Kahler M 1998 Rationality in IR
Kahler M 1998 Rationality in IR
Kahler M 1998 Rationality in IR
http://journals.cambridge.org/INO
Miles Kahler
The role of reason in international relations has been contested since the eighteenth
century. The construction of a sphere of calculated state action, raison d'etat, and an
image of the balance of power suggested an Enlightenment equilibrium as compre-
hensible to human reason as a clockwork. Even at the time, however, the obsessive
and often self-defeating war-making of Louis XIV and Frederick the Great illustrated
the irrationality of collective outcomes and the failure of self-imposed limits in a
world grounded in raison d'etat.1 During the nineteenth century, advancing industrial
capitalism promised to overcome passions in the interest of human progress, and
modern political economy reinforced the belief that individual calculations of inter-
est could lead to beneficial social outcomes. International politics, however, was only
partially captured by the force of reason.
The questioning of reason deepened in the twentieth century as modern psychol-
ogy undermined the image of a unified and rational self. Democratic politics meant
that the phantom of an elitist and state-centered rationality would remain elusive.
Disastrous international outcomes—the failure of cooperation in the 1930s, the monu-
mental carnage of two world wars—produced pessimism regarding the power of
human reason to comprehend the realm of international competition and to contain
the passions of ideology and nationalism.
As the study of international relations took shape in the United States after World
War I, however, these shocks to reason in all of its guises—a model of individual
psychology, an avenue for comprehending international reality, and an instrument of
The author wishes to thank Alexander Thompson and the other participants in the University of Chicago
PIPES seminar, Arthur Stein, John McMillan, and the special editors of this issue for their comments on
earlier drafts.
1. Kissinger 1994, 66.
progress—were felt only faintly. A perspective that was broadly liberal and material-
ist assumed a central place. Incorrectly labeled idealist, human reason in this view
continued to offer the possibility of collective mastery over the forces that had pre-
cipitated world war.2
At the same time, international relations was denned in social scientific terms, as
subject to the same regularities as other spheres of social life. By the 1930s, pioneers
in the new field had begun to adopt the model of natural science for their research;
like the liberal materialists, Charles Merriam, Harold Lasswell, and Quincy Wright
assumed that human reason could illuminate international relations in the same way
that it had comprehended the economy and political behavior. They embedded the
study of world politics in a broader political analysis that stretched from individuals
to national governments to the interaction among those governments.
Two events shook the rationalist faith of this liberal and nascent social scientific
enterprise. The cataclysm of World War II produced progressive hopes for a world in
which rational planning and institutional design would play a larger role. Those
hopes were not entirely disappointed in the postwar management of international
economic relations, but the onset of the Cold War undermined lingering hopes that
collective reason could overcome the force of ideology. Political persecution and war
also produced an emigration of European scholars whose realist tenets were far more
pessimistic regarding the abilities of reason to comprehend and to curb the violent
tendencies of world politics. Those beliefs were in sharp conflict with the prevailing
consensus in American international relations.
The roots of realism lay in currents of European thought that had undermined the
reign of reason. Realism injected an awareness drawn from European social theory
and philosophy that the image of a unified and rational self had been overturned.
Although these strands, particularly Freudian psychoanalysis, were not foreign to
postwar American social science, the attack launched by realism against what it
regarded as naive liberalism and a misconceived positivist scientific enterprise was
deeper. At the time of its entry into American intellectual life, the relationship be-
tween realism and rationalism in politics was more confrontational than complemen-
tary.
In Scientific Man Versus Power Politics, published immediately after World War
II, Hans Morgenthau drew intellectual ammunition from the European cataclysm for
a realist attack on prevailing liberal ideology. He assailed the current intellectual
consensus as "a repudiation of politics," offering a false hope of meliorating a social
world driven by irrationality. Morgenthau declared that "our civilization assumes
that the social world is susceptible to rational control conceived after the model of
the natural sciences, while the experiences, domestic and international, of the age
contradict this assumption."3 He was not alone among realists in questioning the
dominant liberal embrace of reason. In early formulations of the security dilemma, a
core concept of realism, John Herz also pointed to an underlying irrationality in the
2. This account of interwar international relations in the United States is drawn from Kahler 1997.
3. Morgenthau 1946, 71, 2.
Rationality in International Relations 921
4. Herzl951,16.
5. Stephanson 1989, 180-81.
6. Ross 1991,473.
922 International Organization
here, from rational choice to social constructivist, pragmatically deploy their theories
in order to understand the substance of international relations. Whether the field has
reached agreement on the meaning of "understanding" is an issue too large to con-
sider here; my own belief is that broad canons of evidence and argument in the social
sciences are widely shared.7
On the narrower ground of whether rationality and rationalist models provide a
basis for constructing (or reconstructing) the field of international relations, an al-
leged affinity between rational choice models and traditional state-centric views of
international politics as well as a long-standing embrace of game theory has until
recently insulated international relations from an increasingly acrimonious conflict
between proponents of rational choice and their critics in other social sciences.8
Nevertheless, the current tendency to set up rational choice models as imperialistic
targets risks yet another fruitless and time-consuming "great debate" in international
relations. Previous great debates, whether maxi- (realism versus idealism) or mini-
(neorealism versus neoliberalism), have seldom advanced a coherent research pro-
gram for the field.9
Another intellectual tournament of this kind might be preempted by demonstrating
the value of a competitive exchange between those endorsing rationalist models and
their critics, rather than an all-or-nothing contest producing victory or defeat for one
side. Rationalist treatments have already been challenged to extend their scope and
refine their modeling; those who are skeptical of such accounts (from a number of
perspectives) have been pressed to reinforce the rigor of their arguments and to
define domains in which rational choice and the proposed alternatives carry the most
explanatory weight. Given the waves of "bashing" that too often occur on either
side, it would be premature to argue for convergence between rational choice and its
principal competitors. One feasible outcome, however, can already be discerned in
particular fields of research: a willingness by either side to emphasize problem-
focused research, permitting explanatory power rather than theoretical polemic to
decide the contest.
Two additional and equally important observations serve to obscure the lines in the
sand that are often drawn on either side. Rational and nonrational accounts share
methodological shortcomings. One problem, considered at greater length later, is a
too-easy aggregation from individual to collectivity. Confronting such shared meth-
odological problems could also contribute to intellectual exchange between rational
and nonrational modes of explanation.
Careful scrutiny of the criticisms leveled by either side also demonstrates that
differences between rational and nonrational often revolve around questions of defi-
nition. In accepting the narrower terms of controversy, reason and rationality are
defined here in broadly instrumental terms. Still, the variety of rationalist accounts is
a target for critics, who see in diversity a slippery unwillingness to confront empirical
7. For a different view of the importance of epistemological concerns, see Smith, Booth, and Zalewski,
1996; and Ruggie, this issue.
8. See Green and Shapiro 1994; and Friedman 1996.
9. Kahlerl997.
Rationality in International Relations 923
shortcomings. For those employing rational choice frames, on the other hand, such
variety undermines the allegations of some critics that they represent a monolithic
intellectual tribe. Criticisms revolve around the distinction between what John Fere-
john terms "thin" and "thick" rational accounts. To the former's assumption of
simple instrumental rationality, the latter adds auxiliary assumptions regarding agent
preferences and beliefs.10 Many of these auxiliary assumptions—such as those con-
cerning the possibility of other-regarding goals—lie at the core of many criticisms of
rational choice.
Another important definitional misunderstanding that exaggerates the lines of dis-
agreement is the common conflation of methodological individualism and rational
choice, a reasonable linkage given the roots of both in economics. As the comparison
of rationalist and constructivist accounts will suggest, individualist approaches need
not imply rationality, and rationalist accounts can and do incorporate social content.11
Since the "thickness" and individualism of rationalist models is often at the center
of disputes over their usefulness, Elster's definition of rational choice can serve as a
useful benchmark. As an explanation of behavior,
rational choice theory appeals to three distinct elements in the choice situation.
The first element is the feasible set, i.e., the set of all courses of action which (are
rationally believed to) satisfy various logical, physical, and economic constraints.
The second is (a set of rational beliefs about) the causal structure of the situation,
which determines what course of action will lead to what outcomes. The third is
a subjective ranking of the feasible alternatives, usually derived from a ranking
of the outcomes to which they (are expected to) lead. To act rationally, then, sim-
ply means to choose the highest-ranked element in the feasible set.12
Whether such a relatively "thin" definition remains empty or inaccurate, as some
critics allege, or provides the basis for a far-reaching explanation of foreign policy
and international outcomes has been central in controversies over the power of ratio-
nalist models in international relations.
Defining a benchmark for the nonrational side of this contemporary intellectual
contest is even more contentious than establishing the meaning of rationality. The
diverse critics of rational choice models in international relations either propose alter-
native nonrational explanations for behavior on the part of agents in international
relations or call into question the scope and accuracy of a rationalist account for the
behavior in question. Whether these alternatives modify, complement, or supplant
rationalist accounts is another question of central importance.
Rationalist models have confronted four persistent sources of criticism as the re-
search programs of international relations evolved after 1945. Realism has often
been paired with the assumption of a rational and unitary state actor, but its relation-
ship with rationalist theorizing has been uneasy, in both its classical, power-
maximizing form and its neorealist and structural variants. Psychological assaults on
rational choice can be traced to Freud; contemporary criticisms share the individual-
ist premises of rational choice models but dispute its claims regarding the information-
processing powers of agents. Both rationalist and psychological models share a third
hurdle in explaining international outcomes: constructing a plausible model of action
for entities beyond the individual level, whether bureaucratic organizations, interest
groups, or states. Finally, the rationality and the individualism of beliefs is ques-
tioned by theories that stress culture, identity, and norms as independent sources of
action.
An elective affinity between international relations and rationalist models has often
been based on the assumptions of realism, which has claimed a dominant place in the
American study of international relations since 1945. The relationship of classical
realism to rational models of state behavior is more tenuous than latter-day realists
care to admit, however. The domestication of realism by the American study of
international relations obscured the earlier history of realism and rendered it less
subversive of rational choice models. In Politics Among Nations, Morgenthau him-
self adopted rational reconstruction from the viewpoint of actors as a means of com-
prehending foreign policy. This marriage of realist tenets and rationalist models took
place most clearly in the evolution of deterrence theory, but taming realism and
rendering it scientific has also been the program of structural realism (or neorealism).
Kenneth Waltz's neorealism represented the final domestication of realism by
American social science.13 Waltz self-consciously aimed to produce a social scien-
tific version of realism far removed from the anti-scientific model of power politics
endorsed by the younger Morgenthau. Whether Waltz's neorealism also represented
a final incorporation of realism within a rational choice paradigm is far more uncer-
tain. Although Robert O. Keohane attributed a rationality assumption to both classi-
cal realism and Waltz's structural variant, the microfoundations of both are unclear.14
Morgenthau's critical stance toward rationalism has already been described. Norma-
tive prescriptions of calculation and prudence suggested that realism understood ra-
tional behavior as far from universal in international politics.
Waltz drew analogies between his enterprise and microeconomics, but his empha-
sis on structure seems to place neorealism in a different methodological camp. Elster
notes that pure structuralist accounts deny the importance of rational choice in favor
of structural constraints. A modified version of structuralism—which may approach
Waltz's position—assumes uniformity in preferences and motivations and attributes
differences in behavior to differences in the opportunity set, which could be defined
by tighter or looser structural constraints.15 This second variant can be accommo-
dated within a rational choice framework, but whether structural realism relies on
choice under structural constraints or two other adaptive mechanisms—selection along
Darwinian lines and socialization—is uncertain. Waltz's own position seems to vary
on this question. In Theory of International Politics, Waltz argues that structure af-
fects behavior through socialization and competition.16 In his treatment of both clas-
sical and structural realism, Keohane argues that the rationality assumption is one of
three key assumptions that define the "hard core" of a realist research program; he
includes Waltz within the rationalist camp as well.17 In his response to Keohane,
Waltz argues that selection carries most of the explanatory weight in structural real-
ism, awarding it a position of "central importance"; he stipulates that political lead-
ers cannot make "the nicely calculated decisions that the word 'rationality' sug-
gests."18 The realm of reason within neorealism remains ambiguous. Under tight
structural constraints of international competition and selection, the rationality of
agents seems superfluous. Waltz fails to demonstrate that structures have such consis-
tent and predictable effects, however.
Versailles, George and George demonstrate that Wilson's behavior was critical to an
important historical outcome. In demonstrating that his behavior in a complicated
strategic setting was the result of nonrational influences of which he was unaware,
however, two significant assertions must be confirmed: a counterfactual proposition
that a more "reasonable" course would have resulted in a different outcome and the
more difficult contention that his behavior was nonrational, if not when measured by
short-term political ends, then by longer-term goals that he had set. These are diffi-
cult tests for those who argue that nonrational influences on behavior are strong.
Responding to such claims, Sidney Verba framed a telling response in defense of
rational decision-making models.20 Verba pointed to two important shortcomings in
many psychological accounts that were critical of rationalist models. He noted unre-
solved issues of data: whether findings from experimental and clinical settings could
be transferred to the far different environment of foreign policy and domestic poli-
tics. He also pointed to the problem of aggregation for any individualist model of
choice: both rational and psychological models slipped too easily from individual
attributions to those of organizations and bureaucracies.
Verba also clarified the methodological tests that should be applied to nonrational
psychological explanations. He advanced a cost-benefit criterion for the inclusion of
psychological variables: add psychological complexity only when it yielded greater
explanatory power. Even more important, psychological explanations needed to move
from important generalizations that were too broad in scope to contingent statements
that would clarify when "nonlogical" influences on decision making would be sig-
nificant. Finally, Verba pointed out that many psychological explanations or critiques
incorporated, implicitly or explicitly, a rational benchmark. This benchmark was
essential, whatever its limitations in particular cases, in order to permit "systematic
consideration of deviations from rationality."21 Each of the issues raised by Verba
more than three decades ago remains significant in evaluating the psychological re-
search agenda.
Cognitive psychology rapidly overtook psychoanalytic theory as the principal chal-
lenger to rational models of behavior. The proliferation of studies of foreign policy
influenced by cognitive psychology also blurred the alternative research program.
Philip Tetlock and Charles McGuire, Jr. discerned two key assumptions in this di-
verse literature: international politics imposes heavy information-processing de-
mands on policymakers; in the face of those demands, policymakers—"limited ca-
pacity information processors"—employ "simplifying strategies" to comprehend
their environment.22 Those strategies may violate definitions of rational behavior and
call into question the use of rational choice as a norm for individual decision making.
One widespread bias discovered by psychologists in foreign policy decisions is the
reliance on cognitive structures (given a variety of labels—cognitive maps, opera-
tional codes, or schemas) deeply influenced by past experience and often resistant to
more recent data that might modify or overturn those structures. Yuen Foong Khong,
for example, has carefully charted the persistent use of historical analogies as sche-
mas for organizing incoming data, comparing a psychological interpretation of this
widespread behavior to alternative explanations.23
The discovery of "theory-driven" behavior, the term that Tetlock and McGuire
use to describe this mimicking by policymakers of scientific practice, poses difficult
judgments for those evaluating its positive and normative effects on policy out-
comes. Since reliance on preexisting beliefs is both widespread and necessary for the
processing of new information, this research program must assess when such reli-
ance becomes irrational and distorts policy outcomes. As Tetlock and McGuire,
Khong, and others who argue for damaging cognitive rigidity are forced to admit,
"reliance on prior beliefs and expectations is not irrational per se (one would expect
it from a 'good Bayesian'); it becomes irrational only when perseverance and denial
dominate openness and flexibility."24 Assessing that point in other than a tautological
way (by referring to a positive or negative outcome as evidence) is very difficult. In
effect, the rationality of reliance on existing schemas or cognitive maps for interpret-
ing the world is dependent on the desirability of updating beliefs more or less fre-
quently in the face of discrepant information. No uniform answer to that dilemma is
given in the psychological literature. Khong suggests a procedural strategy—forcing
existing analogies to a rigorous and public "scientific" test of their validity. That
kind of serious testing also imposes costs, however, and once again a sensitive com-
parison of the benefits (in terms of decision-making quality) would also be required.
