (1), pp. 5–22. ‘The twin track model of employee voice: An Anglo-
American perspective on union decline and the rise of
Bengtsson, E. 2013. ‘Swedish trade unions and
alternative forms of voice”, IZA Discussion Paper, No.
European Union migrant workers’, Journal of Industrial
11223.
Relations, 55 (2), pp. 174–189.
REFERENCES 73
Böckerman, P.; Uusitalo, R. 2006. ‘Erosion of the Ghent De Stefano, V. 2017. ‘Non-standard work and limits
system and union membership decline: Lessons from on freedom of association: A human rights-based
Finland’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 44(2), approach’, Industrial Law Journal, 46 (2), pp. 185-207.
pp. 283-303. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/indlaw/dww034
Caspersz, D. 2013. ‘Organising international migrant Doellgast, V.; Lillie, N.; Pulignano, V. (eds). 2018.
labour. International comparisons’, Journal of Industrial Reconstructing solidarity. Labour unions, precarious
Relations, 55 (2), pp. 169–173. work, and the politics of institutional change in Europe.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Castles, S.; Miller, M.J. 2009. The Age of Migration.
International population movements in the modern Doerflinger, N.; Pulignano, V. 2018. ‘Crisis-related
world. London: Palgrave-McMillan, 4th ed. collective bargaining and its effects on different
contractual groups of workers in Belgian and German
Checchi, D.; Visser, J. 2005. ‘Pattern persistence in
workplaces’, Economic and Industrial Democracy, 39
European trade union density: A longitudinal analysis
(1), pp. 131-150.
1950-1996’, European Sociological Review, 21 (1), pp.
1-21. Donado, A.; Wälde, K. 2012. ‘How trade unions increase
welfare’, The Economic Journal, 122, pp. 990-1009.
Checchi, D.; Visser, J.; van de Werfhorst, H. 2010.
‘Inequality and union membership: The influence Durazzi, N.; Fleckenstein, T.; Lee, S.C. 2018. ‘Social
of relative earnings and inequality attitudes’, British solidarity for all? Trade union strategies, labor market
Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 48 (1), pp. 84-108. dualization, and the welfare state in Italy and South
Korea’, Politics & Society, 46 (2), pp. 205–233.
Chen, F. 2003. ‘Between the state and labour: the
conflict of Chinese trade unions’ double identity in Dølvik, J-E.; Visser, J. 2009. ‘Free Movement, Equal
market reform’, China Quarterly, 176, pp. 1006–28. Treatment and Worker Rights: Can the EU solve its
trilemma of fundamental principles?’, Industrial
Chen, F. 2009. ‘Union power in China: source, operation,
Relations Journal, vol. 40 (6), pp. 315-350.
and constraints’, Modern China, 35 (6), pp. 662–89.
Ebbinghaus, B.; Visser, J. 1999. ‘When institutions
Chen, M.A.; Madhav, R.; Sankaran, K. 2014. ‘Legal
matter: Union growth and decline in Western Europe,
reforms for the self-employed: Three urban cases’,
1950–1995’, European Sociological Review, 15 (2), pp.
Indian Journal of Industrial Relations, 50 (1), pp. 133-
135-158.
150
Emmenegger, P. 2014. The power to dismiss: Trade
China Labour Bulletin. 2014. ‘Searching for the union:
unions and the regulation of job security in Western
The workers’ movement in China. 2011-13’. CLB
Europe. New York: Oxford University Press.
Research Report, February. http://www.clb.org.hk/en/
sites Erickson C.L.; Fisk, C.; Milkman, R.; Mitchell, D; Wong,
K. 2002. ‘Justice for janitors in Los Angeles: Lessons
Coase, R.H. 1937. ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica 4
from three rounds of negotiations’, British Journal of
(16), pp. 386–405.
Industrial Relations, 40 (3), pp. 543–567.
Connolly, H.; Marino, S.; Martinez Lucio, M. 2017,
Eurofound 2018. Employment and working conditions
‘“Justice for Janitors” goes Dutch. The limits and
of selected types of platform work. Luxembourg:
possibilities of unions’ adoption of organizing in
Publications Office of the European Union. https://
a context of regulated social partnership’, Work,
www.eurofound.europa.eu/sites/default/files/ef_
Employment and Society, 31 (2), pp. 319–335.
publication/field_ef_document/ef18001en.pdf
Cook, A.; Lorwin, V.R.; Kaplan Davies, A. (eds).
Farrell, D.; Greig, F. 2016. ‘The online platform economy:
1984. Women in Trade Unions in eleven countries.
What is the growth trajectory?’. JP Morgan Chase &
Philadelphia: Temple University Press.
