Wcms 492724
Wcms 492724
Wcms 492724
Mariya Aleksynska
Janine Berg
Mariya Aleksynska
Janine Berg
Publications of the International Labour Office enjoy copyright under Protocol 2 of the Universal Copyright Convention.
Nevertheless, short excerpts from them may be reproduced without authorization, on condition that the source is indicated.
For rights of reproduction or translation, application should be made to ILO Publications (Rights and Licensing),
International Labour Office, CH-1211 Geneva 22, Switzerland, or by email: rights@ilo.org. The International Labour Office
welcomes such applications.
Libraries, institutions and other users registered with a reproduction rights organization may make copies in accordance with
the licences issued to them for this purpose. Visit www.ifrro.org to find the reproduction rights organization in your country.
Firms' demand for temporary labour in developing countries: necessity or strategy? / Mariya Aleksynska, Janine Berg;
International Labour Office, Inclusive Labour Markets, Labour Relations and Working Conditions Branch. - Geneva: ILO,
2016 (Conditions of work and employment series ; No. 77)
International Labour Office Inclusive Labour Markets, Labour Relations and Working Conditions Branch.
temporary employment / temporary worker / enterprise level / business strategy / regulation / private sector / working
conditions / developing countries
13.01.3
The designations employed in ILO publications, which are in conformity with United Nations practice, and the presentation
of material therein do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the International Labour Office
concerning the legal status of any country, area or territory or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers.
The responsibility for opinions expressed in signed articles, studies and other contributions rests solely with their authors, and
publication does not constitute an endorsement by the International Labour Office of the opinions expressed in them.
Reference to names of firms and commercial products and processes does not imply their endorsement by the International
Labour Office, and any failure to mention a particular firm, commercial product or process is not a sign of disapproval.
ILO publications and digital products can be obtained through major booksellers and digital distribution platforms, or ordered
directly from ilo@turpin-distribution.com. For more information, visit our website: www.ilo.org/publns or contact
ilopubs@ilo.org.
Using data on private sector firms in developing countries, this paper investigates the
determinants of firms’ recourse to temporary labour. We find that there are two types of
firms: those that do not use temporary labour, and those that do. Among the latter, some
firms use temporary labour very intensively, suggesting that they may strategically organize
their production processes around this type of employment relationship. These firms are
different from others in their characteristics but also in their reasons for employing
temporary labour. At the same time, our main findings suggest that, for all firms in
developing countries, the key factors affecting demand for temporary labour are firm
expansion and the regulations authorising the use of temporary labour for permanent tasks.
Other employment protection legislation provisions have a limited and different effect,
depending on the type of firm.
Acknowledgements ............................................................................................................. iv
1. Introduction................................................................................................................... 1
6. Conclusions .................................................................................................................. 24
References ........................................................................................................................... 26
Annex .................................................................................................................................. 30
Annex
Appendix A: Sample Description ........................................................................................................ 30
Appendix B: Description of Variables ................................................................................................ 31
Appendix C: Descriptive Statistics...................................................................................................... 33
Our study is based on the World Bank Enterprise Survey, which is the largest and
most recent firm-level survey in the world. We use a sub-sample of over 72,000 private
firms covering 118 developing countries during the period from 2006 to 2014. The survey
contains detailed questions on firm’s current and past activities. To assess the role of labour
market institutions, we use a recently developed ILO EPLex indicator (ILO, 2015c), which
measures the degree of employment protection afforded to workers with permanent
contracts. We also test the relevance of fixed-term contracts regulations, employing an
indicator of whether fixed-term contracts (FTCs) are authorized for permanent tasks and an
indicator of whether FTCs have legal limits or can be used for unlimited duration.
Our main findings are three. First, the micro-level hypotheses for firm use of
temporary labour identified by previous literature as relevant for developed countries –
flexibility needs, cost saving strategies, and technological adjustments – are relevant in
developing countries, too.
Second, the data and our empirical results suggest that there exist two types of firms:
those that do not use temporary labour, and those that do. Firms that do not use any
temporary labour (at least not on a regular basis), represent the majority of formal firms in
developing countries, their share is about 60 per cent. Firms using temporary labour do so
quite intensively: on average, about one third of their workforce is temporary. This average,
however, also hinders important disparities across firms, as there are 5 per cent of firms that
account for 57 per cent of all temporary labour, and 18 per cent of using firms have 50 per
cent or more of their workforce staffed with temporary workers. Thus, it seems that some of
the using firms use temporary labour not only for what can be called “traditional” purposes,
such as replacing a temporarily absent worker, meeting short-term needs of seasonal spikes
in demand, or for screening and probation, but also strategically, organizing their production
processes around the use of temporary labour. Moreover, employing temporary labour may
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section II contains a review of the
literature and the main hypotheses that have been advanced to explain firms’ use of
temporary labour. In Section III, we provide a brief description of the data, followed by
descriptive statistics in Section IV. Section V provides the main results of our analysis,
distinguishing between those factors that are more ‘internal’ to the firm and those that are
‘external’, as well as between different types of firms. The last section gives a summary of
our findings and discusses the implications for policy debates.
On the other hand, firms also need to ensure that they have sufficient, knowledgeable
staff to carry out the core operations of the firm and ensure firm longevity. Thus firms often
seek the right balance between stability and flexibility in their workforce. Economists have
long recognized that firms operate with this consideration in mind. In their seminal study of
internal labour markets, Doeringer and Piore (1971) explained how within a firm there are
essentially two labour markets, a primary, or internal, market consisting of jobs that are
well-paid, stable and with advancement opportunities and a secondary, or external, market,
which is lower-paid, lower-skilled and with fewer opportunities for training and
advancement. The authors explained how many firms in diverse industries organized their
workforce as internal labour markets, but also relied on a secondary group of workers whose
skills were general and where the recruitment, screening and training costs were markedly
lower.
Building on the insights of Doeringer and Piore (1971) and the efficiency-wage model
of Bulow and Summers (1986) and Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984), Saint-Paul (1996) shows
mathematically how dualism along the permanent-temporary workers divide can arise
endogenously within a firm as a response to demand fluctuations. Because searching and
recruiting workers with necessary skills and monitoring their work is costly, firms pay
efficiency wages (wages above market clearing) to both motivate and retain workers. Since
adjusting such labour to demand fluctuations is also costly, firms will have an incentive to
split their workforce into a higher-paid, primary or core workforce and a secondary, or
peripheral, workforce, for whom the adjustment costs are substantially lower. These
adjustment costs may be related to the direct firing costs, but stem primarily because
secondary employees are paid less than the efficiency wages that primary employees
receive. Saint-Paul (1996) shows that such dualism arises naturally and can be optimal for a
firm, even in absence of labour market institutions and regulations, such as employment
protection legislation. In countries where firms have limited possibility of choosing which
workers can be granted employment security because of the existing employment protection
Some further nuances regarding the use of temporary workers as “buffers” is provided
by the literature examining the role of unions and collective bargaining in firm’s decision to
hire temporary workers. On the one hand, unions may contribute to growing recourse of
temporary employment if it helps isolate permanent workers from the negative effects of
demand volatility and technological shocks (Saint-Paul, 1996; Bentolila and Dolado, 1994;
Abraham and Taylor, 1996). Thus, a few empirical studies have found that temporary
contracts are more wide-spread in countries with higher union densities or higher collective
bargaining coverage (Kahn, 2007; Baranowska and Gebel, 2010; Hevenstone, 2010). On the
other hand, unions may also oppose the recourse to temporary labour, either out of social
cohesion considerations (Visser, 2002), or because they may perceive temporary workers as
threats to their bargaining power (Heery, 2004), especially when firms strategically use
externalized workers to diminish unions’ power (Hatton, 2014).