In cases where particular schemas seem to produce outcomes whose costs are uni-
formly high, avoiding the use of certain kinds of schemas or analogies might be a
more efficient rule of thumb.
Other psychological alternatives to rationalist models of explanation emphasize
the process by which decisions are made, particularly the use of information-
processing shortcuts and heuristics; these alternatives are often portrayed as challeng-
ing rational choice models more directly. Prospect theory has evoked the most inter-
est among students of foreign policymaking. Based on robust experimental evidence,
prospect theory points to deviations from expected utility theory, the conventional
means of explaining choice under conditions of risk. In barest outline, individuals
systematically and frequently evaluate outcomes with respect to a reference point
rather than using net losses or gains; individuals are risk-averse with respect to gains
from that reference point and risk-acceptant with regard to losses; and preference
ordering varies according to the framing of prospects (a clear violation of the crite-
rion of invariance in rational choice).25 Despite the difficulties in measuring these
effects outside an experimental or laboratory setting, researchers using cases drawn
from international politics have already begun to examine the explanatory power of
prospect theory weighed against predictions based on expected utility.26 To the de-
gree that convincing tests can be made using the data available, results appear mixed:
expected utility theory is hardly without value in explaining many of the outcomes.
The rich psychological literature in international relations has produced many case
studies demonstrating widespread cognitive and information processing distortions
that deviate from the predictions of rational choice and expected utility theories.
Psychological approaches often supplement rational choice explanations, however,
rather than providing an alternative to them. In other cases, such as prospect theory,
expected utility theorists are hard at work incorporating anomalous findings into
broader and more inclusive theories of decision making.27 Theory-building strategies
among psychological critics of rationalist models confront the same issue of "thin-
ness" as those using rational choice. Critics of rational choice voice dissatisfaction
with the emptiness of those models in the absence of a theory of preferences. Psycho-
logical process models, such as prospect theory, remain equally empty without a
theory of reference points or framing.
Psychological studies of foreign policymaking have produced important evidence
that qualifies rational choice models, but they do not represent a single psychological
alternative to rational choice. Mirroring the claims of rational choice theorists, psy-
chological critics have argued wide scope for their findings. They have generally
avoided a presentation of contingent theories or hypotheses that would stipulate the
conditions under which psychological distortions of rational decision making are
most likely. Even the most prolific and perceptive scholars who have mined histori-
cal and contemporary data find it difficult to claim more than the presence of system-
atic and widespread biases toward misperception across a wide range of cases.28 The
judgment of Tetlock and McGuire of a decade ago still stands: psychological ap-
proaches must work, not toward a single "cognitive portrait," but rather toward
producing a "contingency theory of information processing," specifying more clearly
the conditions under which particular cognitive strategies, rational and nonrational,
are pursued.29
Unfortunately, the obstacles to that course are formidable. Critics of the psycho-
logical perspective on choice have long alleged that the transfer of experimental
laboratory data, no matter how robust, to real-world choice situations is a flawed
strategy: even the most ingenious experiments cannot capture the subjective percep-
tions of risk that are present in markets or international bargaining.30 Even if one
allows the validity of testing for such effects in historical or contemporary settings,
the collection and evaluation of data that is aimed at reconstructing very refined,
subjective estimates of risk and utility is difficult to accomplish. Alternative and
equally convincing explanations based on different utility calculations (for example,
those including domestic political goals) can often be constructed.
Given these difficulties, Verba's cost-benefit criterion of research efficiency must
be taken seriously. Weighing the potential explanatory contribution of psychological
Deterrence theory represents one of the most sophisticated and highly elaborated
uses of rational actor modeling in international relations. It has also been an intellec-
tual testing ground for both rational actor (subjective expected utility) models and
those deploying psychological models. Much of the debate has centered on method-
ological issues, particularly the use of deductive models rather than case studies.
Participants on either side, however, have admitted that the contenders share an in-
ability to offer convincing models that aggregate individual choices and behavior.
Jervis has pointed out that units composed of many individuals appear more irratio-
nal than individual decision makers for several reasons: governments or coalitions
that pursue contradictory goals, organizational or institutional incapacity in strategy
choice, alternation of different groups (with different preference orderings) in power,
and the possibility of cycling.34 George Downs, who has urged a positive symbiosis
between rationalist and psychological approaches to decision making in order to
produce a "strong" model of deterrence, also remarks on a less positive attribute on
the part of both rational deterrence theorists and psychological modelers to transfer
their assumptions about individual choice to states and organizations.35
Elster notes that treating the polity "as a unitary actor, with coherent and stable
values, well-grounded beliefs, and a capacity to carry out its decisions" is most
widespread in international relations and in the theory of economic planning.36 Given
its unhappy consequences in economic planning, it is surprising that this assumption,
which he labels potentially "treacherous and misleading," has been so easily ac-
cepted as an adequate microfoundation for much of international relations. Realist
assumptions of state rationality depended on an implicit selection argument, as de-
scribed in the case of Waltz: states that were unable to behave in at least a crudely
rational manner would be selected out through intense international competition.
Although a model of international selection may give some purchase on the differen-
tial survival of units, the link between rational action and survival has not been made.
In fact, much of the psychological literature suggests precisely the opposite: that
distortions in decision making and deviations from a rational model occur frequently
in international politics, with mixed survival consequences for the units in question.
Building on early decision-making models, Graham Allison's Essence of Decision
was one of the first efforts to challenge unitary and rational actor assumptions on the
basis of political process.37 Allison described a rational actor model of governmental
decision making (model I) and then proposed two alternatives that heavily qualified
the model. In choosing the Cuban Missile Crisis, the most threatening case of super-
power crisis bargaining during the Cold War, Allison deliberately selected a case in
which the international environment should have reinforced pressures toward unitary
and rational decision making. Instead, Allison found substantial deviations from such
a model, which he explained through two alternatives, an organizational process
model (model II) and a bureaucratic politics model (model III).
Critics of Allison's approach focused initially on the descriptive accuracy of his
account of the foreign policy process. More recently, however, his specification of
the models and particularly his tilt against his candidate for a rational choice model
have become a target. Jonathan Bendor and Thomas H. Hammond argue that Allison
creates a rational actor model without a dimension of strategic behavior. Omitting a
test of the insights of game theory is odd in a study of crisis bargaining. They contend
that Allison sets a benchmark for individual rationality that makes easier his promo-
tion of boundedly rational or nonrational models.38
Allison's second and third models, whatever their shortcomings, trace two paths
by which political and social units and organizations could be portrayed as rational.
The first avenue is increasing circumscription of rationality as aggregation increases.
Model II assumed that large organizations constrained individual rationality and be-
haved according to highly simplified decision rules. John Steinbruner's cybernetic
theory of decision, published soon after Allison's work appeared, elaborated a simi-
lar model of simplified organizational behavior that relied on simple and nonrational
decision-making processes.39 In both cases, rationality was held to become more
bounded and imperfect as one moved from individual choice to organizational rou-
tine. Despite the widely held view that organizations are less rational and "dumber"
than the individuals who compose them, Bendor and Hammond argue that large
organizations may, on the contrary, enhance the decision-making capacities of indi-
viduals rather than constrain them. Allison's view of institutional rationality is founded
on an optimistic view of individual rationality embodied in model I.40
If limitations on rationality are one route toward aggregation (the whole is less
rational than its parts), Allison's model of bureaucratic bargaining points toward
another. Policy outcome may be seen as the equilibrium of two-level or linked games.
In other words, bargaining among rational agents within an institutional setting adds
a degree of specification and rigor missing in Allison's bureaucratic politics model,
as well as captures the dimension of external bargaining. Helen Milner's contribution
to this issue of 10 describes at greater length the positive benefits of relaxing the
assumption that states are units. She provides a particularly telling critique of the
realist assumption that states are unitary actors. Less attention will be given here to
the modeling of internal political processes. Aggregation conceived as bargaining
among rational domestic actors in what Milner terms polyarchic settings has its own
risks and limits, however. Allison's early bureaucratic politics model appears to as-
sume that little hierarchy exists in foreign policy organizations.41 Two-level game
models sometimes evade this issue by positing a "chief of government" or other
authoritative decision maker who bargains with other political actors, typically legis-
lators (or the legislature). Whether that chief executive must also bargain with bureau-
cratic subordinates or cabinet colleagues (other than coalition partners in a parliamen-
tary regime) can be unclear in simpler game-theoretic models of two-level games.
Modeling the influence and points of intervention of interest groups raises similar
issues. Although on many international economic issues, a likely route for influenc-
ing foreign policy will be the legislature, many interest groups forge strong bonds
with bureaucracies in order to influence policy implementation. How such influence
filters into the preferences of the chief executive or head of government should also
be incorporated in the modeling of foreign policymaking. Principal-agent models
and delegation regimes provide one avenue of institutional analysis that can incorpo-
rate diverse domestic actors within hierarchical settings.42
Another potential weakness of rational institutionalist analysis is its treatment of
the institutional rules of the game. Robert Bates's recent study of the International
Coffee Organization is an excellent exemplar of building from rational social and
economic actors toward institutions at the domestic and the international level.43 His
treatment of political institutions is squarely within the frame of positive political
economy, "the study of rational decisions in a context of political and economic
institutions," or, as Bates puts it, institutions "defining political games in which
interests compete for influence over public policy."44
Building foreign policy actions from individual rational actors constrained by in-
stitutions leaves open the question of whether institutions are exogenous or endog-
enous, however. Positive political economy ultimately regards institutional change
as explicable through the same rational choice means as equilibrium outcomes within
a given institutional setting. However, most studies, like that of Bates, accept domes-
tic institutions as fixed and play out the domestic political games (interacting with
international strategic bargaining) within that context. In assessing the stability of
national preferences in a more elaborated institutionalist analysis of foreign policy,
as described by Milner, stability of domestic political institutions and the games that
they define is crucial. Unfortunately, determining when political actors will opt for
institutional change rather than change within institutions is rarely specified clearly.
If one can assume relatively fixed preferences on the part of key individuals (or
representatives of interests) and fixed institutional rules of the game, treating national
preferences and behavior within a rationalist framework is far more convincing than
under circumstances in which institutional rules change frequently and unpredict-
ably.
Despite their weaknesses, Allison's alternative models stood at the beginning of
two broad avenues for creating unified, if not unitary, rational actors from organiza-
tional and national collectivities. One route produces actors embedded in and con-
strained by organizational context. Whether that context bounds or amplifies their
rational decision making remains open to argument. The second route carefully speci-
fies domestic bargaining games that are then linked to international bargaining behav-
ior and strategic interaction. Those games may vary according to domestic institu-
tions, information environment, and type of international interaction.45 This second
avenue produces outcomes that may serve as proxies for a unified national interest.
Both routes force close attention to the simple, conventional assumptions within
international relations that have produced unitary and rational actors from the com-
plexities of domestic political and bureaucratic competition.
42. For an introduction to agency problems and their solutions in a political context, see Kiewiet and
McCubbins 1991, chap. 2.
43. Bates 1997a.
44. See Ibid., 164; and Alt and Shepsle 1990, 2.
45. For a representative and rigorous array of models linking international and domestic politics, see
Pahre and Papayoanou 1997.
Rationality in International Relations 933
Rather than emphasizing the social and cultural content of beliefs and preferences,
a third set of critics concentrates on the determinants of identity, which is held to be
socially constructed and prior to any definition of preferences or behavior. Once
again, the elevation of identity undermines methodological individualism rather than
rationalist models per se, but some interpretations of identity call into question ratio-
nal choice assumptions as well. Social constructivism, which incorporates a diverse
body of scholarship, emphasizes socially constructed identity and its implications as
a core constituent of its research program.60 Sociological approaches to international
relations also argue against a starting point of individual, rational agents. Instead,
agents themselves, whether individuals or states, are shaped profoundly by a dense
institutional environment. The environment can not only alter choices, it can also
constitute the properties of actors and even their existence.61 The sociological perspec-
tive accepts institutions as pervasive; although institutions "are certainly the product
of human activity, they are not necessarily the products of conscious design." They
represent "collective outcomes that are not the simple sum of individual interests."62
The social constructivist or sociological view of a highly institutionalized environ-
ment shaping or even determining the identity of its constituent actors need not be
incompatible with rationalist models. One could argue that choices are simply highly
constrained by social and cultural determinants (as earlier criticisms alleged) and that
socially constituted identities are an ontological issue prior to be\\aviota\ modeling
along rational choice lines.63 As John Ruggie puts it, "a core constructivist research
concern is what happens before the neo-utilitarian model purportedly kicks in. "M In
Outlining the effects Of identity on national security policy, for example, Ronald L.
Jepperson, Peter J. Katzenstein, and Alexander Wendt point to two ways in which
identity is prior to interests: states may develop interests linked to particular identi-
ties, or domestic identity politics may be reflected in foreign policy interests. In both
cases, identity is prior to interests and may define those interests, but the pursuit of
those interests could be incorporated in a rationalist model.65
Once again, however, extending or reinterpreting this concern with identity may
produce conflict rather than complementarity with a rationalist approach. Identity
may itself affect interests and behavior in a direct and unmediated way that is difficult
to reconcile with rational choice models. Kristen Renwick Monroe's sphere of ethi-
cal action, for example, proceeds directly from identity: "Certain kinds of political
action emanate primarily from one's perception of self in relation to others; this
perception effectively delineates and sets the domain of choice options perceived as
available to an actor, both in an empirical and moral sense." Or more radically:
"ethical action does not result from conscious calculus."66 Identity may also under-
mine a rationalist calculus if it can be attached to different forms of rationality. Shawn
Rosenberg contends that individuals may exhibit different structures of reasoning
and different rationalities; at the level of collectivities, cultural arguments (described
earlier in the case of non-Western cultures) could ascribe the same variation.67 Doubts
remain, however: would selection produce some form of roughly similar rationality
among individuals or collectivities; can the evidence of such radical variation in
reasoning (drawn from experimental evidence) be transposed to social and political
settings?
A final alternative to rational choice explanations of behavior, described by Elster
as the only alternative that cannot be absorbed by even an expanded rationalist frame,
is behavior driven by social norms.68 Behavior driven by social norms defined in this
way undermines both individualist and rationalist premises of rational choice mod-
els. The norms in question are social in two respects: they are shared by a population,
and that population sustains them by enforcing them (through expressed approval
and disapproval). Unlike rational action, which is determined by the instrumental
pursuit of future outcomes, norm-driven behavior is not outcome-oriented. One easy
guide to behavior governed by social norms (as compared to behavior driven by
rational or optimizing behavior) is the response (when challenged) that a certain
action "just isn't done." Norm-driven behavior is nonrational in a second sense, in
its tie to the emotions: "Social norms have a grip on the mind that is due to the strong
emotions their violations can trigger."69
Elster's conception of norm-driven behavior is contested from both the rationalist
and the social constractivist positions. Those deploying rational choice models seek
to incorporate this sphere of human behavior within a rationalist perspective as well.
Russell Hardin, for example, challenges Elster's definition of norms as not outcome-
oriented. For Hardin, following norms may combine elements of both rational self-
interest and nonconsequentialist motivation. The. fluid boundaries between norm-
driven and rational choice can only be assessed empirically.70 Social constructivists,
on the other hand, would contest the methodological individualism of Elster's defini-
tion and seek to expand the scope of norm-driven behavior as against behavior ex-
plained through individual choice.71 Two separable characteristics of norms are at
issue then: to what degree norms can be regarded as based in individual beliefs and
behavior and to what degree norms are sustained by rational self-interest (denned
minimally as concern with the consequences of the behavior induced by norms).