Company Institute.
Crouch, C.J. 1982. Trade unions. The logic of collective
Fearon, J. 2003. ‘Ethnic and Cultural Diversity by
action. Glasgow: Fontana.
Country’, Journal of Economic Growth, 8 (2), pp.
Czarzasty, J.; Gajewska, K.; Mrozowicki, A. 2014. 195–222.
‘Institutions and strategies: Trends and obstacles to
Fine, J. 2006. Worker centers: organizing communities
recruiting workers into trade unions in Poland’, British
at the edge of the dream, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University/
Journal of Industrial Relations, 52 (1), pp. 112–135.
ILR Press.
De Stefano, V. 2016. The rise of the “Just-In-Time
Fine, J. 2011. ‘New forms to settle old scores: Updating
workforce”: On-demand work, crowdwork and labour
the worker centre story in the United States”, Relations
protection in the “gig-economy”. Geneva. ILO, Conditions
Industrielles/Industrial Relations, 66 (4).
of Work and Employment Series No. 71.
Finkin, M. 2016. ‘Beclouded work, beclouded workers
in historical perspective”, Comparative Labour Law &
Policy Journal, 37.
74 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
FES. N.d. Trade Unions in Transformation. Berlin: Hassel, A. 2007. ‘The curse of institutional security:
Friedrich Ebert Stiftung. the erosion of German trade unionism’, Industrielle
Beziehungen, 14 (2), pp. 176–91.
Frangi, L.; Koos, S.; Hadziabdic, S. 2017. ‘In unions we
trust! Analysing confidence in unions across Europe’, Hassel, A. 2014. ‘The Paradox of Liberalization:
British Journal of Industrial Relations, 55 (4), pp. Understanding dualism and the recovery of the
831–858. German political economy’, British Journal of Industrial
Relations, 52 (1), pp. 57-81.
Frangi, L.; Routh, S. 2014. ‘From employee to homo
faber? Considerations about union renewal and Hayter, S.; Visser, J. (eds). 2018. Collective agreements:
informal workers in Brazil and India’, Just Labour: A Extending labour protection. Geneva: ILO.
Canadian Journal of Work and Society, 21, pp. 42-67.
Heckscher C.; McCarthy, J. 2014. ‘Transient solidarities:
Freeman, R.B. 1998. ‘Spurts in union growth: Defining Commitment and collective action in post-industrial
moments and social processes’. In M.D. Bordo, C. societies’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 52 (3),
Goldin, and E.N. White (eds). The defining moment: The pp. 627–657.
Great Depression and the American economy in the
Heery, E. 2009. Trade unions and contingent labour:
Twentieth Century, Chicago: The University of Chicago
Scale and method, Cambridge Journal of Regions,
Press, pp. 265-295.
Economy and Society, 2, pp. 429–442.
Flesher Fominaya, C. 2015. ‘Debunking spontaneity:
Heery E.; Adler, L. 2004. ‘Organizing the unorganized’.
Spain’s 15-M/Indignados as autonomous movements’,
In: C. Frege and J. Kelly (eds). Varieties of Unionism.
Social Movement Studies 14 (2), pp. 1–22.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 45–70.
Freeman, R.B.; Medoff, J.L. 1984. What do Unions do?.
Herberg, M. 2018. Trade unions in transformation.
New York: Basic Books.
Success stories from all over the world. Berlin: Friedrich
Freeman, R.B.; Hersch, J.; Mishel, L. (eds). 2005. Ebert Stiftung.
Emerging labor market institutions for the Twenty-First
Holgate, J. 2015. Community organizing in the UK:
Century. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
A ‘new’ approach for trade unions?, Economic and
Friedman, E.; Kuruvilla, S. 2015. ‘Experimentation and Industrial Democracy 36 (3), pp. 431–455.
decentralization in China’s labor relations’, Human
Holtgrewe, U.; Doellgast, V. 2012. ‘A Service Union’s
Relations, 68 (2), pp. 181–95.
innovation dilemma. Limitations on collective action in
Gallin, D. 2001. ‘Propositions on trade unions and German industrial relations’, Work, Employment and
informal employment in times of globalisation, Society, 26, pp. 314-30.
Antipode, 33 (3). Geneva, Global Labour Institute.
Horwitz, S.K.; Horwitz, J.B. 2007. The effects of team
Gahan, P.; Pekarek, A.; Nicholson, D. 2018. ‘Unions and diversity on team outcomes. A meta-analytical review
collective bargaining in Australia in 2017’, Journal of of team demography, Journal of Management, 23 (6),
Industrial Relations, 60 (3), pp. 337–357. pp. 987-1015.