Second, organizations may value the lower direct labour costs that firms incur while
using temporary labour, because in a vast majority of cases, temporary workers are indeed
Third, the use of temporary employment, especially in the European context of the
past three decades, has often been explained by the significantly lower firing costs
associated with terminating temporary contracts, as compared to permanent contracts. While
workers on fixed-term contracts are typically well protected during the period covered by
the contract (in some instances, termination of such contracts before their end date may
entail payment of all wages due until the contractual end date), at the end of the contract,
generally no reasons need to be provided by the employer to justify the end of the
employment relationship, beyond the end date of a fixed-term contract being reached. In
contrast, terminating employment relationship with permanent workers, at the initiative of
the employer, usually entails certain costs, including severance payments, costs associated
with notification procedures, and other compensatory payments if terminations are unfair.
Starting in the 1970s, numerous European countries partly deregulated labour markets with
the aim of increasing labour market flexibility, by allowing for a wider use of temporary
contracts, by expanding their scope to jobs that were not temporary in nature, and by
increasing the allowed duration and number of renewals. At the same time, employment
protection for permanent workers remained relatively intact. As a result, the wedge in the
costs associated with terminating a temporary and a permanent worker grew, leading many
researchers to attribute the growth of temporary employment in some European countries to
these partial reforms (Bentolila and Dolado, 1994; Blanchard and Landier, 2002; Boeri and
Garibaldi, 2007; Faccini, 2014; OECD, 2014). Similar reforms on the use of temporary
labour occurred in some developing countries, particularly Peru (Vega-Ruíz, 2005).
Nonetheless, the low separation costs for temporary workers has to be weighed against costs
associated with the frequent search for new workers (Holmlund and Storrie, 2002).
3. Data description
Our analysis is based on the World Bank Enterprises Survey, a representative firm-
level survey of private companies in developing countries. The data were collected between
2006 and 2014, with most countries being surveyed twice, and a few countries, such as
Bulgaria and Chile, surveyed three times. Apart from a small overlap, a different set of
enterprises was surveyed in each wave, leading us to choose a pooled setting for the data
analysis.
The survey data are collected from face-to-face interviews with top managers and
business owners of formal (registered) companies with 5 or more employees , operating in
manufacturing and services sectors. The survey covers a broad range of questions on firm-
level characteristics, business environment topics, and characteristics of the firms’
workforce, including the number of temporary and permanent workers in an enterprise. The
latter questions allow computing both the use and the prevalence of temporary workers (as a
share of all employees) in an enterprise.
Using this question, combined with the question on the number of permanent full-
time employees employed in an establishment, we construct a variable temp_share_all, as a
ratio of temporary workers to the sum of temporary and permanent workers. This variable is
used as principal dependent variable in further analysis. As explained below, we also test
alternative dependent variables.
In addition, we complement the World Bank Enterprises Survey with macro data from
various sources. Data on GDP growth and GDP per capita are from the World Bank
statistical portal; unemployment is from ILO STAT. To assess the role of regulations on
termination of permanent contracts we use a recently developed ILO EPLex indicator
measuring the overall degree of protection afforded by legislation to workers on permanent
contracts (ILO, 2015c). Lastly, we also complement these data with two dichotomous
variables from the World Bank’s Doing Business indicators describing the regulation of
fixed-term contracts (FTCs): the first takes value one if FTCs are authorised for permanent
tasks, and zero otherwise; the second takes value one if FTC regulations specify any limits
to the FTC duration, and zero otherwise.
Source: Own computations based on the World Bank Enterprise Survey, 2015.
Notes: Data for 135 countries, for the latest available year, ranging from 2005 for Morocco and Egypt to 2014
for Afghanistan and Myanmar. For the majority of countries (67), data refer to 2009 or 2010.
Interestingly, however, only about 40 per cent of all firms throughout the world
employ temporary workers, meaning that about 60 per cent of firms do not use temporary
labour at all. The minority of firms that use temporary labour use it quite intensively: on
average, about one third of their workforce is temporary (Figure 2). A closer look reveals
however a strong heterogeneity across the using firms: 5 per cent of firms account for using
57 per cent of all temporary labour. From Figure 2, it is also apparent that there is a certain
spike at 50 per cent of temporary labour, suggesting a possible categorization within the
using firms. Firms with fewer than 50 per cent of temporary workers in their workforce
account for 82 per cent of all using firms, and the mean share of temporary workers among
them is a rather moderate 19 per cent. Firms with 50 per cent or more of temporary workers
in their workforce account for 18 per cent of all using firms, and the mean share of
temporary workers among them is 63 per cent. This suggests that there are some firms that
may self-select into being high users of temporary labour, with their production process and
human resource strategy organized around the use of temporary workers. Also, plausibly,
firms make their decision about hiring temporary labour in two steps: they first decide
whether to use or not temporary labour, and only then they decide how much.
5
4
3
Density
2
1
0
0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
temporary employees as % of all employees, employed by a firm in fiscal year
Source: Own computations based on the World Bank Enterprise Survey, 2015.
Notes: Data for 118 countries (baseline regression sample), all survey years (2006-2014).
Thus, we also checked the differences in means of characteristics of firms that do not
use temporary labour, and the firms that do, distinguishing also between moderate and
intensive users (Appendix C). The differences in most firm characteristics appear to be
statistically significant based on t-tests for differences of sample means. While it is difficult
to find a common pattern in these descriptive results, moderate users of temporary labour
are more similar to non-using firms in terms of labour efficiency. They are also the ones that
provide the most training to permanent staff. Figure 3 shows the distribution of firm size
across three types of firms, and suggests that both types of using firms are bigger in size as
compared to non-using firms, with intensive users having a potential to be more sizeable
than all others. Thus, it seems that there are worthy differences between these firms.
Figure 3. Distribution of firm employees (in logs), by type of firm with respect to temps use
.4
.3
.2
.1
0
0 2 4 6 8 10
x
Non-using Traditional
Intensive
Source: Own computations based on the World Bank Enterprise Survey, 2015.
Notes: Data for 118 countries (baseline regression sample), all survey years (2006-2014).
0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
x
Lower- and lower-middle income countries Upper-middle and higher-income countries
Source: Own computations based on the World Bank Enterprise Survey, 2015.