More than in economic transactions (where there are strong norms regarding what
money can buy), international relations has been portrayed as a setting of weak or
nonexistent norms. Norm-driven behavior in the conventional or realist view is rare
ences, was willing to attribute a circumscribed rationality to states and other interna-
tional actors. Typically, the issue is dealt with through simple pragmatism: unitary
actors are a useful assumption until proven unrealistic. Only recently has institu-
tional analysis provided a rigorous means for identifying the constraints on domestic
political actors and modeling both the international and domestic bargaining in which
they engage.
A diverse set of critics who emphasize culture and norms exemplify a third strat-
egy that is necessary for fruitful theoretical exchange: clarifying points of comple-
mentarity and conflict through careful definition. Many of these critics have ques-
tioned the individualist assumptions of most rational choice models; their arguments
have implications that are less clear for rational choice assumptions. By forcing
implicit auxiliary assumptions to the surface, rational choice models have been broad-
ened. By pressing for a theory of preference and belief formation and arguing for
attention to the identity formation of actors, alternatives based on culture and norms
opened questions that many rationalist models had mistakenly believed to be an-
swered. As a result, new research agendas—driven by rationality, culture, and iden-
tity—have illuminated ethnic and identity politics and their influence on interna-
tional relations, the character of units—as defined by themselves and by others—
across time, and "knowledge politics," the construction of social knowledge within
and across national boundaries.
Arguing for inevitable convergence or accommodation between rational choice
and its critics would be as naive as proclaiming peace in our time. Nevertheless, the
conditions described provide a basis for intellectual exchange that promises to ad-
vance research agendas on either side rather than promoting fruitless and grandiose
claims and counterclaims. Careful stipulations of scope, acknowledgment of joint
methodological shortcomings, and precise definition of perceived differences can be
supplemented empirically by problem-centered research. If research agendas are
largely theory-driven, selection biases will tend to favor research questions more
tractable for rational choice or its critics. By accepting the "neutral" empirical ground
of historical or contemporary issues whose importance is widely acknowledged, a
level playing field for theoretical competition may be established. Deterrence served
this purpose and illuminated the differences between rational deterrence theory and
its critics. Nationalism and ethnicity provide a similar competitive research frontier
for social constructivist and rational choice models.
Full-blown alternatives to rational choice may arise from each of these critical
alternatives. An evolutionary or selective model, endorsed by Waltz, would render
micro-level rationality otiose. Prospect theory or another model of psychological
processes may yet offer the breadth of application that rational choice has enjoyed as
a model of individual decision. Social constructivism could produce a unified, norm-
driven model of international relations that will contend with the state-centric and
rationalist predilections of both neorealists and liberal institutionalists.
What is more likely is further evolution of rationalist models in directions that
accommodate at least some of these criticisms. Heroic and unrealistic assumptions
regarding information and information processing will continue to be relaxed in fa-
Rationality in International Relations 941
References
Adler, Emanuel. 1987. The Power of Ideology: The Quest for Technological Autonomy in Argentina and
Brazil. Berkeley: University of California Press.
———. 1991. Cognitive Evolution: A Dynamic Approach for the Study of International Relations and
Their Progress. In Progress in Postwar International Relations, edited by Emanuel Adler and Beverly
Crawford, 43–88. New York: Columbia University Press.
———. 1992. The Emergence of Cooperation: National Epistemic Communities and the International
Evolution of the Idea of Nuclear Arms Control. International Organization 46:101–45.
———. 1997. Seizing the Middle Ground: Constructivism in World Politics. European Journal of Inter-
national Relations 3:319–63.
Adler, Emanuel, and Michael Barnett. 1996. Governing Anarchy: A Research Agenda for the Study of
Security Communities. Ethics and International Affairs 10:63–98.
Adler, Emanuel, and Michael Barnett, eds. 1998. Security Communities. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Adler, Emanuel, and Peter M. Haas. 1992. Conclusion: Epistemic Communities, World Order, and the
Creation of a Re ective Research Program. International Organization 46:367–90.
Aggarwal, Vinod K. 1996. Debt Games: Strategic Interaction in International Debt Rescheduling. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Akerlof, George A. 1970. The Market for ‘‘Lemons.’’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 84:488–500.
———. 1980. A Theory of Social Custom, of Which Unemployment May Be One Consequence. Quar-
terly Journal of Economics 94:749–75.
Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti. 1996. Income Distribution, Political Instability and Investment.
European Economic Review 40:1203–28.
Alesina, Alberto, and E. Spolaore. 1997. On the Number and Size of Nations. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 112:1027–56.
Alger, Chadwick. 1965. Personal Contact in Intergovernmental Organizations. In International Behavior:
A Social-Psychological Analysis, edited by Herbert C. Kelman, 523–47. New York: Holt, Rinehart and
Winston.
———. 1970. Research on Research: A Decade of Quantitative and Field Research on International
Organization. International Organization 23:414–50.
Alker, Hayward R. 1970. Computer Simulations, Conceptual Frameworks, and Coalition Behavior. In The
Study of Coalition Behavior, edited by Sven Groennings, 369–95. New York: Rinehart and Winston.
———. 1990. Rescuing ‘‘Reason’’ from the ‘‘Rationalists’’: Reading Vico, Marx, and Weber as Re ective
Institutionalists. Millennium: Journal of International Studies 19:161–84.
———. 1996. Rediscoveries and Reformulations: Humanistic Methodologies for International Studies.
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Alker, Hayward R., and Thomas J. Biersteker. 1984. The Dialectics of World Order: Notes for a Future
Archaeologist of International Savoir Faire. International Studies Quarterly 28:121–42.
Alker, Hayward R., and Bruce Russett. 1965. World Politics in the General Assembly. New Haven, Conn.:
Yale University Press.
Allison, Graham T. 1971. Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis. Boston: Little,
Brown.
Allison, Graham, and Morton Halperin. 1972. Bureaucratic Politics: A Paradigm and Some Policy Impli-
cations. World Politics 24:40–79.
Allport, Gordon W. 1954. The Nature of Prejudice. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.
Almond, Gabriel. 1950. The American People and Foreign Policy. New York: Harcourt Brace.
Alt, James E., and Kenneth A. Shepsle, eds. 1990. Perspectives on Positive Political Economy. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Alter, Karen. 1996. The European Court’s Political Power. West European Politics 19:458–60.
Alvarez, R. Michael, Geoffrey Garrett, and Peter Lange. 1991. Government Partisanship, Labor Organiza-
tion, and Macroeconomic Performance. American Political Science Review 85:541–56.
1014 International Organization
American Political Science Review. 1997. Forum (articles by John Vasquez, Kenneth Waltz, Thomas
Christensen and Jack Snyder, Colin Elman and Miriam Fendius Elman, Randall Schweller, and Ste-
phen Walt). American Political Science Review 91:899–935.
Andersen, Heine. 1997. Forskere i Danmark—videnskabssyn, vurderinger og aktiviteter: En videnskabsso-
ciologisk undersøgelse med særlig vægt paÊ samfundsvidenskaber. Working Paper 97. Copenhagen:
Copenhagen Business School, Department of Management, Politics, and Philosophy.
Andersen, Heine, and Lars Frode Frederiksen. 1995. Internationale Tidsskrifter i Samfundsvidenskaber—
Myter og realiteter. Samfundsøkonomen 5:14–22.
Andrews, Bruce. 1975. Social Rules and the State as a Social Actor. World Politics 27:521–40.
Andrews, David M. 1994. Capital Mobility and State Autonomy. International Studies Quarterly 38:193–
218.
Andrews, David M., and Thomas D. Willett. 1997. Financial Interdependence and the State. International
Organization 51:479–511.
Angell, Norman. 1911. The Great Illusion. New York: Putnam and Sons.
Appadurai, Arjun. 1996. Modernity at Large: Cultural Dimensions of Globalization. Minneapolis: Univer-
sity of Minnesota Press.
Aron, Raymond. 1966. Peace and War: A Theory of InternationalRelations. Translated by Richard Howard
and Annette Baker Fox. New York: Doubleday.
Arrighi, Giovanni. 1994. The Long Twentieth Century. London: Verso.
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1994. Methodological Individualism and Social Knowledge. American Economic Re-
view 84:1–9.
Art, Robert J. 1973. Bureaucratic Politics and American Foreign Policy: A Critique. Policy Sciences
4:467–90.
———. 1996. American Foreign Policy and the Fungibility of Force. Security Studies 5:7–42.
Arthur, W. Brian. 1988. Self-Reinforcing Mechanisms in Economics. In The Economy as an Evolving
Complex System, edited by Philip W. Anderson, Kenneth J. Arrow, and David Pines, 9–32. Reading,
Mass.: Addison-Wesley.
———. 1989. Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-in by Historical Events. Economic
Journal 99:116–31.
Aschauer, David A. 1990. Public Investment and Private Sector Growth. Washington, D.C.: Economic
Policy Institute.
Ascher, Charles A. 1952. Current Problems in the World Health Organization. International Organization
6:27–50.
Ascher, William. 1983. New Development Approaches and the Adaptability of International Agencies:
The Case of the World Bank. International Organization 37:415–39.
Ashley, Richard K. 1984. The Poverty of Neorealism. International Organization 38:225–86.
———. 1987. The Geopolitics of Geopolitical Space: Toward a Critical Social Theory of International
Relations. Alternatives 12:403–34.
———. 1988. Untying the Sovereign State: A Double Reading of the Anarchy Problematique. Millen-
nium: Journal of International Studies 12:227–62.
Austin-Smith, David. 1995. Campaign Contributions and Access. American Political Science Review
89:566–81.
Austin-Smith, David, and John Wright. 1992. Competitive Lobbying for a Legislator’s Vote. Social Choice
and Welfare 9:229–57.
———. 1994. Counteractive Lobbying. American Journal of Political Science 38:25–44.
Avant, Deborah D. 1994. Political Institutions and Military Change: Lessons from Peripheral Wars.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Axelrod, Robert. 1981. The Emergence of Cooperation Among Egoists. American Political Science Re-
view 75:306–18.
———. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.
———. 1986. An EvolutionaryApproach to Norms. American Political Science Review 80:1095–1111.
———. 1997. The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-Based Models of Competition and Collaboration.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
References 1015
Badie, Bertrand, and Marie-Claude Smouts. 1992. Le retournement du monde. Sociologie de la scène
internationale. Presses de la Fondation Nationale des Sciences Politiques and Dalloz.
Baldwin, David A. 1979. Power Analysis and World Politics: New Trends Versus Old Tendencies. World
Politics 31:161–93.
———. 1985. Economic Statecraft. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1989. Paradoxes of Power. New York: Blackwell.
———. 1995. Security Studies and the End of the Cold War. World Politics 48:117–41.
Baldwin, David A., ed. 1993. Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Baldwin, Robert E. 1985. The Political Economy of U.S. Trade Policy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Ball, M. Margaret. 1951. Bloc Voting in the General Assembly. International Organization 5:3–31.
———. 1961. Issue for the Americas: Human Rights and the Preservation of Democratic Institutions.
International Organization 15:21–37.
Ban eld, Edward. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. New York: Free Press.
Banks, Michael. 1984. The Evolution of International Relations Theory. In Con ict in World Society: A
New Perspective on International Relations, edited by Michael Banks, 1–21. Brighton, Sussex: Wheat-
sheaf.
Banuri, Tariq, and Juliet Schor, eds. 1992. Financial Openness and National Autonomy. New York: Ox-
ford University Press.
Baran, Paul A., and Paul M. Sweezy. 1966. Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Economic and
Social Order. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Barber, Benjamin. 1995. Jihad Versus McWorld. New York: Times Books.
Barber, William J. 1991. British and American Economists and Attempts to Comprehend the Nature of
War, 1910–1920. In Economics and National Security: A History of Their Interaction, edited by Crau-
furd D. Goodwin, 61–86. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press.
Barkin, J. Samuel, and Bruce Cronin. 1994. The State and the Nation: Changing Norms and Rules of
Sovereignty in International Relations. International Organization 48:107–30.
Barnes, James, Marshall Carter, and Max Skidmore. 1980. The World of Politics. New York: St. Martin’s
Press.
Barnett, Michael. 1995. The New United Nations Politics of Peace: From Juridical Sovereignty to Em-
pirical Sovereignty. Global Governance 1:79–97.
———. 1997. Bringing in the New World Order: Liberalism, Legitimacy, and the United Nations. World
Politics 49:526–51.
Barnett, Michael, and Martha Finnemore. 1997. The Politics, Power, and Pathologies of International
Organizations. Paper presented at the 93d Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Associa-
tion, Washington, D.C.
Baron, David. 1991. A Spatial Bargaining Theory of Government Formation in Parliamentary Systems.
American Political Science Review 85:137–65.
Baron, David, and John Ferejohn. 1989. Bargaining in Legislatures. American Political Science Review
83:1181–1206.
Barro, Robert, and Xavier Sala-I-Martin. 1995. Economic Growth. New York: Macmillan.
Bates, Robert H. 1997a. Open-Economy Politics: The Political Economy of the World Coffee Trade.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1997b.Area Studies and the Discipline. PS: Political Science and Politics 30:166–70.
Bauer, Raymond A., Ithiel de Sola Pool, and Anthony Dexter. 1972. American Business and Public Policy:
The Politics of Foreign Trade. 2d ed. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.
Bayoumi, Tamim, and Barry Eichengreen. 1997. Ever Closer to Heaven? An Optimum Currency Area
Index for European Countries. European Economic Review 41:761–70.
Beard, Charles. 1935. The Open Door at Home. New York: Random House.
Bendix, Reinhard. 1964. Nation-Building and Citizenship. New York: Wiley.
Bendix, Reinhard, ed. 1968. State and Society. Boston: Little, Brown.
Bendor, Jonathan, and Thomas H. Hammond. 1992. Rethinking Allison’s Models. American Political
Science Review 86:301–22.
1016 International Organization
Berger, Suzanne, and Ronald Dore, eds. 1996. National Diversity and Global Capitalism. Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press.
Berger, Thomas U. 1996. Norms, Identity, and National Security in Germany and Japan. In The Culture of
National Security, edited by Peter J. Katzenstein, 317–56. New York: Columbia University Press.
———. 1998. Cultures of Antimilitarism: National Security in Germany and Japan. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell
University Press.
Bergesen, Albert, ed. 1980. Studies of the Modern World System. New York: Academic Press.
Berkovitch, Nitza. 1995. From Motherhood to Citizenship: The Worldwide Incorporation of Women into
the Public Sphere in the Twentieth Century. Ph.D. diss., Stanford University, Stanford, Calif.
Berman, Harold J. 1983. Law and Revolution. The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Bernauer, Thomas. 1995. The Effect of International Environmental Institutions: How We Might Learn
More. International Organization 49:351–77.
Bernheim, B. Douglas. 1994. A Theory of Conformity. Journal of Political Economy 102:841–77.
Betts, Richard K. 1997. Should Strategic Studies Survive? World Politics 50:7–33.
Bhagwati, Jagdish, and Hugh Patrick. 1990. Aggressive Unilateralism: America’s 301 Policy and the
World Trading System. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Bhaskar, Roy. 1979. The Possibility of Naturalism. Atlantic Highlands, N.J.: Humanities Press.
Bigo, Didier. 1996. Polices en réseaux: l’expérience européenne. Paris: Presses de la Fondation Nationale
des Sciences Politiques.
Blainey, Geoffrey. 1973. The Causes of War. New York: Free Press.
Blake, David, and Robert Walters. 1976. The Politics of Global Economic Relations. Englewood Cliffs,
N.J.: Prentice Hall.