Goerke, L.; Pannenberg, M. 2007. ‘Trade union Huws, U.; Spencer, N.H.; Syrdal, D.S.; Holts, K. 2017.
membership and works councils in West Germany’, ‘Work in the European gig economy: Research
Industrielle Beziehungen 14 (2), pp. 154–175. results from the UK, Sweden, Germany, Austria,
the Netherlands, Switzerland and Italy’, Brussels:
Gomez, R.; Gunderson, M. 2005. ‘The experience
Foundation of European Progressive Studies and UNI
good model of trade union membership’. In P.V.
Europa.
Wunnava, The Changing Role of Unions: New Forms of
Representation. New York: ME Sharpe. Hyman, R.; Gumbrell-McCormick, R. 2017. ‘Resisting
labour market insecurity. Old and new actors, rivals
Gordon, S.; Maharaj, B. 2014. ‘Representing foreign
or allies?’, Journal of Industrial Relations, 59 (4), pp.
workers in the private security industry: A South
538–561.
African perspective on trade union engagement’,
Journal of Modern African Studies, 52 (1), pp. 123–49. Ibsen C.L.; Tapia, M. 2017. ‘Trade union revitalisation:
Where are we now? Where to next?’, Journal of
Gorodzeisky, A.; Richards, A. 2013. ‘Trade unions and
Industrial Relations, 59 (2), pp. 170–191.
migrant workers in western Europe’, European Journal
of Industrial Relations, 19 (3), pp. 239–54. Ibsen, C. L.; Toubøl, J.; Jensen, D.S. 2017. ‘Social
customs and trade union membership: A multi-level
Gumbrell-McCormick, R. 2011. ‘European trade unions
analysis of workplace union density using micro-data’,
and “Atypical’ Workers”’, Industrial Relations Journal,
European Sociological Review, 33 (4), pp. 504-517.
42 (3), pp. 293-310.
Hall, J.V.; Krueger, A.B. 2018. ‘An analysis of the labor
market for Uber’s driver-partners in the United States,
Industrial and Labour Relations Review, 71 (3), pp.
705–732.
REFERENCES 75
International Labour Office (ILO). 2002: Resolution Kaminska, M.E.; Kahancová, M. 2017. ‘State, market
concerning decent work and the informal economy, and collective regulation in the hospital sector in East-
adopted by the General Conference of the ILO. Geneva. Central Europe: union strategies against all odds’,
https://www.ilo.org/public/english/standards/relm/ Comparative Labor Law & Policy Journal, 38 (2), pp.
ilc/ilc90/pdf/pr-25res.pdf 257-289.
—. 2015a, The Future of Work Centenary initiative, Kanbur, R.; Rajaram, P.K.; Varshney, A. 2011. ‘Ethnic
Report by the Director-General. diversity and ethnic strife. An interdisciplinary
perspective’, World Development, 39 (2), pp. 147-158.
—. 2015b. Global estimates on migrant workers:
Results and methodology. Geneva: ILO, https://www. Karreth, A.K. 2018. Schools of democracy: how trade
ilo.org/global/topics/labour-migration/publications/ union membership impacts political participation in
WCMS_436343/lang--en/index.htm Africa’s emerging democracies, Democratization, 25
(1), pp. 158-177.
—. 2016. Non-standard employment around the word.
Understanding challenges, shaping prospects. Geneva: Katz, L.F.; Krueger, A.B. 2016. The rise and nature of
ILO, e-book. alternative work arrangements in the United States,
1995–2015, ILR Review, 72 (2), pp. 382-416.
—. 2018a. Men and women in the informal economy. A
statistical portrait. Third ed., Geneva: ILO. https://www. Keune, M. 2013. ‘Trade union responses to precarious
ilo.org/global/publications/books/WCMS_626831/ work in seven European countries: Overview report.’
lang--en/index.htm Available at: http://www.uva-aias.net/361
—. 2018b. World Economic and Social Outlook. Trends Kjellberg, A. 2018, ‘Kollektivavtalens täckningsgrad
2018. Geneva: ILO, http://www.ilo.org/global/ samt organisationsgraden hos arbetsgivarförbund och
research/global-reports/weso/2018/lang--en/index. fackförbund’. Department of Sociology, Lund University
htm
Kjellberg, A.; Ibsen, C.L, 2016, ‘Attacks on Union
IOM. 2016. ‘Global Migration Trends. Factsheet 2015’. Organizing—Reversible and irreversible changes in the
Geneva: International Organization for Migration, Ghent-system in Sweden and Denmark’, in T.P.Larsen
http://publications.iom.int/system/files/global_ and A-Ilsøe, eds. Den Daske Model set udefra.
migration_trends_2015_factsheet.pdf Copenhagen: Jurist- and Økonomforbundets Forlag,
279-302.