Notes: Data for 118 countries, all survey years (2006-2014). World Bank typology of countries by income
Correlation: -0.137
.3
Timor Leste2009
Tanzania2013
Liberia2009
Togo2009 Uganda2013
Mongolia2009
Chad2009 Kenya2013
Congo2009
Mongolia2013
Afghanistan2008
Benin2009 Bolivia2006 Peru2006
.2
Vietnam2009
Philippines2009
Rwanda2011
Lesotho2009 DRC2010 Kenya2007 Ukraine2013
Bhutan2009 Kyrgyz Tanzania2006 Peru2010
Republic2013
Honduras2006 Iraq2011
Kosovo2013 Panama2006 Colombia2010
Micronesia2009 BurkinaFaso2009
Mauritania2006
Mali2010 Bolivia2010
Paraguay2006
Vanuatu2009 Niger2009 Colombia2006
Guyana2010 Nicaragua2006
Gabon2009
Centralafricanrepublic2011
Kosovo2009 Elsalvador2010
ElSalvador2006
Samoa2009Gambia2006 Rwanda2006
Kyrgyz Republic2009
Tajikistan2013
Mali2007 Yemen2010
SriLanka2011
Uganda2006
Nepal2013 Venezuela2010
Ecuador2006
CapeVerde2009
Djibouti2013 Paraguay2010
TrinidadandTobago2010
Nicaragua2010
Georgia2008 Venezuela2006
Montenegro2009
Botswana2006
Armenia2009 Bangladesh2007
Ethiopia2011
Guatemala2006
Malawi2009 Côte
Madagascar2009
Tajikistan2008 d'Ivoire2009 Chile2006 Pakistan2007
Poland2009
StKittsandNevis2010
Grenada2010 Zambia2013
LaoPDR2012
Costarica2010
Nepal2009
Angola2006
Guatemala2010
.1
Bahamas2010 Honduras2010
Cameroon2009
DRC2006
Georgia2013 Chile2010
Montenegro2013
Namibia2006 DRC2013 Nigeria2007
Fiji2009 Moldova2009
Barbados2010 Albania2007
Senegal2007Ghana2007 SouthAfrica2007
StVincentandGrenadines2010
Swaziland2006 Botswana2010
Mauritius2009
Guinea2006 Indonesia2009
Burundi2006 Mozambique2007Uruguay2006 Azerbaijan2009
Zambia2007
Bosnia andCroatia2007
Herzegovina2009
DominicanRepublic2010
Croatia2013
Serbia2009
Mexico2010
GuineaBissau2006
Eritrea2009 Fyr Macedonia2009
Uruguay2010
Estonia2009 Angola2010
CzechBangladesh2013
Republic2009 China2012
Tonga2009 Latvia2009 Russia2012
Brazil2009
Albania2013 Lithuania2013 Kazakhstan2013 Russia2009
Jamaica2010 Lithuania2009 Azerbaijan2013
Serbia2013
Suriname2010 Latvia2013 Belarus2008 Ukraine2008
Kazakhstan2009
Romania2009
Belarus2013 Mexico2006
Belize2010 Bosnia and Herzegovina2013
Armenia2013
Fyr Macedonia2013 Turkey2008
Antiguaandbarbuda2010 Panama2010 Bulgaria2013
Hungary2009
Moldova2013
LaoPDR2009 Bulgaria2007 Romania2013
StLucia2010
Dominica2010 Bulgaria2009
Sierra Leone2009
0
20 22 24 26 28 30
GDP PPP, in logs
Source: Own computations based on the World Bank Enterprise Survey, 2015; and World Bank ICP, 2015.
Notes: Data for 166 country-year pairs (117 countries).
0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
x
FTCs prohibited for permanent tasks FTCs authorized for permanent tasks
Source: Own computations based on the World Bank Enterprise Survey, 2015; and WB DB 2015 information.
Notes: Data for 118 countries, all survey years (2006-2014).
Correlation: 0.029
.3
Tanzania2013
Uganda2013
Mongolia2009
Afghanistan2008
Mongolia2013
.2
Rwanda2011 Vietnam2009
Philippines2009
Afghanistan2014
DRC2010 Lesotho2009
Tanzania2006
Peru2010
Panama2006
BurkinaFaso2009
Niger2009
Gabon2009
Elsalvador2010 Centralafricanrepublic2011
Yemen2010
SriLanka2011
Venezuela2010
Georgia2008 Bangladesh2007
Armenia2009Ethiopia2011
Madagascar2009
Côte d'Ivoire2009
Zambia2013 Malawi2009Angola2006
.1
Cameroon2009
Georgia2013 Honduras2010
DRC2006
Chile2010
Nigeria2007 DRC2013Moldova2009 Montenegro2013
Senegal2007
SouthAfrica2007
Mexico2010 Azerbaijan2009 Indonesia2009
Argentina2010
China2012
Bangladesh2013 Angola2010
Fyr Macedonia2009 Czech Republic2009
Russia2012
Mexico2006 Serbia2013
Romania2009
Hungary2009 Fyr Macedonia2013
Bulgaria2013Panama2010
Antiguaandbarbuda2010
Moldova2013
Romania2013
StLucia2010
0
.2 .4 .6 .8
Level of employment protection, regular contracts
Source: Own computations based on the World Bank Enterprise Survey, 2015; and ILO EPLex (ILO, 2015d)
information
Notes: Data for 63 country-year pairs (45 countries).
5.1 Specifications
Drawing on the overview of the literature, we start by examining the role of various
factors in firm’s decision regarding the amount of temporary labour to employ. The reasons
that prompt firm’s use of temporary labour are divided into those reasons that are ‘internal’
to the firm (micro-level) and those that are ‘external’ (macro-level). Within internal reasons,
we distinguish between those that are related to flexibility, cost, and technology. For
external factors, we test the relevance of the macroeconomic conditions and labour market
institutions.
Our empirical set-up follows closely Davis-Blake and Uzzi (1993), Devicienti et al.
(2014), and Portugal et al. (2009). The baseline specification allowing to analyse the firm-
level internal determinants of using temporary workforce is as follows:
Among the individual baseline firm characteristics Xi, we include the total number of
employees in a firm and its square, to capture both the actual firm size and its possible
nonlinear effects; firm age as a difference between the year of the survey and the date of
firms’ creation; two dichotomous variables for firm ownership: whether the firm is mainly
owned by domestic private or foreign private individuals, the benchmark category being
whether the firm is owned by domestic government; as well as average productivity, defined
as logarithm of the ratio of the last years’ establishment’s total annual sales converted in the
US dollars divided by all employees, as a measure (or rough proxy) of efficiency2.
To analyze the relevance of macro factors, we also estimate specifications such as (2),
where Kkt is the country-year specific macroeconomic variable.
Temp_share_all ijkt = αijk + β1i Xi + β2iYi + β3kt Kkt + jj + tt+ εijkt (2)
Since not all countries are observed more than once in the data, to avoid
multicollinearity issues, in such regressions, we omit country fixed effects, but cluster errors
on the country level. We first estimate (1) and (2) by OLS, to obtain results comparable to
those in the literature.
Lastly, we also consider the possibility that firms make their decisions regarding
hiring temporary labour in two steps, first deciding whether to employ it or not, and only
afterwards deciding on the amount. In these specifications, we use Cragg (1971) hurdle
model, in which different factors affect each stage. Our hurdle model is characterized by the
relationship:
where si is the selection variable equal to one if firms employ any temporary labour,
and zero otherwise:
1 𝑖𝑓 𝑍𝑖 𝛾 + 𝜀𝑖 > 0
𝑠𝑖 = { (4)
0 𝑜𝑡ℎ𝑒𝑟𝑤𝑖𝑠𝑒
In its turn, hijkt * is the continuous latent dependent variable observed only if si = 1.
The linear outcome model is:
1
Alternatively, one could also include survey dummies. We prefer separating country and time fixed effects, to
the extent that several countries were surveyed several times, and there is enough variation in both countries and
years.