Bloom eld, Lincoln P. 1960. The United Nations and U.S. Foreign Policy. Boston: Little, Brown.
Blyth, Mark. 1997. Any More Good Ideas? Comparative Politics 29:229–50.
Boli, John, and George Thomas. 1998. INGOs and the Organization of World Culture. In Constructing
World Culture: International Nongovernmental Organizations Since 1875, edited by John Boli and
George Thomas. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
Bolton, P., and G. Roland. 1997. The Breakup of Nations: A Political Economy Analysis. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 112:1057–90.
Bonham, G. Matthew. 1970. Participation in Regional Parliamentary Assemblies: Effects on Attitudes of
Scandinavian Parliamentarians. Journal of Common Market Studies 8:325–36.
Brady, D. W. 1988. Critical Elections and Congressional Policy Making. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford Uni-
versity Press.
Braudel, Fernand. 1980. On History. Translated by Sarah Matthews. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Brawley, Mark. 1993. Liberal Leadership: Great Powers and Their Challengers in Peace and War. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Brenner, Robert. 1977. The Origins of Capitalist Development: A Critique of Neo-Smithian Marxism.
New Left Review 104:25–92.
Brodie, Bernard. 1949. Strategy as a Science. World Politics 1:467–88.
———. 1959. Strategy in the Missile Age. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Brodie, Bernard, ed. 1946. The Absolute Weapon: Atomic Power and World Order. New York: Harcourt,
Brace and Company.
Brooks, Stephen G. 1997. Dueling Realisms. International Organization 51:445–78.
Brown, Michael E. 1995. The Flawed Logic of NATO Expansion. Survival 37:34–-52.
Brown, Seyom, and Larry L. Fabian. 1975. Toward Mutual Accountability in Non-Terrestrial Realms.
International Organization 29:877–92.
Bryant, Ralph. 1987. International Financial Integration. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, and David Lalman. 1992. War and Reason. New Haven, Conn.: Yale Univer-
sity Press.
Bull, Hedley. 1968. Strategic Studies and Its Critics. World Politics 20:593–605.
References 1017
———. 1972. The Theory of International Politics, 1919–1969. In The Aberystwyth Papers: International
Politics, 1919–1969, edited by Brian Porter, 30–55. London: Oxford University Press.
———. 1977. The Anarchical Society: A Study of Order in World Politics. London: Macmillan.
———. 1995. The Anarchical Society. A Study of Order in World Politics. 2d ed. London: Macmillan.
Bull, Hedley, and Adam Watson, eds. 1984. The Expansion of European Society. London: Oxford Univer-
sity Press.
Burley, Anne-Marie. 1993. Regulating the World: Multilateralism, International Law, and the Projection
of the New Deal Regulatory State. In Multilateralism Matters, edited by John Gerard Ruggie, 125–56.
New York: Columbia University Press.
Burley, Anne-Marie, and Walter Mattli. 1993. Europe Before the Court: A Political Theory of Legal
Integration. International Organization 47:41–76.
Butter eld, Herbert. 1959. The Whig Interpretation of History. London: G. Bells and Son.
Butter eld, Herbert, and Martin Wight. 1968. Diplomatic Investigations: Essays in the Theory of Interna-
tional Politics. London:Allen and Unwin.
Buzan, Barry. 1984. Economic Structure and International Security: The Limits of the Liberal Case.
International Organization 38:597–624.
———. 1991. People, States, and Fear: An Agenda for International Security Studies in the Post–Cold
War Era. Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Reinner.
———. 1993. From International System to International Society: Structural Realism and Regime Theory
Meet the English School. International Organization 47:327–52.
———. 1996. The Timeless Wisdom of Realism? In International Theory: Positivism and Beyond, edited
by S. Smith, K. Booth and M. Zalewski, 47–65. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Buzan, Barry, and Richard Little. 1996. Reconceptualizing Anarchy: Structural Realism Meets World
History. European Journal of International Relations 2:403–38.
Buzan, Barry, Ole Wæver, and Jaap de Wilde. 1997. Security: A New Framework for Analysis. Boulder,
Colo.: Lynne Rienner.
Calleo, David. 1978. The German Problem Reconsidered: Germany and the World Order, 1870 to the
Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cameron, David R. 1978. The Expansion of the Public Economy. American Political Science Review
72:1243—61.
———. 1995. Transnational Relations and the Development of European Economic and Monetary Union.
In Bringing Transnational Relations Back In, edited by Thomas Risse-Kappen, 37–78. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Campbell, David. 1992. Writing Security: United States Foreign Policy and the Politics of Identity. Min-
neapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
———. 1996. Political Prosaics, Transversal Politics, and the Anarchical World. In Challenging the Bound-
aries, edited by Michael J. Shapiro and Hayward R. Alker, Jr. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota
Press.
Campbell, Donald T. 1987. Evolutionary Epistemology. In Evolutionary Epistemology, Theory of Ration-
ality, and the Sociology of Knowledge, edited by G. Radnitsky and W. W. Bartley. La Salle, Ill.: Open
Court.
Cantwell, John. 1989. Technical Innovations in Multinational Corporations. London: Blackwell.
Caporaso, James A. 1978a. Dependence, Dependency, and Power in the Global System: A Structural and
Behavioral Analysis. International Organization 32:13–44.
———. 1995. False Divisions: Security Studies and Global Political Economy. Mershon International
Studies Review 39:117–22.
Caporaso, James A., ed. 1978b. Dependence and Dependency in the Global System. International Organi-
zation 32 (1). Special issue.
Cardoso, Fernando Henrique, and Enzo Faletto. 1979. Dependency and Development in Latin America.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Carey, John. 1996. The Politics of Term Limits. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Carr, Edward Hallett. 1939. The Twenty Years’Crisis: An Introduction to the Study of International Rela-
tions. New York: Harper and Row.
1018 International Organization
———. [1946] 1962. The Twenty Years’Crisis 1919–1939: An Introduction to the Study of International
Relations. 2d ed. Reprint, London: Macmillan.
———. [1946] 1964. The Twenty Years’ Crisis, 1919–1939: An Introduction to the Study of International
Relations. 2d ed. Reprint, New York: Harper and Row.
Carter, Gwendolen M. 1950. The Commonwealth in the United Nations. International Organization 4:
247–60.
Caves, Richard E. 1996. Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis. 2d ed. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Cederman, Lars-Erik. 1997. Emergent Actors in World Politics: How States and Nations Develop and
Dissolve. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Cerny, Philip G. 1990. The Changing Architecture of Politics. London: Sage.
Cerulo, K. A. 1997. Identity Construction: New Issues, New Directions. Annual Review of Sociology
23:385–402.
Chaiken, Shelly, Wendy Wood, and Alice Eagly. 1996. Principles of Persuasion. In Social Psychology:
Handbook of Basic Principles, edited by E. T. Higgins and A. Kruglanski, 702–42. New York: Guilford
Press.
Chan, Gerald. 1997. International Studies in China: Origins and Development. Issues and Studies
33:40–64.
Chan, S. 1997. In Search of Democratic Peace: Problems and Promises. Mershon International Studies
Review 41:59–91.
Chan, Stephen. 1994. Beyond the North-West: Africa and the Rest. In Contemporary International Rela-
tions: A Guide to Theory, edited by A. J. R. Groom and Margot Light, 237–54. London and New York:
Pinter Publishers.
Chayes, Abram, and Antonia Handler Chayes. 1993. On Compliance. International Organization 47:175–
205.
———. 1995. The New Sovereignty. Compliance with International Regulatory Agreements. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Checkel, Jeffrey T. 1997. International Norms and Domestic Politics: Bridging the Rationalist-Construc-
tivist Divide. European Journal of International Relations 3:473–95.
———. 1998. The Constructivist Turn in International Relations Theory. World Politics 50:324–48.
Clarida, Richard, and Mark Gertler. 1996. How the Bundesbank Conducts Monetary Policy. Unpublished
manuscript, Columbia University, New York.
Claude, Inis L. 1956. Swords into Plowshares. New York: Random House.
———. 1963. The Political Framework of the United Nations’Financial Problems. International Organi-
zation 17:831–59.
———. 1966. Collective Legitimization as a Political Function of the United Nations. International
Organization 20:367–79.
Clayton, William. 1945. The Foreign Economic Policy of the State Department. Department of State
Bulletin 12:979–82.
Coase, Ronald. 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Economica 4:386–405.
———. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3:1–44.
Cohen, Benjamin J. 1973. The Question of Imperialism: The Political Economy of Dominance and Depen-
dence. New York: Basic Books.
———. 1991. Crossing Frontiers. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
———. 1993. The Triad and the Unholy Trinity. In Economic Relations in the 1990s, edited by Richard
Higgot, Richard Leaver, and John Ravenhill, 133–58. Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner.
———. 1996. Phoenix Risen: The Resurrection of Global Finance. World Politics 48:268–96.
Cohen, Benjamin V. 1951. The Impact of the United Nations on United States Foreign Policy. Interna-
tional Organization 5:274–81.
Cohen, M. D., James G. March, and Johan P. Olsen. 1972. A Garbage Can Model of Organizational
Choice. Administrative Science Quarterly 17:1–25.
References 1019
Coleman, J. S. 1966. Foundations for a Theory of Collective Decisions. American Journal of Sociology
71:615–27.
———. 1986. Individual Interests and Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Collier, R. B., and D. Collier. 1991. Shaping the Political Arena: Critical Junctures, the Labor Movement,
and Regime Dynamics in Latin America. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Collini, Stefan, Donald Winch, and John Burrow. 1983. That Noble Science of Politics: A Study in Nine-
teenth-Century Intellectual History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Collins, Susan. 1988. In ation and the European Monetary System. In The European Monetary System,
edited by Francesco Giavazzi, Stefano Milosi, and Marcus Miller, 112–36. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Combs, Jerald. 1983. American Diplomatic History: Two Centuries of Changing Interpretations. Berke-
ley: University of California Press.
Comisso, Ellen, and Laura D’Andrea Tyson, eds. 1986. Power, Purpose, and Collective Choice: Eco-
nomic Strategy in Socialist States. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Commission of the European Communities. 1990. One Market, One Money. European Economy 44:
63–68.
Condliffe, J. B. 1938. Markets and the Problem of Peaceful Change. Paris: League of Nations.
———. 1944. Economic Power as an Instrument of National Policy. American Economic Review 34:
305–14.
Conforti, Benedetto. 1993. International Law and the Role of Domestic Legal Systems. Dordrecht: Mar-
tinus Nijhoff.
Conybeare, John A. C. 1980. International Organization and the Theory of Property Rights. International
Organization 34:307–34.
Cooper, Richard N. 1968. The Economics of Interdependence: Economic Policy in the Atlantic Commu-
nity. New York: McGraw Hill.
Copeland, Dale C. 1996. Economic Interdependence and War: A Theory of Trade Expectations. Interna-
tional Security 20:5–41.
Corsetti, Giancarlo, and Nouriel Roubini. 1991. Fiscal De cits, Public Debt, and Government Insolvency.
Journal of Japanese and International Economies 5:354–380.
———. 1995. Political Biases in Fiscal Policy. In Monetary and Fiscal Policy in an Integrated Europe,
edited by Barry Eichengreen, Jeffry Frieden, and Jürgen von Hagen, 118–37. New York: Springer.
Coser, Louis. 1956. The Functions of Social Con ict. New York: Free Press.
Cox, Gary W. 1987. The Effõcient Secret. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1997. Making Votes Count. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cox, Robert W. 1969. The Executive Head. International Organization 23:205–30.
———. 1981. Social Forces, States, and World Orders: Beyond International Relations Theory. Millen-
nium: Journal of International Studies 10:126–55.
———. 1983. Gramsci, Hegemony, and International Relations:An Essay in Method. Millennium: Journal
of International Studies 12:162–75.
———. 1987. Production, Power, and World Order: Social Forces in the Making of History. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Cox, Robert W., and Harold K. Jacobson. 1973. The Anatomy of In uence: Decisionmaking in Interna-
tional Organization. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Crawford, Elisabeth T., and Albert D. Biderman. 1969. Social Scientists and International Affairs: A Case
for a Sociology of Social Science. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Crawford, Neta. 1993. Decolonization as an International Norm: The Evolution of Practices, Arguments,
and Beliefs. In Emerging Norms of Justi ed Intervention, edited by Laura Reed and Carl Kaysen,
37–61. Cambridge, Mass.: American Academy of Arts and Sciences.
Cummins, Jason G., Kevin A. Hassett, and R. Glenn Hubbard. 1995. Tax Reforms and Investment: A
Cross-Country Comparison. NBER Working Paper 5232. Cambridge, Mass: National Bureau of Eco-
nomic Research.
1020 International Organization
Cushman, David. 1988. Exchange-Rate Uncertainty and Foreign Direct Investment in the United States.
Weltwirtschaftsliches Archiv 124:322–36.
Cyert, R. M., and James G. March. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
Prentice-Hall.
Dahl, Robert A. 1961. Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City. New Haven, Conn.:
Yale University Press.
———. 1984. Modern Political Analysis. 4th ed. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
———. 1994. A Democratic Dilemma: System Effectiveness Versus Citizen Participation. Political Sci-
ence Quarterly 109:23–34.
David, Paul. 1985. Clio and the Economics of Qwerty. American Economic Review Papers and Proceed-
ings 75:332–37.
———. 1993. Institutions as the ‘‘Carriers of History’’? Unpublished manuscript, Stanford University,
Stanford, Calif.
de Boissieu, Christian, and Jean Pisani-Ferry. 1998. The Political Economy of French Economic Policy in
the Perspective of EMU. In Forging an Integrated Europe, edited by Barry Eichengreen and Jeffry
Frieden, 49–89. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
de Marchi, Neil. 1991. League of Nations Economists and the Idea of Peaceful Change in the Decade of
the 1930s. In Economics and National Security: A History of Their Interaction, edited by Craufurd D.
Goodwin, 143–78. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press.
de Wilde, Jaap. 1991. Saved from Oblivion: Interdependence Theory in the First Half of the Twentieth
Century. A Study on the Causality Between War and Complex Interdependence. Dartmouth, England:
Aldershot.
Demchak, Chris. 1991. Military Organizations, Complex Machines: Modernization in the U.S. Armed
Services. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Dennett, Raymond. 1949. Politics in the Security Council. International Organization 3:421–33.
Der Derian, James. 1987. On Diplomacy. Oxford: Blackwell.
Desch, Michael. 1996. War and Strong States, Peace and Weak States? International Organization
50:237–68.
Dessler, David. 1989. What’s at Stake in the Agent-Structure Debate? International Organization
43:441–74.
Destler, I. M. 1992. American Trade Politics: System Under Stress. Washington, D.C.: Institute for Inter-
national Economics.
———. 1994. Foreign Policy Making with the Economy at Center Stage. In Beyond the Beltway, edited
by Daniel Yankelovich and I. M. Destler, 26–42. New York: Norton.
Deutsch, Karl W. 1953. Nationalism and Social Communication: An Inquiry into the Foundations of
Nationality. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Deutsch, Karl W., and J. David Singer. 1964. Multipolar Power Systems and International Stability. World
Politics 16:390–406.
Deutsch, Karl W., Sidney A. Burrell, Robert A. Kann, Maurice Lee, Jr., Martin Lichterman, Raymond E.
Lindgren, Francis L. Loewenheim, and Richard W. Van Wagenen. 1957. Political Community and the
North Atlantic Area: International Organization in the Light of Historical Experience. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Dewey, J. 1927. The Public and Its Problems. Denver, Colo.: Alan Swallow.
Diebold, William, Jr. 1960. The Changed Economic Position of Western Europe: Some Implications for
United States Policy and International Organization. International Organization 14:1–19.
Diez, Thomas. 1997. International Ethics and European Integration: Federal State or Network Horizon?