IPSP. 2018. Rethinking Society for the 21st Century.
Report of the International Panel on Social Progress, Klandermans, B.; Visser, J. 1995, De vakbeweging in de
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, vol. 1, welvaartsstaat. Assen: van Gorkum.
chapter 7: The future of work – good jobs for all’, by
Kloosterboer, D. 2007. Innovative trade union strategies.
W. Eichhorst, and A. Portela de Souza, with P. Cahuc,
Amsterdam: Federatie Nederlandse Vakbeweging
D. Demazière, C. Fagan, N. Guimarães, H. Fu, A.
(FNV).
Kalleberg, A. Manning, F. McGinnity, H. Rapoport, Ph.
Scranton, J. Siegrist, K. Thelen, M.-A. Valfort, and J. Korkut , U.; de Ruyter, A.; Maganaris, M.; Bailey, D.
Visser. 2017. ‘What next for unions in Central and Eastern
Europe? Invisibility, departure and the transformation
Jacobson, R.; Geron, K. 2011. ‘Unions and the politics
of industrial relations’, European Journal of Industrial
of immigration’, Socialism and Democracy, 22 (3), pp.
Relations, 23 (1), pp. 65–80.
105-122.
Kornelakis, A.; Voskeritsian, H. 2016. ‘Getting together
Jeong, J. 2001. ‘Pursuing centralized bargaining in
or breaking apart? Trade union strategies, restructuring
an era of decentralization? A progressive union goal
and contingent workers in Southern Europe’, Economic
in Korea from a comparative perspective’, Industrial
and Industrial Democracy, 39 (2), pp. 357–375.
Relations Journal, 32 (1), pp. 55–70.
Kranendonk, M.; de Beer, P. 2016. “What explains
Johnston, H.; Land-Kazlauskas, C. 2018. ‘Organizing
the union membership gap between migrants and
on-demand: Representation, voice, and collective
natives?, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 54 (4),
Bargaining in the Gig Economy’, Geneva: ILO, Conditions
pp. 846–869.
of Work and Employment Series, No. 94.
Krings, T. 2010. ‘Trade unions and migrant labour in
Kalleberg, A.L. 2018. Precarious lives: Job insecurity
the “Global Age”: New alliances or old antagonisms?’
and well-being in rich democracies. Cambridge, UK:
In G. Menz and A. Caviedes (eds). Labour migration in
Polity Press.
Europe. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan
Kaminska, M.E. 2018. ‘A world of very dead letters
Kucera, D. 2007. ‘Measuring Trade Union Rights by
indeed: Working Time Directive in the hospital sector
Violations of These Rights’. In D. Kucera (ed). Qualitative
in East-Central Europe’. Paper presented at the
indicators of labour standards: Comparative methods
International Conference on Global Dynamics of
and applications. Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 145-82.
Social Policy of the Collaborative Research Center
1342, University of Bremen, 25-26 October.
76 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
Kucera, D.; Sari, D. 2016. New “Labour Rights Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Indicators”: Method and Results. https://www. Development (OECD). 2016. New Forms of Work in the
researchgate.net/publication/301788004/download Digital Economy. Paris, Digital Economy Papers, no.
260.
Lee, J. 2010. ‘Between fragmentation and
centralization: South Korean industrial relations in —. 2017a. Employment Outlook 2017. Paris.
transition’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 49 (4),
—. 2017b. Unlocking the potential of SMEs for social
pp. 767–791
development goals. Paris. https://oecd-development-
Lechske, J.; Vandaele, K. 2018. ‘Explaining leaving matters.org/2017/04/03/unlocking-the-potential-of-
union membership by the degree of labour market smes-for-the-sdgs/
attachment. Exploring the case of Germany’, Economic
—. 2018. ‘The rise of self-employment in the
and Industrial Democracy, 39 (1), pp. 64-86.
Netherlands’. OECD Economic Survey of the
Lindell, I. 2008. ‘Building alliances between formal and Netherlands 2018. Paris.
informal workers: Experiences from Africa’. In A. Bieler,
Palier, B.; Thelen, K. 2010. ‘Institutionalizing dualism:
I. Lindberg, and D. Pillay (eds). Labor and challenges
Complementarities and change in France and
of globalization: What prospects for international
Germany’, Politics & Society, 38, pp. 119-48.
solidarity? Scottsville: UKZN Press.