2
To explore the rich data at hand, we also tested potential importance of some other variables, such as a
dichotomous variable for female ownership, a dichotomous variable measuring whether a firm has been
formally registered when it began operations, and a variable measuring the skill production mix (computed as a
ratio of permanent full-time employees that are skilled production workers, compared to all full-time permanent
workers). We have not found any statistically significant effects on these variables (not reported, but available
on request), and hence did not retain them for further specifications. We did find a statistically significant effect
on the variable measuring the proportion of nonproduction employees to all permanent full-time employees
(equally not reported); however, this variable is only available for manufacturing, thus considerably reducing
the sample size. We have not retained it in further specifications either.
where Xi, Yi and Kkt are the micro and macro explanatory variables as in equations
(1) and (2).
Flexibility hypothesis
More specifically, the information on the principal market served is constructed from
the survey question regarding the main market (either local, national or international) in
which the establishment sold its major product over the past year. From these responses, we
construct two dichotomous variables, the first equal to one if the principal market served is
national, and the second equal to one if the principal market is international, with local
market being a benchmark category.
Firms may need more flexibility when they expand their operations. As a measure of
expansion, we include the ratio of current number of permanent employees to the number of
permanent employees three years ago (expansion over a short to medium term). Higher
values of this variable capture a mid-term and long-term growth of the core labour force and
firm’s expansion.
3
There is literature addressing how unionization can affect, both positively and negatively, firms’ recourse to
temporary labour. We used information on the share of unionized workers in an enterprise to explore this issue.
The variable has an insignificant effect, but it is also available for only a fifth of the sample (the question is
asked in only 27 countries, and only in 2006; with substantial number of missing values). Thus, we do not retain
this variable for further analysis.
Note: Dependent variable in columns 1-4 is the share of temporary employees in a firm. Estimation method: OLS. All
regressions include sector, country, and year effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses. ** - significant at 1 per cent,
* - significant at 5 per cent.
All of these variables are found to have a statistically significant impact on the use of
temporary labour both in the individual and (with some exceptions) joint specification
(column 4 of Table 3), confirming the relevance of the flexibility hypothesis for firms in
developing countries. As will be shown later, however, the only robust variables are,
however, the ones measuring firm expansion and to a certain extent informal competition
and demand volatility. While some of the firm’s growth can happen because of the
conversion of temporary into permanent contracts and investing in personnel, our results
show that the firm expansion is accommodated by the use of temporary labour. Conversely,
companies that had downsized might have done so at the expense of changing
organizational structure, job definitions, but also terminating or not-renewing temporary
labour.
Cost hypothesis
While many of the flexibility-related variables also embed cost factors, the literature
offers more direct ways of testing for the relevance of the cost hypothesis. We follow it by
including, in Table 3 column 2, the total labour costs, as well as controls for whether firms
offer training to permanent staff. Our estimation results show that the higher is the total
labour bill (expressed in logarithmic term, and converted into USD), the higher is the
incidence of temporary labour. The training dummy also shows a positive and significant
result. The literature suggests that training effects may be different depending of the nature
of temporary jobs and depending on the nature of training. The positive coefficient on
training offered to permanent workers is in line with the hypothesis suggesting that firms
organize their workforce along the core-periphery model, whereby the core workforce
receives training and is used with a long-term perspective, while the periphery workforce,
which is also usually less skilled and lower paid, rotates regularly.
Technology factors
To check the relevance of technology, we use three variables: the degree to which
telecommunications were perceived as an obstacle to the current operations of the
establishment; whether the establishment has an internationally recognized certification; and
whether the establishment uses any technology licensed from a foreign-owned company
(Table 3, column 3). The telecommunications variable most likely reflects volatility in
production and thus the need to have a ‘buffer’ of labour, rather than the effect of
technology on the standardization of production and the use of different types of labour. The
In the remainder of Table 4, we test the relevance of the labour market regulations
governing the termination of regular contracts and the use of fixed-term contracts. To
measure the level of protection afforded by employment protection legislation for regular
contracts, we include the newly developed EPLex indicator (ILO, 2015c), which accounts
for all aspects of employment protection legislation, such as the extent of protection
afforded by valid and prohibited grounds for dismissal, trial periods, notification procedures
and length of notice period, severance and redundancy payments, and redress provisions.
While this indicator is available for 100 countries around the world and spanning 2009-
2014; its overlap with the World Bank Enterprises Survey country sample is not perfect and
restricts our sample to 45 countries. As some of the authors using these indicators note, it is
also important to look at the role of each individual EPL sub-component, rather than at the
EPL aggregates (Verkerke and Freyens, 2016 forthcoming). Thus, we use both aggregated
EPLex indicator, to compare our results with those found in the literature, and the
disaggregated components, to have a better understanding which EPL pillar is more
relevant. To measure the regulations governing the use of fixed-term contracts, we use the
World Bank’s Doing Business Indicators database, and specifically two dichotomous
variables: one on whether FTCs are prohibited for permanent tasks; and the other on
whether legislation does not limit the use of FTCs .
We further checked robustness of these findings not only to the model specification,
but also to alternative dependent variables and to the estimation methods, in Table 5.
Column 1 is a replication of Table 3 column 4 for comparative purposes. Column 2 of Table
5 is also a replication of Table 3 column 4, but on a sample restricted to the one with
available institutional data. This ensures that we compare changes in coefficients that are
due to changes in the model, not to the sample. Column 3 of Table 5 adds further
disaggregated EPL variables and regulations of fixed-term contracts. In column 4, the
dependent variable is a binary variable equal to one if firms use any temporary labour, and
zero otherwise; the estimation method is probit. Because a substantial percentage of firms do
not employ temporary labour at all, our dependent variable, expressed either as a share or as
a number of temporary workers, features a sizeable number of zeroes. Thus, in column 5, we
also fit the Poisson count model which may be seen as more appropriate than OLS. All in
all, our results are consistent across the different specifications.