Alternatives 22:287–312.
DiMaggio, Paul. 1997. Culture and Cognition. Annual Review of Sociology 23:263–87.
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Walter W. Powell. 1983. The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and
Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields. American Sociological Review 48:147–60.
———. 1991. Introduction. In The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, edited by Paul J.
DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, 1–38. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
References 1021
Donnelly, Jack. 1986. International Human Rights:A Regime Analysis. International Organization 40:599–
642.
———. 1995. Realism and the Academic Study of International Relations. In Political Science in History:
Research Programs and Political Traditions, edited by James Farr, John S. Dryzek, and Stephen T.
Leonard, 175–97. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.
Downs, George W. 1989. The Rational Deterrence Debate. World Politics 41:225–38.
Downs, George W., and David Rocke. 1995. Optimal Imperfection: Domestic Uncertainty and Institutions
in International Relations. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Doyle, Michael W. 1983a. Kant, Liberal Legacies, and Foreign Affairs. Part 1. Philosophy and Public
Affairs 12:205–35.
———. 1983b. Kant, Liberal Legacies, and Foreign Affairs. Part 2. Philosophy and Public Affairs 12:
323–53.
———. 1997. Ways of War and Peace: Realism, Liberalism, and Socialism. New York: Norton.
Dubois, Ellen Carol. 1994. Woman Suffrage Around the World: Three Phases of Suffragist Internation-
alism. In Suffrage and Beyond: International Feminist Perspectives, edited by Caroline Daley and
Melanie Nolan, 252–74. New York: New York University Press.
Duchene, Francois. 1994. Jean Monnet: The First Statesman of Interdependence. New York: Norton.
Dunn, Frederick S. 1948. The Scope of International Relations. World Politics 1:142–46.
———. 1949. The Present Course of International Relations Research. World Politics 2:80–95.
Dunne, Timothy. 1994. The Genesis and the History of the ‘‘English School’’ of International Relations. In
The ‘‘English School’’ of International Relations: A Conference Report, edited by Iver B. Neumann,
1–17. NUPI Report 179. Oslo: Norwegian Institute of International Affairs.
Dunning, John H. 1988. Multinationals, Technology, and Competitiveness. Boston: Unwin Hyman.
Dupont, Cedric. 1994. Domestic Politics and International Negotiations. In Game Theory and Interna-
tional Relations, edited by P. Allan and C. Schmidt, 156–90. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Durkheim, Emile. 1933. The Division of Labor in Society. Translated by G. Simpson. New York: Mac-
millan.
———. 1938. The Rules of Sociological Method. 8th ed. Translated by Sarah A. Solovay and John H.
Mueller. Edited by E. G. Catlin. New York: The Free Press.
———. 1951. Suicide, A Study in Sociology. Translated by John A. Spaulding and George Simpson.
Edited by George Simpson. New York: Free Press.
———. 1953a. Individual and Collective Representations. In Sociology and Philosophy, translated by D.
F. Pocock. London: Cohen and West.
———. 1953b. Value Judgments and Judgments of Reality. In Sociology and Philosophy, translated by D.
F. Pocock. London: Cohen and West.
Duvall, Raymond D., P. Terrence Hoppmann, Brian L. Job, and Robert T. Kudrle. 1983. The Economic
Foundations of War: Editor’s Introduction. International Studies Quarterly 27:379.
Dyson, Kenneth H. F. 1980. The State Tradition in Western Europe—A Study of an Idea and Institution.
Oxford: Martin Robertson.
Eagly, Alice, and Shelly Chaiken. 1993. The Psychology of Attitudes. Fort Worth, Tex.: Harcourt Brace
Jovanovich.
Earle, Edward Mead. 1943. Adam Smith, Alexander Hamilton, Friedrich List: The Economic Foundations
of Military Power. In Makers of Modern Strategy: Military Thought from Machiavelli to Hitler, edited
by Edward Mead Earle, 117–54. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Easton, David, John G. Gunnell, and Luigi Graziano, eds. 1991. The Development of Political Science: A
Comparative Survey. London and New York: Routledge.
Egeberg, M., and J. Trondal. 1997. An Organization Theory Perspective on Multi-level Governance in the
EU: The Case of the EEA as a Norm of Affiliation. Working Paper Series 21. Oslo: ARENA.
Eggertsson, Thrainn. 1996. A Note on the Economics of Institutions. In Empirical Studies of Institutional
Change, edited by L. Alston, T. Eggertsson, and D. North, 6–24. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Eichengreen, Barry. 1994. The Endogeneity of Exchange-Rate Regimes. In Understanding Interdepen-
dence, edited by Peter Kenen, 3–33. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
1022 International Organization
———. 1996. Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Fabio Ghironi. 1996. European Monetary Uni cation: The Challenges Ahead. In
Monetary Reform in Europe, edited by Francisco Torres, 83–120. Lisbon: Universidade Catholica
Editora.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Charles Wyplosz. 1993. The Unstable EMS. Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 1:51–143.
Eide, A., and B. Hagtvet, eds. 1992. Human Rights in Perspective. A Global Assessment. Oxford: Black-
well.
Eisenstadt, S. N. 1987. European Civilization in Comparative Perspective. Oslo: Norwegian University
Press.
Elias, Norbert. 1994. The Civilizing Process. Translated by Edmund Jephcott. Oxford: Blackwell.
Elshtain, Jean. 1987. Women and War. New York: Basic Books.
———. 1996. Is There a Feminist Tradition on War and Peace? In The Ethics of War and Peace, edited by
Terry Nardin. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Elster, Jon. 1979. Ulysses and the Sirens: Studies in Rationality and Irrationality. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
———. 1983. Sour Grapes: Studies in Subversion of Rationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
———. 1984. Ulysses and the Sirens: Studies in Rationality and Irrationality. Rev. ed. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
———. 1986a. Introduction. In Rational Choice, edited by Jon Elster, 1–33. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
———. 1989a. Social Norms and Economic Theory. Journal of Economic Perspectives 3:99–117.
———. 1989b. Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1989c. The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Elster, Jon, ed. 1986b. The Multiple Self. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Emerson, Rupert, and Inis L. Claude. 1952. The Soviet Union and the United Nations: An Essay in
Interpretation. International Organization 6:1–26.
Emory, F. E., and E. L. Trist. 1973. Towards a Social Ecology: Contextual Appreciation of the Future in
the Present. London: Plenum.
Encarnation, Dennis. 1992. Rivals Beyond Trade: America Versus Japan in Global Competition. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Englemann, Daniela, Hans-Joachim Knopf, Klaus Rocher, and Thomas Risse-Kappen. 1997. Identity
Politics in the European Union: The Case of Economic and Monetary Union. In The Politics of Eco-
nomic and Monetary Union, edited by Petri Minkkinen and Heikki Patomäki, 105–32. Boston: Kluwer.
Epstein, David, and Sharyn O’Halloran. 1997. Choosing How to Decide: Efficient Policy Making Under
Separate Powers. Unpublished manuscript, Columbia University, New York.
Eriksen, E. O., and J. WeigaÊ rd. 1997. Conceptualizing Politics: Strategic or Communicative Action?
Scandinavian Political Studies 20:219–41.
Ernst, Manfred. 1978. Attitudes of Diplomats at the United Nations: The Effects of Organization Partici-
pation on the Evaluation of the Organization. International Organization 32:1037–43.
Esping-Andersen, Gösta. 1985. States Against Markets. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Euben, Roxanne. 1995. When Worldviews Collide: Con icting Assumptions About Human Behavior
Held by Rational Actor Theory and Islamic Fundamentalism. Political Psychology 16:157–78.
Evans, Peter B. 1972. National Autonomy and Economic Development. In Transnational Relations and
World Politics, edited by Robert O. Keohane and Joseph S. Nye, Jr., 325–42. Cambridge, Mass.:
Harvard University Press.
———. 1979. Dependent Development: The Alliance of Multinational,State, and Local Capital In Brazil.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1995. Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
References 1023
Evans, Peter B., Harold K. Jacobson, and Robert D. Putnam, eds. 1993. Double-Edged Diplomacy: Inter-
national Bargaining and Domestic Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Evans, Peter B., Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skocpol, eds. 1985. Bringing the State Back In.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Evans, Tony, and Peter Wilson. 1992. Regime Theory and the English School of International Relations: A
Comparison. Millennium: Journal of International Studies 21:329–51.
Eyre, Dana P., and Mark C. Suchman. 1996. Status, Norms, and the Proliferation of Conventional Weap-
ons: An Institutional Theory Approach. In The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in
World Politics, edited by Peter J. Katzenstein, 79–113. New York: Columbia University Press.
Fagen, Richard. 1978. A Funny Thing Happened on the Way to the Market. International Organization
32:287–300.
Farnham, Barbara. 1992. Roosevelt and the Munich Crisis: Insights from Prospect Theory. Political Psy-
chology 13:205–35.
Farr, James. 1988. The History of Political Science. American Journal of Political Science 32:1175–95.
Farr, James, John Gunnell, Raymond Seidelman, John S. Dryzek, and Stephen T. Leonard. 1990. Can
Political Science History Be Neutral? American Political Science Review 84:587–607.
Farr, James, and Raymond Seidelman, eds. 1993. Discipline and History. Political Science in the United
States. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Farr, James, John S. Dryzek, and Stephen T. Leonard, eds. 1995. Political Science in History: Research
Programs and Political Traditions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Farrell, Joseph, and Matthew Rabin. 1996. Cheap Talk. Journal of Economic Perspectives 10:103—18.
Fearon, James D. 1994a. Cooperation and Bargaining Under Anarchy. Unpublished manuscript, Univer-
sity of Chicago, Chicago, Ill.
———. 1994b. Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Disputes. American
Political Science Review 88:577–92.
———. 1995. Rationalist Explanations for War. International Organization 49:379–414.
———. 1997. What Is Identity (As We Now Use the Word)? Unpublished manuscript, University of
Chicago, Chicago, Ill.
———. 1998. Domestic Politics, Foreign Policy, and Theories of International Relations. In Annual
Review of Political Science 1, edited by Nelson Polsby, 289–313. Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews.
Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. 1996. Explaining Interethnic Cooperation. American Political
Science Review 90:715–35.
Feenberg, Daniel R., and Harvey S. Rosen. 1986. State Personal Income and Sales Taxes, 1977–1983. In
Studies in State and Local Public Finance, edited by Harvey S. Rosen, 134–79. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Feinberg, Gerald. 1978. What Is the World Made of? Atoms, Leptons, Quarks, and Other Tantalizing
Particles. Garden City, N.Y.: Anchor/Doubleday.
Feis, Herbert. 1930. Europe, the World’s Banker, 1870–1914. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
———. 1950. The Road to Pearl Harbor. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Feldstein, Martin. 1997. EMU and International Con ict. Foreign Affairs 76:60–73.
Feldstein, Martin, and P. Bacchetta. 1991. National Savings and International Investment. In National
Savings and Economic Performance, edited by Douglas Bernheim and John Shoven, 201–26. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Feldstein, Martin, and Charles Horioka. 1980. Domestic Savings and International Capital Flows. The
Economic Journal 90:314–29.
Ferejohn, John. 1991. Rationality and Interpretation: Parliamentary Elections in Early Stuart England. In
The Economic Approach to Politics, edited by Kristen Renwick Monroe, 279–305. New York: Harper-
Collins.
———. 1993. Structure and Ideology. In Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political
Change, edited by Judith Goldstein and Robert Keohane, 207–33. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press.
1024 International Organization
———. 1995. Foreword. In Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions, edited by Kenneth Shepsle
and Barry Weingast, ix–xiii. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Ferejohn, John, and Charles Shipan. 1990. Congressional In uence on Bureaucracy. Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization 6:1–20.
Field, Alexander James. 1979. On the Explanation of Rules Using Rational Choice Models. Journal of
Economic Issues 13:49–72.
———. 1981. The Problem with Neoclassical Institutional Economics: A Critique with Special Reference
to the North/Thomas Model of Pre-1500 Europe. Explorations in Economic History 19:174–98.
———. 1984. Microeconomics, Norms, and Rationality. Economic Development and Cultural Change
32:683–711.
Finger, J. Michael, Merlinda Ingco, and Ulrich Reincke. 1996. The Uruguay Round. Washington, D.C.:
World Bank.
Finnemore, Martha. 1993. International Organizations as Teachers of Norms: The United Nations Educa-
tional, Scienti c, and Cultural Organization and Science Policy. International Organization 47:
565–97.
———. 1995. Sovereign Default and Military Intervention. Paper presented at the 91st Annual Meeting of
the American Political Science Association, San Francisco.
———. 1996a. National Interests in International Society. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1996b. Norms, Culture, and World Politics: Insights from Sociology’s Institutionalism. Interna-
tional Organization 50:325–47.
———. 1996c. Constructing Norms of Humanitarian Intervention. In The Culture of National Security:
Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by Peter J. Katzenstein, 153–85. New York: Columbia
University Press.
Fischer, Markus. 1992. Feudal Europe, 800–1300: Communal Discourse and Con ictual Practices. Inter-
national Organization 46:427–66.
Fiske, Susan, and Shelly Taylor. 1994. Social Cognition. New York: Random House.
Flora, P. 1983. State, Economy, and Society in Western Europe 1815–1975. Frankfurt: Campus.
Florini, Ann. 1996. The Evolution of International Norms. International Studies Quarterly 40:363–89.
Forsythe, David P. 1991. The Internationalization of Human Rights. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.
Fox, William T. 1949. Interwar International Relations Research: The American Experience. World Poli-
tics 2:67–79.
———. 1951. The United Nations in the Era of Total Diplomacy. International Organization 5:265–73.
Fox, William T., and Annette Baker Fox. 1961. The Teaching of International Relations in the U.S. World
Politics 13:339–59.
Franck, Thomas. 1990. The Power of Legitimacy Among Nations. New York: Oxford University Press.
———. 1992. The Emerging Right to Democratic Governance. American Journal of International Law
86:46–91.
Frankel, Benjamin, ed. 1996. Realism: Restatements and Renewal. London: Frank Cass.
Frankel, Jeffrey A. 1993. On Exchange Rates. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Andrew Rose. 1996. The Endogeneity of the Optimum Currency Area Criteria.
Unpublished manuscript, University of California, Berkeley.
Frankel, Jeffrey A., Ernesto Stein, and Shang-Jin Wei. 1996. Regional Trading Arrangements: Natural or
Super-natural? NBER Working Paper 5431. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Fratianni, Michele, and Jürgen von Hagen. 1992. The European Monetary System and European Mon-
etary Union. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
French, Kenneth, and James Poterba. 1991. International Diversi cation and International Equity Mar-
kets. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings) 81:222—26.
Frey, Frederick. 1985. The Problem of Actor Designation in Political Analysis. Comparative Politics
127–52.
Friedberg, Aaron L. 1988. The Weary Titan: Britain and the Experience of Relative Decline, 1895–1905.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1989. The Strategic Implications of Relative Economic Decline. Political Science Quarterly
104:401–32.
References 1025
Frieden, Jeffry A. 1990. Debt, Development, and Democracy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1991. Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Fi-
nance. International Organization 45:425–51.
———. 1996. The Impact of Goods and Capital Market Integration on European Monetary Politics.
Comparative Political Studies 29:195–222.
———. 1997a.Actors and Preferences in International Politics. Unpublished manuscript, Harvard Univer-
sity, Cambridge, Mass.
———. 1997b. Monetary Populism in Nineteenth-Century America: An Open Economy Interpretation.
Journal of Economic History 57:367–95.
Frieden, Jeffry A., and Ronald Rogowski. 1996. The Impact of the International Economy on National
Policies. In Internationalization and Domestic Politics, edited by Robert O. Keohane and Helen V.