Pedersini, R. 2010. ‘Trade union strategies to recruit
Liu, M. 2010. ‘Union organizing in China: still a
new groups of workers.’ Dublin: European Foundation
monolithic labor movement?’, Industrial and Labor
for the improvement of Living and Working Conditions.
Relations Review, 64 (1), pp. 30–52.
Penninx, R.; Roosblad, J. (eds). 2000. Trade unions,
—. 2014 “The future of Chinese labor relations”,
immigration and immigrants in Europe 1960–1993:
Perspectives on Work, 18, pp. 76–9 and 116–19.
A comparative study of the actions of trade unions in
LO/FTF. Labour market profiles. http://www. seven West European countries. Oxford: Berghahn.
ulandssekretariatet.dk/content/landeanalyser
Pernicka, S.; Blaschke, S. 2006. ‘Selbständige – (k)
Marshall, A.; Perelman, L. 2008. ‘Why “union eine Klientel für Gewerkschaften?’, Österreichische
revitalization” is not an issue in Argentina. Labour Zeitschrift für Soziologie, 31 (2), pp. 29-53.
institutions and the effectiveness of traditional trade
Pernot, J.-M. 2010. Syndicats: lendemains de crise?
union recruitment strategies’. Paper presented at
Paris: Gallimard.
29th Annual Conference of the International Working
Party on Labour Market Segmentation, Porto, 8-10 Pesole, A.; Urzì Brancati, C.; Fernández-Macías, E.;
September. Biagi, F.; González Vázquez, I. 2018. Platform workers
in Europe: Evidence from the COLLEEM survey, Joint
Marx, P.; Starke, P. 2017. Dualization as destiny? The
Research Centre, Luxembourg: Publications Office of
political economy of the German minimum wage
the European Union.
reform, Politics & Society, 45 (4), pp. 559–584.
Pulignano, V.; Doerflinger, N. 2014. ‘Wie heeft wie
Milkman, R. 2013. ‘Back to the future? US Labour
nodig? Vakbonden en jongeren in België’. Louvain,
in the new Gilded Age’, British Journal of Industrial
Centre for Sociological Research, working paper
Relations, 51 (4), pp. 645–665.
2014/1.
Mosoetsa, S.; Stillerman, J.; Tilly, C. 2016. ‘Precarious
Pulignano V.; Ortiz Gervasi, L.; de Franceschi, F. 2016.
labor, South and North. An introduction’, International
‘Union responses to precarious workers: Italy and
Labour and Working-Class History, 89, pp. 5-19.
Spain compared’, European Journal of Industrial
Murphy, C.; Turner, T. 2016. ‘Organising precarious Relations, 22 (1), pp. 39–55.
workers: Can a public campaign overcome weak
Raess, D.; Dürr, A.; Sari, D. 2018. Protecting labor rights
grassroots mobilisation at workplace level?’, Journal of
in preferential trade agreements: The role of trade
Industrial Relations, 58 (5), pp. 589–607.
unions, left governments, and skilled labor, Review of
Murray, M. 2018. ‘EPZs are strategies for economic International Organizations, August 2018. (https://doi.
development’, Small Business Forum, https://www. org/10.1007/s11558-018-9301-z)
thebalancesmb.com/export-processing-zones-
Ramalho, J. R. 2010. ‘Flexibilidade e crise do
epz-2221273
emprego industrial: sindicatos, regiões e novas ações
Noronha, E.; D’Cruz, P. 2017. ‘New Identities require empresariais, Sociologias, 12 (25), pp. 252-284.
new strategies. Union formation in the IT/ITES sector’.
Rasmussen, M.; Pontusson, J. 2017. Working-class
In S. George, and S. Sinha (eds). Redefined labour
strength by institutional design? Unionization, partisan
spaces. New York/New Delhi: Routledge.
politics, and unemployment Insurance systems, 1870
to 2010, Comparative Political Studies, 51 (6).