Table 5. Robustness of the results. Modelling the “two-step” firm decision process
VARIABLES (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Share, OLS, Share, Hurdle Hurdle Hurdle
Share, T3 EPL OLS Dummy; Share; Model : Model : Model :
OLS, T3 sample EPL Probit Poisson full «moderate» «intensive
users » users
-2.69e-
Total N employees -6.52e-06 -1.12e-05* -1.22e-05* -2.60e-05 -0.001 05** -1.81e-05** -9.91e-06
(4.38e- (7.37e-
06) (4.69e-06) (4.66e-06) (3.70e-05) 05) (9.17e-06) (6.58e-06) (1.78e-05)
Total N employees
squared 2.66e-10 4.77e-10* 5.07e-10* 1.23e-09 5.26e-09 1.13e-09* 8.77e-10** 1.82e-09
(1.94e- (3.54e-
10) (2.17e-10) (2.18e-10) (1.68e-09) 09) (4.41e-10) (2.96e-10) (3.83e-09)
Firm age 0.004** 0.0003** 0.0003** 0.005** 0.001 -0.0003* -0.0006** 0.0005*
(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0009) (0.002) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001)
Own : domestic
private -0.002 -0.007 -0.009 -0.304 -0.133 0.0325 0.033** 0.004
(0.011) (0.012) (0.013) (0.205) (0.141) (0.016) (0.012) (0.014)
Own : foreign
private 0.005 0.002 -0.001 -0.147 -0.049 0.031 0.024 0.014
(0.011) (0.013) (0.017) (0.190) (0.159) (0.019) (0.014) (0.017)
Ln (Efficiency) -0.008** -0.008** -0.008** -0.094** -0.086** -0.002 0.003* -0.005**
(0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.015) (0.017) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
National market -0.0004 -0.001 -0.001 -0.002 -0.002 -0.006 -0.011* -0.004
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.032) (0.056) (0.007) (0.005) (0.006)
International
market 0.002 0.001 0.001 -0.059 -0.013 0.021* -0.004 0.004
(0.006) (0.007) (0.006) (0.056) (0.092) (0.011) (0.008) (0.009)
Informal
competition 0.012** 0.009** 0.008* 0.117** 0.096* 0.006 0.009* -0.007
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.029) (0.048) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005)
Demand volatility 0.002** 0.002* 0.002* 0.012 0.015 0.003* 0.002 0.004*
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.008) (0.014) (0.001) (0.003) (0.002)
Employment
current 0.094** 0.095** 0.094** 0.492** 0.354** 0.106** 0.051** 0.038**
to that three years
ago (0.005) (0.006) (0.006) (0.046) (0.010) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Access to finance 0.0002 0.001 0.003* 0.003 0.022 0.006* 0.004** -0.0001
is an obstacle (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.012) (0.018) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Ln (Total labor
cost) 0.003** 0.004* 0.005** 0.117** 0.046** -0.017** -0.018** 0.004*
(0.0001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.012) (0.017) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Training offered 0.007** 0.016** 0.012** 0.230** 0.180** -0.013* -0.015** 0.018**
(0.003) (0.005) (0.004) (0.033) (0.051) (0.006) (0.004) (0.005)
Regulations is an 0.003* 0.006** 0.007** 0.068** 0.056* 0.007* 0.005* 0.001
obstacle (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.016) (0.023) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002)
Education is an -0.0007 -0.0003 -0.0002 0.028* 0.019 -0.008** -0.003 -0.003
obstacle (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.013) (0.021) (0.003) (0.001) (0.003)
Certification -0.003 0.003 0.006 -0.048 0.088 0.041** 0.023** 0.031**
(0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.046) (0.059) (0.007) (0.005) (0.007)
4
As such, we do not report the results, but they are available upon request.
Taken together, results in Table 5 column 6 show that many variables considered up
to now do not stand robustness check to this alternative specification, either losing
significance or reversing signs. In order to better understand these results, we exploit
another key observation from the descriptive statistics suggesting that there may also be
different types of firms that use temporary labour: some firms use temporary workforce in
“moderate” amounts, while others use it very intensively. In some sense, the former firms
may be more similar to firms that do not use any temporary labour at all then to intensive
users. For example, moderate users may be those non-using firms that occasionally happen
to use some temporary labour for what can be called “traditional” reasons, such as replacing
a temporarily absent worker, meeting short fluctuations in seasonal demand, or for
probation, with the aim of converting them into permanent employees. In contrast, intensive
users would be those that strategically organize their production process around the
possibility of using temporary labour. Thus, the true difference may not between the using
and non-using firms, but firms that use temporary labour very intensively and all others.
To explore this possibility, we divide the firms that use temporary labour into two
groups, based on descriptive statistics. The first group is composed of moderate, or
traditional, users: these are the firms that have fewer than 50 per cent of temporary labour in
their workforce. They represent 87 per cent of the sample of the using firms. The second
group is composed of intensive, or strategic, users: these are the firms in which 50 per cent
The results of these two estimations are striking. They help explain why the
aggregated hurdle model gave unexpected and very mixed results, and also reinforce the
idea that the two types of using firms are very different. They also help understand why
existing literature on firm use of temporary labour, which did not distinguish between these
different firms, sometimes produced opposing results on the role of some firm-level
characteristics. Approximately half of the variables in the model differentiating between
non-using and moderately-using firms have signs as suggested by previous literature and by
our own previous estimations; but the same is also true in the model differentiating between
intensive users and all other firms. Specifically, contrasting column 7 and 8 of Table 5, we
find that intensive users are older and less efficient, they are also more labour-intensive
firms that use temporary labour to face demand volatility and to save on labour costs. In
contrast, moderate users are younger, more efficient, and less labour-intensive; they choose
to employ temporary labour to cope with informal competition and credit constrains, as well
as under the condition that the costs of labour are low. A case in point is the switching sign
on the training for permanent staff variable. For intensive users, it appears with a positive
and significant sign. Existing literature suggests that finding a positive sign is in line with
the hypothesis that firms organize their workforce along the core-periphery model, whereby
the core workforce receives training and is used with a long-term perspective, while the
periphery workforce, which is also usually less skilled and less paid, rotates regularly and
can be terminated at any time, for example, when just-in-time production needs are met. For
moderate users, the sign on the training for permanent staff is negative, and this finding is
also legitimate in the literature. It signifies that most of the firms’ workforce is core and
benefits from equal access to training, while temporary labour is used for probationary
reasons, with the aim of converting them to permanent jobs. Finding this opposite sign on
training reinforces the idea that “intensive” and “moderate” users differ in their approach as
to what role that temporary labour is supposed to serve.
Interestingly, the only firm-level variable that has the same sign for both types of
firms is employment current to that three years ago, suggesting that expanding firms use
temporary labour more intensively. In a separate set of regressions (not reported, but
available on request), we also interacted this variable with sector dummies in order to
capture the extent to which decisions to employ temporary labour may be driven by
specificities of the production process. For moderate users, expansion in any sector leads to
higher use of temporary labour, indicating once again that the moderate using firms are
adding workers in response to increasing demand. For intensive users, however, only an
expansion in six of the fifteen sectors (leather, food, metals and machinery, chemicals and
pharmaceuticals, non-metal sector, and construction) leads to greater use of temporary
labour. This suggests again that the reasons for employing large amounts of temporary
labour among ‘intensive’ users goes beyond pressures of increased demand. Moreover, it
does not seem that the structure of the production process associated with these sectors is
driving firms’ decision to primarily employ temporary workers, as these sectors entail a
wide variety of production methods.
5
We also tried alternative thresholds. The results presented in this section still hold true if we set the threshold
of 40 per cent; they start being different from those presented here if a lower threshold is chosen. We prefer to
keep the 50 per cent threshold, as it is justified by descriptive statistics (Figure 2). It is of course possible that
some firms with fewer than 50 per cent of temporary labour also use temporary labour strategically and as part
of their human resources model.
Our results on EPL are different from those of Pierre and Scarpetta (2013), who report
that the level of EPL has a positive effect on the firm’s use of temporary labour, while
regulations of fixed-term contracts do not play a role. The differences between their results
and ours are mainly due to a different sample size, different modelling of the firm decision
to use temporary labour, different set of controls, different estimation techniques (notably
distinguishing between different types of using firms), and a different measure of EPL (they
rely on the World Bank’s Employing Workers measures that include procedural
requirements, notice period, and severance payments, we use numerous additional EPL
components). While we also find some evidence that some of the EPL components, though
not the aggregate EPL, may foster the use of temporary labour by some firms, we find a
more expected, consistent, and strong effect of regulations of fixed-term contracts on the
firm use of temporary labour.
6. Conclusions
This study has sought to increase understanding of the use of temporary labour by
firms in developing countries. Using firm-level data from the World Bank Enterprise
Survey, we attempted to identify the reasons that motivate firms to rely on temporary labour.
