Ports and Port Services 1 1
Ports and Port Services 1 1
Ports and Port Services 1 1
When considering the degree of substitutability The ability of different ports to serve customers
between different modes of transport, it is also useful in a given hinterland needs to be assessed on a
to examine the value density of goods transported by case-by-case basis. In principle, however, a distinction
the different modes. Value density is a measure of the can be made between captive and contestable
average financial value per unit of volume or weight for hinterlands. All regions where one port has a
a commodity. Data published by the European substantial competitive advantage because of lower
Commission for 2008 shows that the value density transport costs to them (for example, owing to short
differs greatly between different modes of transport distances to the port’s customers’ final destinations)
(see Table 1 below)—for example, the average value belong to the captive hinterland. Such a port is likely
per tonne transported by sea was only a quarter of that to handle the majority of all cargoes to and from these
transported by road. Air transport had by far the highest regions. Competition between ports is more likely to
value density. occur in those regions where no single port has a
significant cost advantage over other ports.
Furthermore, UK data published by the Department for
Transport again suggests that certain types of good are An example of an area in a contestable hinterland
predestined to be transported by certain modes of is Austria, a country without a coastline, but with
transport. For example, the most common goods significant international import and export activities.
transported by inland water are oil and petroleum. In Data published in the Österreichische Seehafenbilanz
the case of rail, the most common good is coal, and for (produced by a weekly publication about transport
road it is foodstuffs, beverages and tobacco.8 logistics and business) shows that a total of eight
seaports currently service shippers moving goods
Observing differences in value densities and types of to and from Austria (Antwerp, Bremen, Constanta,
good transported by different modes of transport (ie,
Table 1 Value density of goods transported in 2008 (EU imports and exports)
Mode of transport € per tonne
Air 43,308
Road 3,289
Sea 865
Rail 470
Hamburg, Koper, Rijeka, Rotterdam, Trieste). The Le Havre and Gothenburg and includes the UK and
largest of these are Hamburg, Bremen, Antwerp and Ireland. In a recent Decision, the Commission was
Rotterdam to the north of the country, and Koper and inclined to consider that the northern European market
Trieste to the south.9 should be further segmented because it was observed
that, for various reasons, not all ports in northern
The port of Hamburg handles around a fifth of Austrian Europe are substitutable. Such reasons were draft
import and export volumes moved through ports; restrictions (the minimum depth of water that a ship or
around a quarter are moved through the port of Koper. boat can safely navigate); distance from main shipping
To determine whether ports that are as far apart as routes; distance from ‘transshipment markets’ (such as
Hamburg and Koper (1,300km by road, and much Scandinavia/the Baltic countries, Spain/Portugal and
further by sea) constrain each other to such an extent UK/Ireland); and capacity limitations that restrict
that neither has market power would require further switching.
analysis. In principle, however, the greater the overlap
between ports’ hinterlands, the greater the probability
that these ports constrain each other. See the box
Countervailing buyer power
below for a discussion of catchment areas. Independently of the outcome of the analysis of
existing competition between modes of transport and
different ports, a port’s ability to exercise any market
Competition between ports— power will depend on customers’ countervailing buyer
ability to compete for power. In such a situation, the buyer power of
transshipment traffic downstream operators—such as shipping companies
and brokers—prevents an upstream business from
In addition to hinterland traffic, ports may compete for acting to an appreciable extent independently of its
transshipment traffic where larger vessels use a port to customers.
transfer cargo to smaller feeder vessels. These feeder
vessels then transport the cargo on to ports that serve Countervailing buyer power might exist where buyers
the required hinterland. are large relative to their supplier(s), and where buyers
have the ability to switch between suppliers. In terms of
The distinction between hinterland and transshipment port users’ size, data published by the United Nations
traffic means that two ports that do not serve the same looking at the concentration of the global container
hinterland may still constrain one another if they shipping market indicates that several players hold a
compete for the same transshipment traffic. For significant global share of supply. At a global level, the
example, the port of Grimsby and Immingham, the UK’s largest four shipping lines (Maersk, MSC, CMA CGM
largest port, is unlikely to serve the same hinterland as Group, and Evergreen Line) accounted for 32% of all
the port of Rotterdam in the Netherlands. Nevertheless, containers transported by water in 2010.10 At a regional
the two ports might still constrain each other if they or port-specific level, concentration will tend to be at
compete for the same transshipment traffic between least as high. There is also evidence that concentration
Europe and other continents (given that both are has increased over time. This level of downstream
deep-water ports). concentration among port users could lead to
countervailing buyer power, particularly at ports with
The European Commission found that the geographic only a few main users. However, it is not sufficient to
market for stevedoring services for transshipment be large to have such power. Buyers must also be able
traffic was wider than that for hinterland traffic. The to credibly threaten to switch away a significant
Commission distinguished between the Mediterranean proportion of demand in the event of a price rise (which
market and the northern European market, which will depend on their outside options).