Milner, 25–47. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Friedman, Edward. 1997. The Challenge of a Rising China: Another Germany? In Eagle Adrift: American
Foreign Policy at the End of the Century, edited by Robert Lieber, 215–45. New York: Longman.
Friedman, J., ed. 1996. The Rational Choice Controversy. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
———. 1968. The Role of Monetary Policy. American Economic Review 58:1–17.
Friedrich, C. J. 1963. Man and His Government. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Frohlich, Norman, Joe Oppenheimer, and Oran Young. 1971. Political Leadership and Collective Goods.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Fudenberg, Drew, and Jean Tirole. 1991. Game Theory. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Fukuyama, Francis. 1992. The End of History and the Last Man. New York: Free Press.
Fure, Odd-Bjørn. 1996. Mellomkrigstid 1920–1940. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.
Galtung, Johan. 1981. Structure, Culture, and Intellectual Style: An Essay Comparing Saxonic, Teutonic,
Gallic, and Nipponic Approaches. Social Science Information 20:817–56.
Gardner, Richard M. 1956. Sterling-Dollar Diplomacy: Anglo-American Collaborationin the Reconstruc-
tion of Multilateral Trade. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Gareau, Frederick H. 1970. Cold War Cleavages as Seen from the United Nations General Assembly:
1947–1967. Journal of Politics 32:929–68.
———. 1981. The Discipline of International Relations: A Multi-National Perspective. Journal of Politics
43:779–802.
Garrett, Geoffrey. 1995. Capital Mobility, Trade, and the Domestic Politics of Economic Policy. Interna-
tional Organization 49:657–87.
———. 1998a. Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1998b. The Transition to Economic and Monetary Union. In Forging an Integrated Europe,
edited by Barry Eichengreen and Jeffry Frieden, 21–47. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
———. 1998c. Capital Flows, Capital Mobility, and Capital Taxation. Unpublished manuscript, Yale
University.
———. 1998d. Governing in the Global Economy. Paper presented at the 94th Annual Meeting of the
American Political Science Association, September, Boston.
Garrett, Geoffrey, and Peter Lange. 1991. Political Responses to Interdependence: What’s ‘Left’ for the
Left? International Organization 45:539–64.
———. 1995. Internationalization, Institutions, and Political Change. International Organization 49:
627–55.
———. 1996. Internationalization, Institutions, and Political Change. In Internationalization and Do-
mestic Politics, edited by Robert O. Keohane and Helen Milner, 48–78. New York: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Garrett, Geoffrey, and Deborah Mitchell. 1998. External Risk and Social Insurance: Reassessing the Glo-
balization–Welfare State Nexus. Unpublished manuscript, Yale University, New Haven, Conn.
Garrett, Geoffrey, and George Tsebelis. 1996. An Institutional Critique of Intergovernmentalism. Interna-
tional Organization 50:269–99.
Garrett, Geoffrey, and Barry R. Weingast. 1993. Ideas, Interests, and Institutions: Constructing the Euro-
pean Community’s Internal Market. In Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political
1026 International Organization
Change, edited by Judith Goldstein and Robert O. Keohane, 173–206. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press.
Geertz, Clifford. 1980. Negara: The Theater-State in Nineteenth-Century Bali. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Gelpi, Christopher. 1997. Crime and Punishment: The Role of Norms in Crisis Bargaining. American
Political Science Review 91:339–60.
George, Alexander L., and Juliette L. George. 1964. Woodrow Wilson and Colonel House: A Personality
Study. New York: Dover Publications.
George, Jim. 1994. Discourses of Global Politics: A Critical (Re)Introduction to International Relations.
Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner.
Gerschenkron, Alexander. 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Cambridge, Mass.:
Harvard University Press.
Giavazzi, Francesco, and Alberto Giovannini. 1989. Limiting Exchange Rate Variability: The European
Monetary System. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Giddens, Anthony. 1979. Central Problems in Social Theory: Action, Structure, and Contradiction in
Social Analysis. Berkeley: University of California Press.
———. 1981. A Contemporary Critique of Historical Materialism. Berkeley: University of California
Press.
———. 1984. The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
———. 1985. The Nation State and Violence. Oxford: Polity Press.
Giesen, Klaus-Gerd. 1995. French Cancan zwischen Positivismus, Enzyklopädismus, und Historismus.
Zeitschrift für internationale Beziehungen 2:141–70.
Gill, Stephen. 1995. Globalisation, Market Civilisation, and Disciplinary Neoliberalism. Millennium:
Journal of International Studies 24:399–424.
Gill, Stephen, ed. 1993. Gramsci, Historical Materialism, and International Relations. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Gill, Stephen R., and David Law. 1989. Global Hegemony and the Structural Power of Capital. Interna-
tional Studies Quarterly 33:475–99.
Gilligan, Carol. 1993. In a Different Voice: Psychological Theory and Women’s Development. Cambridge,
Mass: Harvard University Press.
Gilligan, Michael J. 1997. Empowering Exporters. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Gilligan, Thomas W., and Keith Krehbiel. 1990. Organization of Informative Committees by a Rational
Legislature. American Journal of Political Science 34:531–64.
Gilovich, Thomas. 1991. How We Know What Isn’t So: The Fallibility of Reason in Everyday Life. New
York: Free Press.
Gilpin, Robert. 1972. The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations. In Transnational Relations and
World Politics, edited by Robert O. Keohane and Joseph S. Nye, Jr., 48–69. Cambridge, Mass.: Har-
vard University Press.
———. 1975. U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct
Investment. New York: Basic Books.
———. 1977. Economic Interdependence and National Security in Historical Perspective. In Economic
Issues and National Security, edited by Klaus Knorr and Frank N. Trager, 19–66. Lawrence: University
of Kansas Press.
———. 1981. War and Change in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1984. The Richness of the Tradition of Political Realism. International Organization 38:287–
304.
———. 1987. The Political Economy of International Relations. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press.
———. 1996. No One Loves a Political Realist. Security Studies 5:3–26.
Glaser, Charles. 1994. Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help. International Security 19:50–90.
Gleditsch, N. P. 1992. Democracy and Peace. Journal of Peace Research 29:369–76.
References 1027
Golden, Miriam A. 1998. Economic Integration and Industrial Relations. Unpublished manuscript, Univer-
sity of California, Los Angeles.
Goldmann, Kjell. 1995. Im Westen nichts Neues: Seven International Relations Journals in 1972 and
1992. European Journal of International Relations 1:245–60.
———. 1996. International Relations: An Overview. In A New Handbook of Political Science, edited by
Robert E. Goodin and Hans-Dieter Klingemann, 401–27. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Goldstein, Joshua. 1988. Long Cycles: Prosperity and War in the Modern Age. New Haven, Conn.: Yale
University Press.
Goldstein, Judith. 1993. Ideas, Interests, and American Trade Policy. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press.
———. 1996. International Law and Domestic Institutions: Reconciling North American ‘‘Unfair’’ Trade
Laws. International Organization 50:541–64.
Goldstein, Judith, and Robert O. Keohane. 1993a. Ideas and Foreign Policy: An Analytical Framework. In
Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change, edited by Judith Goldstein and
Robert O. Keohane, 3–30. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Goldstein, Judith, and Robert O. Keohane, eds. 1993b. Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and
Political Change Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Goldthorpe, John H., ed. 1984. Order and Con ict in Contemporary Capitalism. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Goodman, John B., and Louis R. Pauly. 1993. The Obsolescence of Capital Controls? World Politics
46:50–82.
Goodrich, Leland M. 1947. From League of Nations to United Nations. InternationalOrganization 1:3–32.
———. 1956. Korea: A Study of U.S. Policy in the United Nations. New York: Council on Foreign
Relations.
Gordon, Lincoln. 1956. Economic Aspects of Coalition Diplomacy—The NATO Experience. Interna-
tional Organization 10:529–43.
Gordon, Roger, and Lans Bovenberg. 1996. Why Is Capital so Immobile Internationally? American Eco-
nomic Review 86:1057–75.
Gorter, Wytze. 1954. GATT After Six Years: An Appraisal. International Organization 8:1–18.
Gosovic, Branislav, and John Gerard Ruggie. 1976. On the Creation of a New International Economic
Order: Issue Linkage and the Seventh Special Session of the UN General Assembly. International
Organization 30:309–45.
Gould, Stephen Jay. 1987. Time’s Arrow, Time’s Cycle. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.
Gourevitch, Peter A. 1978. The Second Image Reversed: International Sources of Domestic Politics.
International Organization 32:881–912.
———. 1986. Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Gowa, Joanne S. 1989. Rational Hegemons, Excludable Goods, and Small Groups: An Epitaph for Hege-
monic Stability Theory? World Politics 41:307–24.
———. 1994. Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Gray, Colin. 1992. House of Cards: Why Arms Control Must Fail. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Green, Donald P., and Ian Shapiro. 1994. Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory. New Haven, Conn.:
Yale University Press.
Gregg, Robert W. 1966. The UN Regional Economic Commissions and Integration in the Underdeveloped
Region. International Organization 20:208–32.
Greider, William. 1997. One World, Ready or Not. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Greif, Avner. 1994. On the Political Foundations of the Late Medieval Commercial Revolution: Genoa in
the 12th and 13th Centuries. Journal of Economic History 54:271–87.
———. 1995. Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Re ection
on Collectivist and Individualist Societies. Journal of Political Economy 102:912–50.
Grieco, Joseph M. 1988. Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal
Institutionalism. International Organization 42:485–507.
1028 International Organization
———. 1990. Cooperation Among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Groom, A. J. R. n.d. The Study of International Relations in France: A View from Outside. Paper prepared
for a seminar at the Université Pierre Mendès-France, Grenoble. http://snipe.ukc.ac.uk/international/
papers.dir/groom4.html
———. 1994. The World Beyond: The European Dimension. In Contemporary International Relations: A
Guide to Theory, edited by A. J. R. Groom and Margot Light, 219–36. London and New York: Pinter
Publishers.
Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. 1994. Protection by Sale. American Economic Review 84:
833–50.
Grubel, Herbert G., and P. J. Lloyd. 1975. Intra-industry Trade: The Theory and Measurement of Interna-
tional Trade in Differentiated Products. New York: Wiley.
Gruber, Lloyd. 1996. Ruling the World: Power Politics and the Rise of Supranational Institutions. Unpub-
lished manuscript, University of Chicago, Chicago, Ill.
Gunnell, John G. 1991. In Search of the State: Political Science as an Emerging Discipline in the
U.S. In Sociology of the Sciences—A Yearbook. Vol. 15, Discourses on Society: The Shaping
of the Social Sciences, edited by P. Wagner, B. Wittrock, and R. Whitley, 123–61. Dordrecht:
Kluwer.
———. 1993. The Descent of Political Theory: The Genealogy of an American Vocation. Chicago: Uni-
versity of Chicago Press.
———. 1995. The Declination of the ‘‘State’’ and the Origins of American Pluralism. In Political Science
in History: Research Programs and Political Traditions, edited by James Farr, John S. Dryzek, and
Stephen T. Leonard, 19–40. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Gurowitz, Amy. 1997. International Society and State Inclusion of Non-Citizens: The Changing Debate in
Japan and Germany. Paper prepared for the Annual Convention of the International Studies Associa-
tion, 18–22 March, Toronto.
Guttentag, Jack M., and Richard Herring. 1985. Commercial Bank Lending to Developing Countries:
From Overlending to Underlending to Structural Reform. In International Debt and the Developing
Countries, edited by Gordon W. Smith and John T. Cuddington, 129–50. Washington, D.C.: The World
Bank.
Guzzini, Stefano. 1998. Realism in International Relations/International Political Economy: The Con-
tinuing Story of a Death Foretold. London: Routledge.
Haas, Ernst B. 1958. The Uniting of Europe: Political, Social, and Economic Forces, 1950–1957. Stan-
ford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
———. 1961. International Integration: The European and the Universal Process. InternationalOrganiza-
tion 15:366–92.
———. 1964a. Beyond the Nation State: Functionalism and International Organization. Stanford, Calif.
Stanford University Press.
———. 1964b. Technocracy, Pluralism, and the New Europe. In A New Europe?, edited by Stephen
Graubard. London: Oldbourne Press.
———. 1967. The Uniting of Europe and the Uniting of Latin America. Journal of Common Market
Studies 5:315–33.
———. 1975. The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory. Berkeley: Institute of International
Studies, University of California, Berkeley.
———. 1976. Turbulent Fields and the Theory of Regional Integration. International Organization
30:173–212.
———. 1983. Words Can Hurt You; or, Who Said What to Whom About Regimes. In International
Regimes, edited by Stephen D. Krasner, 23–59. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1986. What Is Nationalism and Why Should We Study It? International Organization 40:707–44.
———. 1990. When Knowledge Is Power. Berkeley: University of California Press.
References 1029
Hardin, Russell. 1995. One for All: The Logic of Group Con ict. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press.
Hargens, Lowell L. 1988. Scholarly Consensus and Journal Rejection Rates. American Sociological Re-
view 53:139–51.
Harrison, Lawrence. 1985. Underdevelopment Is a State of Mind: The Latin American Case. Boston:
Madison Books.
Harsanyi, John. 1969. Rational Choice Models of Political Behavior Versus Functionalist and Conformist
Theories. World Politics 21:513–38.
Hartz, Louis. 1955. The Liberal Tradition in America: An Interpretation of American Political Thought
Since the Revolution. New York: Harcourt, Brace, and World.
Hasenclever, Andreas, Peter Mayer, and Volker Rittberger. 1996. Interests, Power, Knowledge: The Study
of International Regimes. Mershon International Studies Review 40:177–228.
———. 1997. Theories of International Regimes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Haskel, Barbara. 1980. Access to Society: A Neglected Dimension of Power. International Organization
34:89–120.
Hassner, Pierre. 1997. Violence and Peace: From the Atomic Bomb to Ethnic Cleansing. Translated by
Jane Brenton. Budapest and New York: Central European University Press.
Havel, Vaclav. 1994. A Call for Sacri ce. Foreign Affairs 73:2–7.
Hawtrey, Ralph G. 1930. Economic Aspects of Sovereignty. London: Longman, Greens and Company.
Hayward, J. E. S. 1983. Governing France: The One and Indivisible Republic. 2d ed. London: Weidenfeld
and Nicolson.
———. 1991. Cultural and Contextual Constraints upon the Development of Political Science in Great
Britain. In The Development of Political Science: A Comparative Survey, edited by David Easton, John
G. Gunnell and Luigi Graziano, 93–107. London and New York: Routledge.
Hechter, M., and S. Kanazawa. 1997. Sociological Rational Choice Theory. Annual Review of Sociology
23:191–214.
Heilbron, Johan. 1991. The Tripartite Division of French Social Science: A Long-Term Perspective. In
Sociology of the Sciences—A Yearbook. Vol. 15, Discourses on Society: The Shaping of the Social
Sciences, edited by P. Wagner, B. Wittrock, and R. Whitley, 73–92. Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Heldt, B., ed. 1992. States in Armed Con ict 1990–1991. Report No. 35. Uppsala: Uppsala University,
Department of Peace and Con ict Research.
Hellmann, Gunther. 1994. Für eine problemorientierte Grundlagenforschung:Kritik und Perspektiven der
Disziplin ‘‘Internationale Beziehungen’’ in Deutschland. Zeitschrift für Internationale Beziehungen
1:65–90.
Henkin, Louis. 1965. The United Nations and Human Rights. International Organization 19:504–17.
Herman, Robert G. 1996. Identity, Norms, and National Security: The Soviet Foreign Policy Revolution
and the End of the Cold War. In The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics,
edited by Peter J. Katzenstein, 271–316. New York: Columbia University Press.
Hermann, Charles. 1968. The Comparative Study of Foreign Policy. World Politics 20:521–34.