The vast country coverage also allowed us to examine the role of labour market institutions
and of the macroeconomic environment in affecting firms’ demand for temporary labour,
providing a new evidence for non-OECD, non-European countries, and also providing new
evidence to developments during a period of global economic crisis. As such, the study
contributes to a better understanding of both firm-level and country-level determinants of
temporary labour use in developing countries.
The paper showed that the use of temporary labour differs widely across firms, with
the majority of firms (60 per cent) not using temporary labour at all. Within the 40 per cent
of firms that do use temporary labour, temporary labour accounts for 28 per cent of the
labour force on average, but there is wide variability in use.
Our analysis indicates that firms’ motivation for using temporary labour is similar to
that found in studies on industrialized countries. Flexibility and cost considerations are the
key motivators; in particular, it is the expanding firms that are in the highest demand for
temporary labour. At the same time, the novel result of this paper is to distinguish between
There has been a growing concern in recent policy debates about an increase in non-
standard forms of employment and the decline of the standard employment relationship.
Although temporary contracts are just one form of atypical contract, little is known about
their use in developing countries. This study was an attempt at exploring trends in the use of
temporary labour across developing countries in order to better understand firms’ principal
motivations. From a policy perspective, our findings are telling as they improve
policymakers understanding of business constraints, but also give evidence of the scope of
legislation to tailor business practices. They are also important in light of proposals for
reforms of regulations of both permanent and temporary contracts, because they indicate
that some reforms would have a different impact depending on the type of the firm. For
example, according to our results, changes in the regulations of permanent contracts would
probably do little to curb the use of temporary labour by those firms that already built this
practice into their production processes. In contrast, there may be merits to some more
specific policies targeted at firms using temporary labour intensively, especially if there is
evidence of abuse of such practice.
Baranowska, A.; Gebel, M. 2010. “The Determinants of Youth Temporary Employment in the
Enlarged Europe: Do Labour Market Institutions Matter?”, in European Societies, Vol.
12, No. 3, pp. 367–390.
Benito, A.; Hernando, I. 2008. “Labour Demand, Flexible Contracts and Financial Factors:
Firm-Level Evidence from Spain”, in Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol.
70, No. 3, pp. 283–301.
Bentolila S.; Dolado, J.J. 1994. “Labour flexibility and wages: lessons from Spain”, in Economic
Policy, Vol. 9, Nr. 18, pp. 53-99.
Bentolila, S.; Saint-Paul, G. 1994. "A model of labor demand with linear adjustment costs", in
Labour Economics, Vol. 1, No. 3-4, pp. 303-326.
Blanchard, O.; Landier, A. 2002. “The perverse effects of partial labour market reform: fixed -
term contracts in France”, in Economic Journal, Vol. 112, No. 480, pp. F189–213.
Boeri T.; Garibaldi, P. 2007. “Two tier reforms of employment protection legislation. A
honeymoon effect?”, in The Economic Journal, Vol. 117, No. 521, pp. F357-F385.
Bulow, J.; Summers, L. 1986. “A Theory of Dual Labour Markets with Application to Industrial
Policy, discrimination, and Keynesian Unemployment”, in Journal of Labour
Economics, Vol. 4, No. 1, pp. 376-414.
Caggese, A.; Cugnat, V. 2008. “Financing Constraints and Fixed-term Employment Contracts”,
in The Economic Journal, Vol. 118, No. 533, pp. 2013–2046.
Capelli, P.H.; Keller, J.R. 2013. “A Study of the Extent and Potential Causes of Alternative
Employment Arrangements”, in Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 66, No. 4,
pp. 874-901.
Cazes, S.; Khatiwada, S.; Malo, M. 2012. Employment Protection and Collective Bargaining:
Beyond the Deregulation Agenda, ILO Employment Working Paper No. 133 (Geneva,
ILO).
Cragg, J. G. 1971. “Some Statistical Models for Limited Dependent Variables with Application
to the Demand for Durable Goods. Econometrica, Vol. 39, pp. 829–844.
Devicienti, F.; Naticchioni, P.; Ricci, A. 2014. Temporary Employment, Demand Volatility and
Unions: Firm-level Evidence, CEPS-INSTEAD Working Paper No. 2014-14
(Luxembourg, CEPS/INSTEAD).
Doeringer, P.; Piore, M. 1971. “Internal labour markets and manpower analysis”, in Lexington,
Mass: Heat, 1971.
Gebel, M.; Giesecke, J. 2011. “Labor Market Flexibility and Inequality: The Changing Skill -
based Temporary Employment and Unemployment Risks in Europe”, in Social Forces,
Vol. 90, No. 1, pp. 17–40.
Hatton, E. 2014. “Temporary Weapons: Employers’ Use of Temps Against Organized Labour”,
in Industrial and Labour Relations Review, Vol. 67, Nr. 1, pp. 86-110.
Heery, E. 2004. “The Trade Union Response to Agency Labour in Britain”, in Industrial
Relations Journal, Vol. 35, No. 5, pp. 434-450.
Hipp, L.; Bernhardt J.; Allmendinger, J. 2015. “Instituions and the Prevalence of Nonstandard
Employment”, in Socio-Economic Review, advanced view, pp. 1-27.
Holmlund, B.; Storrie, D. 2002. “Temporary work in turbulent times: the Swedish experience”,
in Economic Journal, Vol. 112, No. 480, Features, pp. F245-F269.
Houseman, S. 2001) “Why employers use flexible staffing arrangements: Evidence from an
establishment survey,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, vol. 55, no. 1, pp. 149-
170.
Internatonal Labour Office (ILO). 2015. ILOSTAT Database. Available at: www.ilo.org/ilostat
[2 May 2015].
Internatonal Labour Office (ILO). 2015a. Report for a Tripartite Meeting of Experts on Non-
standard Forms of Employment (Geneva, ILO).
Internatonal Labour Office (ILO). 2015b. Final report: Tripartite Meeting of Experts on Non-
standard Forms of Employment (Geneva, ILO).
Internatonal Labour Office (ILO). 2015d. EPLex Online Database. Available at:
http://www.ilo.org/dyn/eplex/termmain.home [2. May 2015].
Kleinknecht, A. 2015. “How ‘structural reforms’ of labour markets harm innovation”, in Social
Europe, No. 6, pp. 1-7.
Kleinknecht, A., van Schaik, F.N.; Zhou, H. 2014. “Is flexible labour good for Innovation?”, in
Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 38, No. 5, pp. 1207-1219.
Ko, J.J.R. 2003. “Contingent and Internal Employment Systems: Substitutes or Complements?”,
in Journal of Labor Research, Vol. 24, No. 3, pp. 473-490.
Lee, B.-H.; Yoo, B.-S. 2008. “The Republic of Korea: From flexibility to segmentation”, in S.
Lee, F. Eyraud (ed.): Globalization, flexibilization and working conditions in Asia and
the Pacific (Oxford, Chandos Publishing and Geneva, ILO).
Mayer, K.J.; Nickerson, J.A. 2005. “Antecedents and performance implications of contracting
for knowledge workers: Evidence from information technology services”, in
Organization Science, Vol. 16, No. 3, pp. 225-242.
Nielen, S.; Schiersch, A. 2014. “Temporary agency work and firm competitiveness: Evidence
from German manufacturing firms”, in Industrial Relations, Vol. 53, No. 3, pp. 365-
375.