REFERENCES 77
Reyneri, E. 2003. ‘Immigration and the underground Swider. S. 2000. The migrant domestic workers union
economy in the new receiving South European movement in Hong Kong. MS thesis Cornell University,
countries: manifold negative effects, manifold deep- Ithaca NY.
rooted causes’, International Review of Sociology, 13
Tapia, M.; Turner, L. 2013. ‘Union campaigns as
(1), pp. 117-43.
counter-movements: Mobilizing immigrant workers
Rodrik, D. 2016. “Premature deindustrialization”, in France and the United Kingdom’, British Journal of
Journal of Economic Growth, 21 (1), pp. 1–33. Industrial Relations, 51, pp. 601–622
Rosanvallon, P. 1988. La question syndicale. Histoire et Tapia, M.; Ibsen, C.L.; Kochan, T.A. 2015. ‘Mapping the
avenir d’une forme sociale. Paris: Calmann-Lévy. frontier of theory in industrial relations: the contested
role of worker representation’, Socio-Economic Review,
Rosenfeld, J. 2014. What Unions No Longer Do.
13, pp. 157-84.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Taylor, B.; Li, Q. 2007. ‘Is the ACFTU a union and does
Rueda, D. 2007. Social democracy inside out.
it matter?’, Journal of Industrial Relations, 49 (5), pp.
Partisanship and labour market policy in advanced
701–15.
industrialized Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University
Press. Todolí-Signes, A. 2017. ‘The end of the subordinate
worker? The on-demand economy, the gig economy,
Schmalz, S.; Thiel, M. 2017.’ IG Metall’s Comeback.
and the need for protection for crowdworkers’,
Trade union renewal in times of crisis’, Journal of
International Journal of Comparative Labour Law and
Industrial Relations, 59 (4), pp. 386–405.
Industrial Relations, 33 (2), pp. 241–268.
Schulze Bischoff, K., with C. Schmidt. 2007. Neue
Traub-Merz, R.; Pringle, T. (eds). 2018. Trade Unions
Selbständige im europäischen Vergleich. Düsseldorf:
in Transition. From Command to Market Economies.
Hans Böckler Stiftung.
Berlin: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung.
Schurman, S.J.; Eaton, A.E., with R. Gumbrell-
Trygstad, S.; Larsen, T.P.; Nergaard, K. 2018. ‘Dealing
McCormick, R. Hyman, C. DiLeo, G.M. Berroterán,
with austerity in the Northern European cleaning
S. Ryklief, M. Varga, and V. Viajar. 2012. Trade union
sector: Social partner strategies strengthen wage
organizing in the informal economy: A review of the
floors’, European Journal of Industrial Relations, online
literature on organizing in Africa, Asia, Latin America,
https://doi.org/10.1177/0959680118790818
North America and Western, Central and Eastern
Europe. Newark N.J., report to the American Center Vandaele, K. 2017. Belgique. Les syndicats sur le qui-
for International Labor Solidarity Rutgers University. vive pour soutenir les travailleurs des plateformes:
https://www.solidaritycenter.org/wp-content/ l’exemple des livreurs de repas. https://www.
uploads/2014/11/Rutgers.Trade-Union-Organizing-in- researchgate.net/publication/323616094
the-Informal-Economy.pdf.
—. 2018. Will trade unions survive in the platform
Scruggs, L.; Lange, P. 2002. ‘Where have all the economy? Emerging patterns of platform workers’
members gone? Globalization, institutions, and union collective voice and representation in Europe. Brussels,
density’, The Journal of Politics, 64 (1), pp. 126-153. ETUI Working Paper 2018/5.
Shalev, M., 1992. ‘The resurgence of labour Van Rie, T.; Marx, I.; Horemans, J. 2011. ‘Ghent revisited:
quiescence’, in M. Regini, ed. The Future of Labour Unemployment insurance and union membership in
Mouvements, London: Sage, pp.102-132. Belgium and the Nordic countries’, European Journal of
Industrial Relations, 17 (2), pp. 125–139.
Shin, K-Y. 2010. ‘Globalisation and the working class in
South Korea: Contestation, fragmentation and renewal’, Van Rij, C.; Saris, W. 1993. ‘Time dependency of trade
Journal of Contemporary Asia, 40 (2). union membership: An event-history analysis’, Quality
and Quantity, 27 (1), pp. 73–93.
Sridhar, R.; Panda, S. 2014. ‘Contract Employees’, Indian
Journal of Industrial Relations, 50 (2), pp. 204-212. Visser, J. 1990. “In search of inclusive unionism”,
Bulletin of Comparative Labour Relations, 18, pp. 1-278.
Song, J. 2014. Inequality in the workplace: Labor
market reform in Japan and Korea. Ithaca, NY: Cornell —. 1991. ‘Trends in Trade Union Membership’,
University Press. Employment Outlook 1991, Paris, OECD, pp. 97-134.
Standing, G. 2011.The precariat: The new dangerous —. 2001. ‘The First Part-time Economy of the World - A
class. London: Bloomsbury. model to be followed?’, Journal of European Social
Policy, 12 (1), pp. 23-41.