Herz, John. 1951. Political Realism and Political Idealism: A Study in Theories and Realities. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Hill, Christopher. 1987. The Study of International Relations in the United Kingdom. Millennium: Journal
of International Studies 16:301–308.
Hill, Christopher, and W. Wallace. 1996. Introduction: Actors and Actions. In The Actors in Europe’s
Foreign Policy, edited by Christopher Hill, 1–16. London: Routledge.
Hilsman, Roger. 1958. Congressional-Executive Relations and the Foreign Policy Consensus. American
Political Science Review 52:725–44.
Hines, James R. 1997. Altered States: Taxes and the Location of Foreign Direct Investment in America.
American Economic Review 86:1076–94.
Hirschman, Albert O. 1977. The Passion and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism Before Its
Triumph. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
References 1031
———. [1945] 1980. National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade. Reprint, Berkeley: University
of California Press.
———. 1981. Essays in Trespassing. New York: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1982. Shifting Involvements. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Hirst, Paul, and Grahame Thompson. 1996. Globalization in Question. Cambridge: Polity.
Hix, Simon. 1998. The Study of the European Union II; The ‘‘New Governance’’Argument and Its Rivals.
European Journal of Public Policy 5:386–402.
Hoffman, Mark. 1987. Critical Theory and the Inter-Paradigm Debate. Millennium: Journal of Interna-
tional Studies. 16:231–49.
Hoffmann, Stanley. 1956. The Role of International Organization: Limits and Possibilities. International
Organization 10:357–72.
———. 1959. International Relations: The Long Road to Theory. World Politics 11:346–77.
———. 1960. Contemporary Theory in International Relations. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
———. 1966. Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe.
Daedalus 95:862–915.
———. 1968. Gulliver’s Troubles or the Setting of American Foreign Policy. New York: McGraw-Hill.
———. 1977. An American Social Science: International Relations. Daedalus 106:41–60.
———. 1978. Primacy or World Order—American Foreign Policy Since the Cold War. New York: Mc-
Graw Hill.
———. 1986. Hedley Bull and His Contribution to International Relations. International Affairs (Lon-
don) 62:179–96.
———. 1987. Raymond Aron and the Theory of International Relations. In Janus and Minerva: Essays in
the Theory and Practice of International Politics, by Stanley Hoffman, 52–69. Boulder, Colo.: West-
view Press.
———. 1997. The United States and Western Europe. In Eagle Adrift: American Foreign Policy at the
End of the Century, edited by Robert Lieber, 178–92. New York: Longman.
Hoffmann, Stanley, ed. 1960. Contemporary Theory in International Relations. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
Prentice-Hall.
Hogarth, R., and M. Reder, eds. 1986. The Behavioral Foundation of Economic Theory. The Journal of
Business 59 (supplement).
Hollis, Martin, and Steve Smith. 1986. Roles and Reasons in Foreign Policy Decision Making. British
Journal of Political Science 16:269–86.
———. 1990. Explaining and Understanding International Relations. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
———. 1991. Beware of Gurus: Structure and Action in International Relations. Review of International
Studies 17:393–410.
Holsti, Kalevi J. 1985. The Dividing Discipline: Hegemony and Diversity in International Theory. Boston:
Allen and Unwin.
———. 1986. The Horsemen of the Apocalypse: At the Gate, Detoured, or Retreating? International
Studies Quarterly 30:355–72.
———. 1996. The State, War, and the State of War. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Holsti, Ole. 1970. Crisis, Escalation and War. Montreal: McGill University Press.
Hoole, Francis W. 1977. Evaluating the Impact of International Organizations. International Organization
31:541–63.
Hopf, Ted. 1998. The Promise of Constructivism in International Relations Theory. International Security
22:171–200.
Hopkins, Raymond F., and Donald J. Puchala. 1978. Perspectives on the International Relations of Food.
International Organization 32:581–616.
Hosli, Madeleine O. 1993.Admission of European Free Trade Association States to the European Commu-
nity: Effects on Voting Power in the European Community Council of Ministers. International Organi-
zation 47:629–43.
Hovet, Thomas, Jr. 1958. Bloc Votes in the United Nations. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Huber, John D. 1992. Restrictive Legislative Procedures in France and the United States. American Po-
litical Science Review 86:675–87.
1032 International Organization
———. 1996a. The Vote of Con dence In Parliamentary Democracies. American Political Science Re-
view 90:269–82.
———. 1996b. Rationalizing Parliament: Legislative Institutions and Party Politics in France. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Huntington, Samuel P. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, Conn., and London:Yale
University Press.
———. 1973. Transnational Organizations in World Politics. World Politics 25:333–68.
———. 1996. The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of the World Order. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Huysmans, Jef. 1998. Revisiting Copenhagen or On the Creative Development of a Security Studies
Agenda in Europe. European Journal of International Relations 4.
Ikenberry, G. John. 1992.A World Economy Restored: Expert Consensus and the Anglo-American Postwar
Settlement. International Organization 46:289–321.
———. 1993a. Creating Yesterday’s New World Order: Keynesian ‘‘New Thinking’’ and the Anglo-
American Postwar Settlement. In Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change,
edited by Judith Goldstein and Robert O. Keohane, 57–86. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1993b. The Political Origins of Bretton Woods. In A Retrospective on the Bretton Woods System,
edited by Michael D. Bordo and Barry Eichengreen, 155–200. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Ikenberry, G. John, and Charles Kupchan. 1990. Socialization and Hegemonic Power. International Orga-
nization 44:283–315.
Ikenberry, G. John, David Lake, and Michael Mastanduno, eds. 1988. The State and American Foreign
Economic Policy. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
IMF, Various years. Balance-of Payments Statistics. Washington, D.C.: IMF.
———. 1983. Exchange Rate Volatility and World Trade. Unpublished manuscript, International Mon-
etary Fund, Washington, D.C.
———. 1991. Determinants and Systematic Consequences of International Capital Flows. Washington,
D.C.: International Monetary Fund.
Inglehart, Ronald. 1997. Modernization and Postmodernization:Cultural, Economic, and Political Change
in 43 Societies. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Irwin, Douglas, and Randall Krozner. 1996. Log-rolling and Economic Interests in the Passage of the
Smoot-Hawley Tariff. NBER Working Paper 5510. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Isaacson, Walter. 1992. Kissinger: A Biography. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Iversen, Torben. 1996. Power, Flexibility and the Breakdown of Centralized Wage Bargaining. Compara-
tive Politics 28:399–436.
Jachtenfuchs, Markus, and Beate Kohler-Koch, eds. 1996. Europäische Integration. Opladen, Germany:
Leske und Budrich.
Jackson, Robert H. 1990. Quasi-States: Sovereignty, International Relations, and the Third World. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1993. The Weight of Ideas in Decolonization: Normative Change in International Relations. In
Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change, edited by Judith Goldstein and
Robert O. Keohane, 111–38. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Jacobson, Harold. 1962. The United Nations and Colonialism: A Tentative Appraisal. International Orga-
nization 16:37–56.
———. 1967. Deriving Data from Delegates to International Assemblies. International Organization
21:592–613.
James, Allan, ed. 1973. The Bases of International Order. London: Oxford University Press.
Janis, Irving L. 1982. Groupthink: Psychological Studies of Policy Decisions and Fiascoes. 2d ed. Boston:
Houghton Mifflin.
———. 1983. Groupthink: Psychological Studies of Policy Decisions and Fiascoes. 2d ed., rev. Boston:
Houghton Mifflin.
Jebb, Sir Gladwyn. 1952. The Role of the United Nations. International Organization 6:509–20.
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency
Costs, and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3:305–60.
References 1033
Jentleson, Bruce. 1986. Pipeline Politics: The Complex Political Economy of East-West Energy Trade.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Jepperson, Ronald L. 1991. Institutions, Institutional Effects, and Institutionalism. In The New Institution-
alism in Organizational Analysis, edited by Walter W. Powell and Paul J. DiMaggio, 143–63. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Jepperson, Ronald L., Alexander Wendt, and Peter J. Katzenstein. 1996. Norms, Identity, and Culture of
National Security. In The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by
Peter J. Katzenstein, 33–75. New York: Columbia University Press.
Jervis, Robert. 1976. Perception and Misperception in International Politics. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
———. 1978. Cooperation Under the Security Dilemma. World Politics 30:167–214.
———. 1988. War and Misperception. In The Origin and Prevention of Major Wars, edited by Robert I.
Rotberg and Theodore K. Rabb, 101–26. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. [1970] 1989a. The Logic of Images in International Relations. Reprint, New York: Columbia
University Press.
———. 1989b. Rational Deterrence: Theory and Evidence. World Politics 41:183–207.
———. 1989c. The Meaning of the Nuclear Revolution: Statecraft and the Prospect of Armageddon.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1991. The Future of World Politics: Will It Resemble the Past. International Security 16:39–73.
———. 1992a. A Political Science Perspective on the Balance of Power and the Concert. American
Historical Review 97:716–24.
———. 1992b. Political Implications of Loss Aversion. Political Psychology 13:187–204.
———. 1993. International Primacy. Is the Game Worth the Candle? International Security 17:52–67.
Joerges, C., K-H. Ladeur, and E. Vos, eds. 1997. Integrating Scienti c Expertise into Regulatory Decision-
Making. National Traditions and European Innovations. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Johnson, Chalmers, and E. B. Keehn. 1995. The Pentagon’s Ossi ed Strategy. Foreign Affairs 74:103–14.
Johnson, Howard C., and Gerhart Niemeyer. 1954. Collective Security: The Validity of an Ideal. Interna-
tional Organization 8:19–35.
Johnson, Robert H. 1994. Improbable Dangers: U.S. Conceptions of Threat in the Cold War and After.
New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Johnston, Alastair I. 1995a. Cultural Realism: Strategic Culture and Grand Strategy in Chinese History.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1995b. Thinking about Strategic Culture. International Security 19:32–64.
———. 1996. Cultural Realism and Strategy in Maoist China. In The Culture of National Security: Norms
and Identity in World Politics, edited by Peter J. Katzenstein, 216–68. New York: Columbia University
Press.
Jones, R. J. Barry. 1995. Globalisation and Interdependence in the International Political Economy:
Rhetoric and Reality. London: Pinter Publishers.
Jones, Stephen R. G. 1984. The Economics of Conformism. Oxford: Blackwell.
Jönsson, Christer. 1993. International Politics: Scandinavian Identity Amidst American Hegemony? Scan-
dinavian Political Studies 16:149–65.
Kagan, Korina. 1997. The Myth of the European Concert: The Realist-Institutionalist Debate and Great
Power Behavior in the Eastern Question, 1821–41. Security Studies 7:1–57.
Kahler, Miles. 1993. International Relations: Still an American Social Science? In Ideas and Ideals:
Essays on Politics in Honor of Stanley Hoffmann, edited by Linda B. Miller and Michael Joseph Smith,
395–414. Boulder, Colo: Westview.
———. 1997. Inventing International Relations: International Relations Theory Since 1945. In New
Thinking in International Relations Theory, edited by Michael W. Doyle and G. John Ikenberry, 20–53.
Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
Kaiser, David E. 1980. Economic Diplomacy and the Origins of the Second World War. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Kaldor, Mary. 1978. The Disintegrating West. New York: Hill and Wang.
1034 International Organization
Kaplan, Morton A. 1957. System and Process in International Politics. New York: Wiley.
Kapstein, Ethan B.. 1990. The Insecure Alliance: Energy Crises and Western Politics Since 1944. New
York: Oxford University Press.
———. 1992. The Political Economy of National Security. New York: McGraw Hill.
———. 1996. Workers and the World Economy. Foreign Affairs 75:16–37.
Kapstein, Ethan, and Michael Mastanduno, eds. Forthcoming. Unipolar Politics: Realism and State Strat-
egies After the Cold War. New York: Columbia University Press.
Karns, David A. 1977. The Effect of Interparliamentary Meetings on the Foreign Policy Attitudes of
United States Congressmen. International Organization 31:515–39.
Kastendiek, Hans. 1991. Political Development and Political Science in West Germany. In The Develop-
ment of Political Science: A Comparative Survey, edited by David Easton, John G. Gunnell, and Luigi
Graziano. 108–26. London and New York: Routledge.
Katzenstein, Peter J. 1975. International Interdependence: Some Long-Term Trends and Recent Changes.
International Organization 29:1021–34.
———. 1976. International Relations and Domestic Structures: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced
Industrial States. International Organization 30:1–45.
———. 1984. Corporatism and Change: Austria, Switzerland, and the Politics of Industry. Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press.
———. 1985. Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell Univer-
sity Press.
———. 1993. Japan’s National Security: Structures, Norms, and Policy Responses in a Changing World.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1996a. Cultural Norms and National Security: Police and Military in Postwar Japan. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1996b. Introduction: Alternative Perspectives on National Security. In The Culture of National
Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by Peter J. Katzenstein, 1–32. New York: Co-
lumbia University Press.
Katzenstein, Peter J., ed. 1978. Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced
Industrial States. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.
———. 1996c. The Culture of National Security. Norms and Identity in World Politics. New York: Co-
lumbia University Press.
———. 1997. Tamed Power: Germany in Europe. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Kay, David. 1967. The Politics of Decolonization: The New Nations and the United Nations Political
Process. International Organization 21:786–811.
Kaysen, C. 1990. Is War Obsolete? A Review Essay. International Security 14:42–64.
Keck, Margaret, and Kathryn Sikkink. 1998. Activists Beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in Interna-
tional Politics. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Keck, Otto. 1995. Rationales Kommunikatives Handeln in den Internationalen Beziehungen: Ist eine
Verbindung von Rational-Choice-Theorie und Habermas’ Theorie des Kommunikativen Handelns Mö-
glich? Zeitschrift Für Internationale Beziehungen 1:5–48.
Keeley, James F. 1990. Toward a Foucauldian Analysis of International Regimes. International Organiza-
tion 44:83–105.
Kelman, Herbert C. 1962. Changing Attitudes Through International Activities. Journal of Social Issues
18:67–87.
Kennan, George F. 1967. Memoirs: 1925–1950. Boston: Little, Brown.
———. 1968. From Prague After Munich: Diplomatic Papers, 1938–1940. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Kennedy, Paul. 1983. Strategy and Diplomacy, 1870–1945. London:Allen and Unwin.
———. 1987. The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Con ict from 1500
to 2000. New York: Random House.
Keohane, Nannerl. 1980. Philosophy and the State in France: The Renaissance to the Enlightenment.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
References 1035
Keohane, Robert O. 1967. The Study of Political In uence in the General Assembly. International Orga-
nization 21:221–37.
———. 1969. Who Cares About the General Assembly? International Organization 23:141–49.
———. 1978. The International Energy Agency: State In uence and Transgovernmental Politics. Interna-
tional Organization 32:929–51.
———. 1980. The Theory of Hegemonic Stability and Changes in International Economic Regimes,
1967–1977. In Change in the International System, edited by Ole Holsti, Randolph M. Siverson, and
Alexander L. George, 131–62. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
———. 1982. The Demand for International Regimes. International Organization 36:325–56.
———. 1983a. The Demand For International Regimes. In International Regimes, edited by Stephen D.
Krasner, 141–71. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1983b. Theory of World Politics: Structural Realism and Beyond. In Political Science: The State
of the Discipline, edited by Ada W. Finifter, 503–40. Washington, D.C.: American Political Science
Association.
———. 1984. After Hegemony. Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1986a. Realism, Neorealism, and the Study of World Politics. In Neorealism and Its Critics,
edited by Robert O. Keohane, 1–26. New York: Columbia University Press.
———. 1986b. Theory of World Politics: Structural Realism and Beyond. In Neorealism and Its Critics,
edited by Robert O. Keohane, 158–203. New York: Columbia University Press.
———. 1988. International Institutions: Two Approaches. International Studies Quarterly 32:379–96.