Nollen, S.; Axel, H. 1996. Managing Contingent Workers: How to reap the benefits and reduce
the risks, (New York, American Management Association).
Oi, W. 1962. “Labour as a quasi-fixed factor”, in The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. LXX,
No. 6, pp. 538-555.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2012. OECD Employment
Outlook (Paris, OECD).
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2014. OECD Employment
Outlook (Paris, OECD).
Pierre, G.; Scarpetta, S. 2006. “Employment Protection: Do Firm’s Perceptions Match with
Legislation?” in Economics Letters, Vol. 90, No. 2006, pp. 328-334.
Pierre, G.; Scarpetta, S. 2013. “Do Firms Make Greater Use of Training and Temporary
Employment When Labor Adjustment Costs are High?”, in IZA Journal of Labor
Policy, Vol. 2, No. 15, pp. 1-17.
Polavieja, J.G. 2006. “The Incidence of Temporary Employment in Advanced Economies: Why
is Spain Different?”, in European Sociological Review, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 61-78.
Portugal, P.; Varejao, J. 2009. Why Do Firms Use Fixed-Term Contracts? IZA Discussion
Papers 4380. (Bonn, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA)).
Prahalad, C.K.; Hamel, G. 1990. “The Core Competence of the Corporation”, in Harvard
Business Review, May-June, pp. 1-15.
Saint-Paul, G. 1996. Dual labour markets: A macroeconomic perspective (Cambridge, MA, MIT
Press).
Ton, Z. 2014. The Good Jobs Strategy: How the smartest companies invest in employees to
lower costs and boost profits (Seattle, WA, Lake Union Publishing).
Uzzi, B.; Barsness, Z.I. 1998. “Contingent employment in British establishments: Organizational
determinants of the use of fixed-term hires and part-time workers”, in Social Forces,
Vol. 76, No. 3, pp. 967-1005.
Vega-Ruíz, M.L. 2005. La reformal laboral en América Latina: quince años después: un
análisis comparado (Ginebra, OIT).
Verkerke, R.; Freyens, B. 2016. Mapping Employment Dismissal Law: A Lexime tric
Investigation of EPL Stringency and Regulatory Style. ILO Working Paper,
forthcoming (Geneva, ILO).
Visser, J. 2002. “Why Fewer Workers Join Unions in Europe: A Social Custom Explanation of
Membership Trends”, in British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 4, No. 3, pp. 403-
430.
Weil, D. 2014. The Fissured Workplace: Why work became so bad for so many and what can be
done to improve it (Cambridge, Harvard University Press).
World Bank, 2011. “World Bank’s Enterprise Survey. Understanding the Questio nnaire”.
Available at: www.enterprisesurveys.org [5 January 2015].
World Bank. 2015. World Bank Enterprise Survey, Online Database. Available at:
www.enterprisesurveys.org [January 2015].
World Bank. 2015. World Bank International Comparison Program Database. Available at:
http://go.worldbank.org/PQ5ZPPYSY0 [2 May 2015].
Note: Counted are the observations of the sample restricted for the baseline econometric analysis. Total sample is
71,943 observations. This is the sample we use for all descriptive statistics in this paper. In some specifications, the sample
size is reduced to 43,158 observations with non-missing data on all firm-level variables of interest; and to 21,377
observations with non-missing data on all firm-level and country-level variables of interest.
Source: World Bank Enterprise Survey, 2015. Online Database. Available at: www.enterprisesurveys.org . Accessed: January 2015.
Low-middle income ; Dichotomous variables equal to one if a country belongs to one of these groups, based on the World Bank classification; low-income countries
Upper-middle income; is the omitted benchmark category
High-income
GDPgrowth Contemporaneous GDP growth
GDPgrowth_3y_lag GDP growth with a 3-year lag
FTC prohib perm Dichotomous variable equal to one if fixed-term contracts use is legally prohibited for permanent tasks
FTC dur unlim Dichotomous variable equal to one if fixed-term contracts use has legally set maximum duration
Source: World Bank, 2015. World Bank International Comparison Program Database. Available at: http://go.worldbank.org/PQ5ZPPYSY0. Accessed: May 2015.
Source: ILO STAT, 2015. ILO Statistical Online Portal. Available at: www.ilo.org/ilostat Accessed: May 2015 .
Employment protection legislation summary indicator measuring the degree of protection afforded to workers when permanent contracts are
EPLex terminated at the initiative of the employer
A1_1 : Valid reasons for Component measuring the degree of protection embedded in the valid reasons for dismissals (ranging from 0, when there is no obligation to
dismissal have a reason for dismissal, to 1, when there is an obligation to have a reason for dismissal, and valid grounds are only worker’s conduct)
Component measuring the degree of protection embedded in prohibited grounds for dismissals (ranging from 0 national labour legislation
contains a list of prohibited grounds for dismissal / discrimination cases that only partly meets the ILO fundamental principles and rights at
work to 1 when national labour legislation contains a list of prohibited grounds for dismissal / discrimination cases that fully meets the ILO
A1_2: prohibited grounds fundamental principles and rights at work; and exceeds the principles established by specific international labour standards governing
for dismissal employment termination
EPLex sub-component measuring maximum probationary period, including all possible renewals, normalized to reflect 0 - no limitation; 1 -
A2 : Trial period less than 1 month
Average of two EPLex sub-components; first measuring procedural notification requirements for individual dismissals (ranging from 0 – when
employer need only orally notify a worker of a decision to terminate his employment; to 1 – when employer cannot proceed to dismissal
A3 : Notification without authorisation from a third party); and second measuring notice period at seven different tenures (normalized so that 0 = minimum,
requirements including zero; 1 = maximum).
Average of two EPLex sub-components; first measuring severance pay at 7 tenures, second measuring redundancy pay at seven tenures; each
A4 : Severance/ Redundancy normalized so that 0 = sample minimum; 1 = sample maximum.
EPLex sub-component reflecting the degree of protection embedded in the options legally offered to workers contesting their dismissal because
of the lack of valid grounds; ranging from 0, when no remedy is available as of right, to 1 when reinstatement is available in case of unfair
A5 : Redress for dismissals dismissal and is the primary remedy for unfair dismissal; legal text explicitly mentions award of back pay and/or other additional payments
Sources: ILO, 2015d. EPLex Online Database. Available at: http://www.ilo.org/dyn/eplex/termmain.home . Accessed: May 2015.
ILO, 2015c. Employment Protection Legislation Summary Indicators in the Area of Terminating Regular Contracts (Individual Dismissals). ILO: Geneva.
Appendix C. Descriptive Statistics
No. 2 Sexual harassment at work: A review of preventive measures (2005), by Deirdre McCann
No. 3 Statistics on working time arrangements based on time-use survey data (2003), by Andrew S.