Stone, K.V.W.; Arthurs, H. (eds). 2013. Rethinking
employment regulation: After the standard contract —. 2002. ‘Why fewer European workers join unions.
of employment. New York: Russell Sage Foundation A social customs explanation of membership trends’,
Press. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 40 (3), pp. 403-
430.
78 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
—. 2018. ICTWSS database on institutional Williams, C.C.; Horodnic, I.A. 2018. ‘Evaluating the
characteristics of trade unions, wage setting, state prevalence and distribution of dependent self-
intervention and social pacts. Open access database at: employment: some lessons from the European
http://www.uva-aias.net/nl/ictwss. Working Conditions Survey’, Industrial Relations
Journal, 49 (2), pp. 109-127.
Visser J.; Hayter, S.; Gammarano, R. 2015. Trends in
collective bargaining coverage: Stability, erosion or Xhauflair, V.; Huybrechts, B.; Pichault, F. 2018. ‘How
decline? Geneva, ILO, Labour Relations and Collective can new players establish themselves in highly
Bargaining Policy Brief No. 1. institutionalized labour markets? A Belgian case study
in the area of project-based work’, British Journal of
Waddington, J.; Kerr, A.th 2002. ‘Unions fit for young
Industrial Relations, 56 (2), pp. 370–394.
workers?’, Industrial Relations Journal, 33 (4).
Western, B. 1997. Between class and market: Postwar
unionization in the capitalist democracies. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Endnotes
1 https://www.ilo.org/ilc/ILCSessions/previous-sessions/104/WCMS_375766/lang--en/index.htm;
https://www.ilo.org/ilc/ILCSessions/previous-sessions/104/reports/reports-to-the-conference/
WCMS_369026/lang--en/index.htm
2 https://www.ilo.org/global/topics/future-of-work/lang--en/index.htm
3 https://www.ilo.org/ilc/ILCSessions/108/committees/committee-of-the-whole/WCMS_711674/lang--en/
index.htm
4 Jelle Visser; Amsterdam Institute for Advanced Labour Studies (AIAS), University of Amsterdam; Bremen
International Graduate School for the Social Sciences (BIGSSS), University of Bremen (Jelle.Visser@uva.
nl). The initial push to write this paper came from Susan Hayter (DDG/P ILO) and I thank her for her
inspiration and the trust she placed in me. Special gratitude goes towards Maria Helena André (ACTRAV
ILO) who has made this research project possible. Rafael Peels (ACTRAV ILO) has been a most competent
and enthusiastic guide keeping the project of researching and writing this paper on track, and giving many
valuable comments. My gratitude extends to Alex Bryson, Rafael Gomez, Anke Hassel, Richard Hyman,
Mara Kahancová, Anders Kjellberg, Marcel van der Linden, Paul de Beer, Valeria Pulignano; Miroslav
Stojanoviç, and Kurt Vandaele for their willingness to read the draft version of this paper and give valuable
comments and suggestions for its improvement. I thank Philippe Pochet of the European Trade Union
Institute (ETUI) for organizing a seminar to discuss the paper with trade union representatives, among
them Rudy de Leeuw, president of the European Trade Union Confederation (ETUC) and Oliver Roethig,
regional secretary of UNI-Europe. Responsibility for the final text, its judgments and its errors lies solely
with the author.
5 ILO, 2015a, The Future of Work Centenary Initiative, Report by the Director-General, Geneva: ILO, point 9. See
also: https://www.ilo.org/global/topics/future-of-work/lang--en/index.htm
6 ITUC website, https://www.ituc-csi.org/IMG/pdf/18_02_02_list_of_affiliates_17th_gc.pdf (accessed 11/11/2018).
The list of affiliates dates from November 2017.
7 In the next paragraphs I have drawn inspiration from chapter 7 (“The Future of Work: Good Jobs for All”) of
IPSP (2018), Rethinking Society for the 21st Century. Report of the International Panel on Social Progress,
Cambridge University Press, 2018, vol. 1.
8 The informal sector refers to production units, informal employment refers to jobs. Unpaid family workers over
the age of 15 are always counted as informal. In the case of own-account workers and employers, the
informal employment status of the job is determined by the formal or informal nature of the enterprise.
Employees are considered working informally if the job is in the informal sector, or, when in the formal
sector, it is not declared, casual, of short duration and below the threshold for social security contributions
(ILO, 2018a:18-19).