spreads across the geographic range between
Catchment areas
The European Commission found that the geographic open the question as to whether northern Europe should
area within which ports compete for hinterland traffic is be further divided, the widest geographic range being
determined by the ‘catchment area’ of the ports—ie, the Hamburg–Le Havre and the narrowest Hamburg–
inland geographic range to which containers can be Antwerp. Although the question was left open, in a
economically distributed. The Commission has identified recent decision the Commission was inclined to consider
three such geographic blocks in Europe: the UK and the narrower geographic range as more appropriate.2
Ireland; Northern Europe; and the Mediterranean.1 It left
Note: 1 The Commission has acknowledged, however, that the catchment area of some northern European and Mediterranean
ports might overlap with respect to the landlocked countries of west and central Europe, such as Switzerland and Austria. 2 The
Commission considered that there was limited competition between the German and French ports because of limited overlap in
their catchment areas and the higher handling fees at the German ports. See European Commission (2008), ‘Case No COMP/
M.5066 EUROGATE / APMM’, Commission decision of 5 June 2008.
In this regard, the Commission was doubtful that The Bundeskartellamt addressed the essential facility
shipping companies had countervailing buyer power question in the context of ferry services provided in the
over ports or port service providers. It found that Baltic Sea between the ports of Puttgarden in northern
shipping companies have difficulties in switching Germany and Rǿdby in southern Denmark. The ferry
between ports because of the complexity of reworking route Rǿdby–Puttgarden essentially links Denmark
schedules, timetables, loops and changes in terminal (and Sweden) with Germany and the rest of western/
cut-offs, which a switch would require. Another central Europe. There is no viable alternative to the
important switching constraint is the fact that, following ports of Rǿdby and Puttgarden since, due to their
a switch, a port’s customers—the shippers—will have location, duration of crossing, and connection to further
to adapt their logistical arrangements for transporting means of traffic, they are able to offer services that no
the cargo from the port to their final inland destination. other port can.
1
Conseil de la Concurrence (2008), ‘Décision n° 08-D-19 du 31 juillet 2008 relative à une demande de mesures conservatoires de la
société AP Moller-Maersk’, July 31st.
2
Bundeskartellamt (2004), ‘Beschluss B9-101/04’.
3
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Directorate for Financial and Enterprise Affairs Competition Committee (2011),
‘Competition Concerns in Ports and Port Services’, Working Party No. 2 on Competition and Regulation, DAF/COMP/WP2/WD(2011), June
27th.
4
Court of Justice of the European Communities (1979), Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v Commission of the European Communities,
Case 85/76.
5
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) (2010), ‘Review of Maritime Transport 2010’, Table 1.3.
6
World Shipping Council Trade Statistics (2007), ‘Top 20 Exporters of Liner Goods by Value, 2007’.
7
UNCTAD (2010), op. cit., Table 1.3.
8
Department for Transport (2008), ‘Delivering a Sustainable Transport System: The Logistics Perspective’.
9
Verkehr (2010), ‘Österreichische Seehafenbilanz’.
10
UNCTAD (2010), ‘Review of Maritime Transport 2010’.
11
These conditions were first set out in the Magill case. Radio Telefis Eireann and Independent Television Publications Ltd v European
Commission, joined cases C-241/91 P and C-242/91 P, European Court of Justice.
12
Bundeskartellamt (2011), ‘B9-188/05 “Scandlines”’, pp. 45 and 50.
If you have any questions regarding the issues raised in this article, please contact the editor,
Dr Gunnar Niels: tel +44 (0) 1865 253 000 or email g_niels@oxera.com
Other articles in the September issue of Agenda include:
For details of how to subscribe to Agenda, please email agenda@oxera.com, or visit our website
www.oxera.com
© Oxera, 2011. All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purposes of criticism or review, no part may
be used or reproduced without permission.