Harvey, Jonathan Gershuny, Kimberly Fisher & Ather Akbari
No. 4 The definition, classification and measurement of working time arrangements (2003), by
David Bell & Peter Elias
No. 5 Reconciling work and family: Issues and policies in Japan (2003), by Masahiro Abe,
Chizuka Hamamoto & Shigeto Tanaka
No. 6 Reconciling work and family: Issues and policies in the Republic of Korea (2004), by Tae-
Hong Kim & Hye-Kyung Kim
No. 7 Domestic work, conditions of work and employment: A legal perspective (2003), by José
Maria Ramirez-Machado
No. 8 Reconciling work and family: Issues and policies in Brazil (2004), by Bila Sorj
No. 9 Employment conditions in an ageing world: Meeting the working time challenge (2004), by
Annie Jolivet & Sangheon Lee
No. 10 Designing programmes to improve working and employment conditions in the informal
economy: A literature review (2004), by Dr. Richard D. Rinehart
No. 11 Working time in transition: The dual task of standardization and flexibilization in China
(2005), by Xiangquan Zeng, Liang Lu & Sa’ad Umar Idris
No. 13 Étude sur les temps de travail et l’organisation du travail: Le cas du Sénégal. Analyse
juridique et enquête auprès des entreprises (2006), by Alfred Inis Ndiaye
No. 14 Reconciling work and family: Issues and policies in Thailand (2006), by Kyoko Kusakabe
No. 15 Conditions of work and employment for older workers in industrialized countries:
Understanding the issues (2006), by N.S. Ghosheh Jr., Sangheon Lee & Deirdre McCann
No. 16 Wage fixing in the informal economy: Evidence from Brazil, India, Indonesia and South
Africa (2006) by Catherine Saget
No. 18 Reconciling work and family: Issues and policies in Trinidad and Tobago (2008), by Rhoda
Reddock & Yvonne Bobb-Smith
No. 19 Minding the gaps: Non-regular employment and labour market segmentation in the Republic
of Korea (2007) by Byung-Hee Lee & Sangheon Lee
No. 20 Age discrimination and older workers: Theory and legislation in comparative context (2008),
by Naj Ghosheh
No. 22 Reconciling work and family: Issues and policies in China (2009), by Liu Bohong, Zhang
Yongying & Li Yani
No. 23 Domestic work and domestic workers in Ghana: An overview of the legal regime and
practice (2009), by Dzodzi Tsikata
No. 24 A comparison of public and private sector earnings in Jordan (2010), by Christopher
Dougherty
No. 25 The German work-sharing scheme: An instrument for the crisis (2010), by Andreas
Crimmann, Frank Weissner & Lutz Bellmann
No. 26 Extending the coverage of minimum wages in India: Simulations from household data
(2010), by Patrick Belser & Uma Rani
No. 27 The legal regulation of working time in domestic work (2010), by Deirdre Mc Cann & Jill
Murray
No. 28 What do we know about low-wage work and low-wage workers (2011), by Damian
Grimshaw
No. 30 Measuring the economic and social value of domestic work: conceptual and methodological
framework (2011), by Debbie Budlender
No. 31 Working Time, Health, and Safety: a Research Synthesis Paper (2012), by Philip Tucker &
Simon Folkard
No. 32 The influence of working time arrangements on work-life integration or ‘balance’: A review
of the international evidence (2012), by Colette Fagan, Clare Lyonette, Mark Smith & Abril
Saldaña-Tejeda
No. 33 The Effects of Working Time on Productivity and Firm Performance: a research synthesis
paper (2012), by Lonnie Golden
No. 35 Why have wage shares fallen? A panel analysis of the determinants of functional income
distribution (2012), by Engelbert Stockhammer
No. 36 Wage-led or Profit-led Supply: Wages, Productivity and Investment (2012), by Servaas
Storm & C.W.M. Naastepad
No. 37 Financialisation and the requirements and potentials for wage-led recovery – a review
focussing on the G20 (2012), by Eckhard Hein & Matthias Mundt
No. 39 Income inequality as a cause of the Great Recession? A survey of current debates (2012), by
Simon Sturn & Till van Treeck
No. 40 Is aggregate demand wage-led or profit-led? National and global effects (2012), by Özlem
Onaran & Giorgos Galanis
No. 42 The visible face of Women’s invisible labour: domestic workers in Turkey (2013), by
Seyhan Erdoğdu & Gülay Toksöz
No. 43 In search of good quality part-time employment (2013), by Colette Fagan, Helen Norman,
Mark Smith & María C. González Menéndez
No. 44 The use of working time-related crisis response measures during the Great Recession (2013),
by Angelika Kümmerling & Steffen Lehndorff
No. 45 Analysis of employment, real wage, and productivity trends in South Africa since 1994
(2014), by Martin Wittenberg
No. 46 Poverty, inequality and employment in Chile (2014), by Sarah Gammage, Tomás
Alburquerque & Gonzálo Durán
No. 47 Deregulating labour markets: How robust is the analysis of recent IMF working papers?
(2014), by Mariya Aleksynska
No. 48 Growth with equity in Singapore: Challenges and prospects (2014), by Hui Weng Tat &
Ruby Toh
No. 49 Informality and employment quality in Argentina, Country case study on labour market
segmentation (2014), by Fabio Bertranou, Luis Casanova, Maribel Jiménez & Mónica
Jiménez
No. 50 Comparing indicators of labour market regulations across databases: A post scriptum to the
employing workers debate (2014), by Mariya Aleksynska & Sandrine Cazes
No. 51 The largest drop in income inequality in the European Union during the Great Recession:
Romania’s puzzling case (2014), by Ciprian Domnisoru
No. 52 Segmentation and informality in Vietnam: A survey of literature, Country case study on
labour market segmentation (2014), by Jean-Pierre Cling, Mireille Razafindrakoto &
François Roubaud
No. 54 How tight is the link between wages and productivity? A survey of the literature (2014), by
Johannes Van Biesebroeck
No. 55 Job quality in segmented labour markets: The Israeli case, Country case study on labour
market segmentation (2014), by Shoshana Neuman
No. 56 The organization of working time and its effects in the health services sector: A comparative
analysis of Brazil, South Africa, and the Republic of Korea (2014), by Jon Messenger &
Patricia Vidal
No. 57 The motherhood pay gap: A review of the issues, theory and international evidence (2015),
by Damian Grimshaw & Jill Rubery
No. 61 Non-standard work and workers: Organizational implications (2015), by Elizabeth George
& Prithviraj Chattopadhyay
No. 62 What does the minimum wage do in developing countries? A review of studies and
methodologies (2015), by Dale Belman & Paul Wolfson
No. 63 The regulation of non-standard forms of employment in India, Indonesia and Viet Nam
(2015), by Ingrid Landau, Petra Mahy & Richard Mitchell
No. 64 The regulation of non-standard forms of employment in China, Japan and the Republic of
Korea (2015), by Fang Lee Cooke & Ronald Brown
No. 66 Minimum wage setting practices in domestic work: An inter-state analysis (2015), by
Neetha N.
No. 67 The effects of non-standard forms of employment on worker health and safety (2015), by
Michael Quinlan
No. 68 Structural change and non-standard forms of employment in India (2015), by Ravi
Srivastava
No. 69 Non-standard forms of employment in some Asian countries: A study of wages and working
conditions of temporary workers (2016), by Huu-Chi Nguyen, Thanh Tam Nguyen-Huu &
Thi-Thuy-Linh Le
No. 70 Non-standard forms of employment in Uganda and Ghana (2016), by Christelle Dumas &
Cédric Houdré
No. 71 The rise of the “just-in-time workforce”: On-demand work, crowdwork and labour
protection in the “gig-economy” (2016), by Valerio De Stefano
No. 72 The introduction of a minimum wage for domestic workers in South Africa (2016), by
Debbie Budlender
No. 74 Income security in the on-demand economy: Findings and policy lessons from a survey of
crowdworkers (2016), by Janine Berg
www.ilo.org/inwork
ISSN 2226-8944