9 The data dates from 2017 or the most recent year and covers 150 countries recorded in ILOSTAT (www.ilo.org/
ilostat/irdata), with additional data on membership composition and group union density rates from the
ICTWSS Database, 6.0 (http://uva-aias.net/en/ictwss). These statistics cover more than 90 per cent of
the world’s population with a fair distribution over world regions and income levels. Omitted are countries
plagued by (civil) war or catastrophic events, among them Afghanistan, Iraq, Syria, Yemen, Libya, Chad,
Somalia, Sudan, South Sudan, Central African Republic, Congo, the Democratic Republic of Congo, and Haiti,
while there is no data for North Korea, Bhutan, Turkmenistan, Tajikistan, Uzbekistan, Qatar, Jamaica or
Puerto Rico. Trade unions are banned in Iran, Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates. The membership
statistics refer to those in employment (in some cases also the unemployed) and they exclude pensioners
and members who have retired from the labour market but retained their union membership (e.g., some
12 million in Western European unions).
80 TRADE UNIONS IN THE BALANCE
10 The reason for not including these unions is that they are not independent from state or party, that workers
cannot freely choose which union to join, and that it is difficult to verify the membership numbers. The 303
million members claimed by the All-China Federation of Trade Unions (ACFTU) would, if correct, make up
58 per cent of the world’s total union membership. In recent times, China’s unions, while being sharply
criticized for not genuinely representing workers, have increasingly adopted a role of intermediating
between workers’ protests and management or local authorities (Chen, 2009; Friedman and Kuruvilla,
2014; Liu, 2019; 2014; Taylor and Li, 2010; China Labour Bulletin, http://www.clb.org.hk/).
11 Total employment statistics include employees, self-employed and own-account workers, unpaid family
workers and, alas, employers. A narrower calculation – without employers and without agriculture – would
have been preferable but is not available for many countries and thus does not allow a comparison across
world regions. Hence, we will make do with this less precise, but generally available yardstick.
12 The Trade Union Law stipulates that enterprises in which a trade union has been established must contribute
two per cent of their monthly payroll to union funds. Worker contributions are limited; https://www.clb.org.
hk/sites/default/files/工人运动三年报告%202015-17%20final.pdf
13 In Italy, the only developed country with a high share of unionized workers (and tenant farmers), the union
density rate is close to 100 per cent, with the unions fulfilling some of the insurance and administrative
functions of the state.
14 Israel appears to be the exception, with higher union density rates in commercial services.
15 Unfortunately, I have no later data.
16 This is an approximation, and the average entry and exit age is probably later for professionals and those with
an academic degree than in the case of workers.
17 In calculating this average and facilitating comparison with earlier years, I have omitted the extreme values for
the Baltic States (where there are virtually no union members under the age of 25).
18 By 2006, 130 countries had established over 3,500 EPZs within their borders, with an estimated 66 million
workers (Murray, 2018). The largest of these were in China, Indonesia, and Bangladesh.
19 In most countries where a comparison with a household survey based on much larger samples can be made,
the ESS estimates much lower density rates. I have adjusted the ESS data to the known average density
rates (see also OECD 2017 for this procedure followed for other compositional union membership data).
20 Union organizing of non-standard workers is not exogenous to the development of non-standard employment.
Elsewhere I have shown this. For example, in the Netherlands, Dutch women working part-time have
organized to make part-time work more attractive in terms of labour rights and work-family balance,
thus making part-time work the ‘norm’ or ‘standard’ for many if not most women with children (Visser,
2001). This is not to deny the continuing disadvantages of part-time work in terms of career and financial
independence.
21 ‘Ryanair turns Polish pilots into precarious workers‘, Financial Times, 1-11-2018.
22 https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:0::NO::P12100_ILO_CODE:R204.
23 https://www.ilo.org/global/topics/non-standard-employment/crowd-work/lang--en/index.htm
24 Sarah O’Connor, ‘How to manage the gig economy’s growing jobs market’, Financial Times, 30-10-2018.
25 For the most recent ILO resolution on the indicator, of October 2018: https://www.ilo.org/global/statistics-and-
databases/meetings-and-events/international-conference-of-labour-statisticians/20/WCMS_648636/
lang--en/index.htm
26 https://www.ilo.org/beirut/events/WCMS_535008/lang--en/index.htm
27 See https://www.ituc-csi.org/wagescampaign for the ongoing ITUC living wage campaign.
28 The Guardian, 27-10-2015.
Cover illustration © Julien Eichinger/Adobe Stock
Contact:
ACTRAV
International Labour Office
4 route des Morillons
CH-1211 Geneva 22
Switzerland
Tel. +41 22 799 70 21
e-mail: actrav@ilo.org