———. 1989a. Neoliberal Institutionalism: A Perspective on World Politics. In International Institutions
and State Power: Essays in InternationalRelations Theory, edited by Robert O. Keohane, 1–20. Boulder,
Colo.: Westview Press.
———. 1990a. Empathy and International Regimes. In Beyond Self-Interest, edited by Jane Mansbridge,
227–36. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
———. 1990b. International Liberalism Reconsidered. In The Economic Limits to Modern Politics, ed-
ited by John Dunn. New York: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1993. Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge After the Cold War. In Neorealism and
Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate, edited by David A. Baldwin, 269–300. New York: Co-
lumbia University Press.
———. 1996a. International Relations, Old and New. In A New Handbook of Political Science, edited by
Robert E. Goodin and Hans-Dieter Klingemann, 462–76. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
———. 1996b. Remarks at the Annual Convention.American Political Science Association.
———. 1997. Problematic Lucidity: Stephen Krasner’s ‘‘State Power and the Structure of International
Trade.’’ World Politics 50:150–70.
Keohane, Robert O., and Lisa Martin. 1995. The Promise of Institutionalist Theory. International Security
20:39–51.
Keohane, Robert O., and Joseph S. Nye, Jr. 1971. Transnational Relations and World Politics: An Introduc-
tion. International Organization 25:329–52.
———. 1974. Transgovernmental Relations and International Organizations. World Politics 27:39–62.
———. 1977. Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition. Boston: Little, Brown.
Keohane, Robert O., ed. 1989b. International Institutions and State Power. Essays in International Rela-
tions Theory. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
Keohane, Robert O., and Stanley Hoffmann, eds. 1991. The New European Community. Boulder, Colo.:
Westview Press.
Keohane, Robert O., and Helen Milner, eds. 1996. Internationalization and Domestic Politics. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Keohane, Robert O., and Joseph S. Nye, Jr., eds. 1972. Transnational Relations and World Politics.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Keohane, Robert O., Joseph S. Nye, Jr., and Stanley Hoffmann, eds. 1993. After the Cold War: Interna-
tional Institutions and State Strategies in Europe, 1989–1991. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press.
1036 International Organization
Kerr, Henry H., Jr. 1973. Changing Attitudes Through International Participation: European Parliamentar-
ians and Integration. International Organization 27:45–83.
Keynes, John Maynard. 1920. The Economic Consequences of the Peace. New York: Harcourt, Brace,
Howe.
Khong, Yuen Foong. 1992. Analogies at War. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Kier, Elizabeth. 1995. Culture and Military Doctrine: France Between the Wars. International Security
19:65–93.
———. 1996. Culture and French Military Doctrine Before World War II. In The Culture of National
Security Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by Peter J. Katzenstein, 186–215. New York:
Columbia University Press.
———. 1997. Imagining War: French and British Military Doctrine Between the Wars. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Kiewiet, D. Roderick, and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1991. The Logic of Delegation. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Kim, Soo Yeon. 1998. Ties That Bind: The Role of Trade in International Con ict Processes, 1950–1992.
Ph.D. diss., Department of Political Science, Yale University, New Haven, Conn.
Kim, Woosang, and Bruce Bueno de Mesquita. 1995. How Perceptions In uence the Risk of War. Interna-
tional Studies Quarterly 39:51–66.
Kindleberger, Charles P. 1951a. Bretton Woods Reappraised. International Organization 5:32–47.
———. 1951b. Group Behavior and International Trade. Journal of Political Economy 59:30–46.
———. 1962. Foreign Trade and the National Economy. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
———. 1969. American Business Abroad:Six Lectures on Direct Investment. New Haven, Conn.: Yale
University Press.
———. 1973. The World in Depression, 1929–1939. Berkeley: University of California Press.
———. 1978. Economic Response: Comparative Studies in Trade, Finance, and Growth. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press.
King, Garry, Robert O. Keohane, and Sidney Verba. 1994. Designing Social Inquiry. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Kirshner, Jonathan. 1995. Currency and Coercion: The Political Economy of International Monetary
Power. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1998. Political Economy in Security Studies After the Cold War. Review of International Political
Economy 5:64–91.
Kissinger, Henry A. 1957a. A World Restored: Castlereagh, Metternich, and the Restoration of Peace,
1812–1822. Boston and London: Scott, Foresman.
———. 1957b. Nuclear Weapons and Foreign Policy. New York: Harper and Row.
———. 1965. The Troubled Partnership. New York: McGraw-Hill.
———. 1969. American Foreign Policy: Three Essays. New York: Norton.
———. 1994. Diplomacy. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Klotz, Audie. 1995a. Norms Reconstituting Interests: Global Racial Equality and U.S. Sanction Against
South Africa. International Organization 49:451–78.
———. 1995b. Norms in International Relations: The Struggle Against Apartheid. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell
University Press.
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Con ict. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Knorr, Klaus. 1948. The Bretton Woods Institutions in Transition. International Organization 2:19–38.
———. 1956. The War Potential of Nations. Princeton, N.J.:Princeton University Press.
———. 1975. The Power of Nations: The Political Economy of International Relations. New York: Basic
Books.
Knorr, Klaus, and James Rosenau. 1961. The International System. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press.
Knorr, Klaus, and Frank N. Trager. 1977. Economic Issues and National Security. Lawrence: University
of Kansas Press.
References 1037
Krehbiel, Keith. 1991. Information and Legislative Organization. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan
Press.
Kreps, David M. 1990a. Corporate Culture and Economic Theory. In Perspectives on Positive Political
Economy, edited by James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle, 90–143. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
———. 1990b. Game Theory and Economic Modeling. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Krugman, Paul R. 1996. Pop Internationalism. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Krugman, Paul R., ed. 1986. Strategic Trade Policy and the New International Economics. Cambridge,
Mass.: MIT Press.
Kuhn, Thomas. 1962. The Structure of Scienti c Revolutions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Kupchan, Charles A. 1994. The Vulnerability of Empire. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Kurth, James. 1979. The Political Consequences of the Product Cycle: Industrial History and Political
Outcomes. International Organization 33:1–34.
Kurzer, Paulette. 1993. Business and Banking. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Kydd, Andrew. 1997. Why Security Seekers Do Not Fight Each Other. Security Studies 7:114–55.
Labs, Eric. 1997. Beyond Victory: Offensive Realism and the Expansion of War Aims. Security Studies
6:1–49.
Ladeur, K-H. 1997. Towards a Legal Theory of Supranationality—The Viability of the Network Concept.
European Law Journal 3:33–54.
LaFeber, Walter. 1997. The Clash: A History of U.S.–Japan Relations. New York: Norton.
Laffan, B. 1997a. The IGC as Constitution-building—What’s New at Amsterdam. Unpublished manu-
script, University College Dublin, Dublin, Ireland.
———. 1997b. The European Union: A Distinctive Model of Internationalization? European Integration
Online Papers 1(018):http://eiop.or.at/eiop.texte/1997018a.htm
Laitin, David D. 1995. Identity in Formation: The Russian-Speaking Nationality in the Post-Soviet Dias-
pora. Archives Europeenes de Sociologie 36:281–316.
Lakatos, Imre. 1970. Falsi cation and the Methodology of Scienti c Research Programmes. In Criticism
and the Growth of Knowledge, edited by Imre Lakatos and Alan Musgrave, 91–195. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Lake, David A. 1984. Beneath the Commerce of Nations: A Theory of International Economic Structures.
International Studies Quarterly 28:143–70.
———. 1988. Power, Protection, and Free Trade: International Sources of U.S. Commercial Policy,
1887–1939. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1993. Leadership, Hegemony, and the International Economy: Naked Emperor or Tattered Mon-
arch with Potential? International Studies Quarterly 37:459–89.
———. 1996. Anarchy, Hierarchy, and the Variety of International Relations. International Organization
50:1–33.
———. Forthcoming. Entangling Relations: American Foreign Policy in Its Century. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Lakoff, George. 1996. Moral Politics: What Conservatives Know that Liberals Don’t. Chicago: Chicago
University Press.
Landes, David S. 1969. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in
Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lange, Peter, and Geoffrey Garrett. 1985. The Politics of Growth. Journal of Politics 47:792–827.
Lange, Peter, and Lyle Scruggs. 1997. Where Have All the Members Gone? Paper presented at the 93d
Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, August, Washington, D.C.
Lange, Peter, Michael Wallerstein, and Miriam Golden. 1995. The End of Corporatism? Wage Setting in
the Nordic and Germanic Countries. In The Workers of Nations, edited by Sanford Jacoby, 76–100.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Lapid, Yosef. 1996. Culture’s Ship: Returns and Departures in International Relations Theory. In The
Return of Culture and Identity in IR Theory, edited by Yosef Lapid and Friedrich V. Kratochwil, 3–20.
Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner.
References 1039
Lapid, Yosef, and Friedrich V. Kratochwil. 1996. Revisiting the ‘‘National’’: Toward an Identity Agenda in
Neorealism? In The Return of Culture and Identity in IR Theory, edited by Yosef Lapid and Friedrich V.
Kratochwil, 105–26. Boulder, Colo: Lynne Rienner.
Lasswell, Harold. 1930. Psychopathology and Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Laver, Michael, and Kenneth Shepsle. 1995. Making and Breaking Governments. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Layne, Christopher. 1993. The Unipolar Illusion: Why New Great Powers Will Rise. International Secu-
rity 17:5–51.
———. 1997. From Preponderance to Offshore Balancing: America’s Future Grand Strategy. Interna-
tional Security 22:86–124.
Le Gloannec, Anne-Marie, ed. 1998. Entre Union et Nations: L’État en Europe. Paris: Presses de la
Fondation Nationale des Sciences Politiques.
Le Goff, Jacques. 1980. Time, Work, and Culture in the Middle Ages. Translated by Arthur Goldhammer.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Leamer, Edward E. 1996. Wage Inequality from International Competition and Technological Change:
Theory and Country Experience. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings) 86:309–14.
Leander, Anna. 1997. Bertrand Badie: Cultural Diversity Changing International Relations? In The Future
of International Relations: Masters in the Making?, edited by Iver B. Neumann and Ole Wæver,
145–69. London: Routledge.
Lebow, Richard Ned. 1994. The Long Peace, the End of the Cold War, and the Failure of Realism.
International Organization 48:249–77.
Lebow, Richard Ned, and Thomas Risse-Kappen. 1995. Introduction: International Relations Theory and
the End of the Cold War. In International Relations Theory and the End of the Cold War, edited by
Richard Ned Lebow and Thomas Risse-Kappen. New York: Columbia University Press.
Leffler, Melvyn P. 1992. A Preponderance of Power: National Security, the Truman Administration, and
the Cold War. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
Legro, Jeffrey W. 1995. Cooperation Under Fire: Anglo-German Restraint During World War II. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1997. Which Norms Matter? Revisiting the Failure of Internationalism. International Organiza-
tion 51:31–63.
Leibowitz, S. J., and Stephen Margolis. 1990. The Fable of the Keys. Journal of Law and Economics
33:1–25.
Leites, Nathan. 1953. A Study of Bolshevism. Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press.
Lenin, V. I. 1916. Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism. New York: International Publishers.
Leonard, Robert J. 1991. War as a ‘‘Simple Economic Problem’’: The Rise of an Economics of Defense. In
Economics and National Security: A History of Their Interaction, edited by Craufurd D. Goodwin,
261–83. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press.
Lessig, Lawrence. 1995. The Regulation of Social Meaning, University of Chicago Law Review 62:
968–73.
Levinthal, D. A., and James G. March. 1993. The Myopia of Learning. Strategic Management Journal
14:95–112.
Levitt, B., and James G. March. 1988. Organizational Learning. Annual Review of Sociology 14:319–40.
Levy, Brian, and Pablo Spiller. 1996. Regulations, Institutions, and Commitment. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Levy, Jack S. 1992. An Introduction to Prospect Theory. Political Psychology 13:171–86.
———. 1997. Prospect Theory, Rational Choice, and International Relations. International Studies Quar-
terly 41:87–112.
Levy, Marc A. 1993. European Acid Rain: The Power of Tote-Board Diplomacy. In Institutions for the
Earth: Sources of Effective International Environmental Protection, edited by Peter M. Haas, Robert
O. Keohane, and Marc A. Levy, 75–132. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
1040 International Organization
Levy, Marc A., Oran R. Young, and Michael Zürn. 1995. The Study of International Regimes. European
Journal of International Relations 1:267–330.
Liberman, Peter. 1996. Trading with the Enemy: Security and Relative Economic Gains. International
Security 21:147–75.
Lindberg, Leon N., and Stuart A. Scheingold. 1970. Europe’s Would-Be Polity: Patterns of Change in the
European Community. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
———. 1971. Regional Integration: Theory and Research. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Lindberg, Leon N., and Charles Maier, eds. 1985. The Politics of In ation and Economic Stagnation.
Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Linz, Juan. 1978. The Breakdown of Democratic Regimes: Crisis, Breakdown, and Reequilibration. Balti-
more, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1990. Continental Divide. New York: Routledge.
———. 1996. American Exceptionalism: A Double-Edged Sword. New York: Norton.
Lipsey, Robert E. 1998. Internationalized Production in Developed and Developing Countries and in
Industry Sectors. NBER Working Paper 6405. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Re-
search.
Lipson, Charles. 1984. International Cooperation in Economic and Security Affairs. World Politics 37:
1–23.
———. 1991. Why Are Some International Agreements Informal? International Organization 45:495–
538.
Liska, George. 1957. International Equilibrium. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Lit n, Karen. 1994. Ozone Discourses. New York: Columbia University Press.
Little, Richard. 1995. Neorealism and the English School: A Methodological, Ontological, and Theo-
retical Reassessment. European Journal of International Relations 1:14–27.
Little, Virginia. 1949. Control of International Air Transport. International Organization 3:29–40.
Lohmann, Susanne. 1998. Federalism and Central Bank Autonomy: The Politics of German Monetary
Policy, 1957–1992. World Politics 50:401–46.
Lohmann, Susanne, and Sharyn O’Halloran. 1994. Divided Government and U.S. Trade Policy: Theory
and Evidence. International Organization 48:595–632.
Loveday, A. 1953. Suggestions for the Reform of the United Nations Economic and Social Machinery.
International Organization 7:325–41.
Lowi, Theodore J. 1992. The State in Political Science: How We Become What We Study. American
Political Science Review 86:1–7.
———. 1993a. A Review of Herbert Simon’s Review of My View of the Discipline. PS: Political Science
and Politics 26:51–52.
———. 1993b. Response to Critiques of Presidential Address. PS: Political Science and Politics 26:539.
Lucas, Robert E. 1972. Expectations and the Neutrality of Money. Journal of Economic Theory 4:103–24.
Luhmann, N. 1982. The Differentiation of Society. New York: Columbia University Press.
Lumsdaine, David Halloran. 1993. Moral Vision: The Foreign Aid Regime, 1949–1989. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
———. 1994. The Centrality of Worldviews and Normative Ideas in Twentieth Century International
Politics. Paper delivered at the 90th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association,
August, New York.
Lupia, Arthur, and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1994. Who Controls? Information and the Structure of Legis-
lative Decision Making. Legislative Studies Quarterly 19:361–84.
Lynn-Jones, Sean, and Joseph S. Nye, Jr. 1988. International Security Studies: A Report of a Conference
on the State of the Field. International Security 12:5–27.
Lyons, Gene M. 1982. Expanding the Study of International Relations: The French Connection. World
Politics 35:135–49.
———. 1986. The Study of International Relations in Great Britain: Further Connections. World Politics
38:626–45.
References 1041
Machina, Mark J. 1987. Choice Under Uncertainty: Problems Solved and Unsolved. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 1:121–54.
MacRae, Duncan. 1958. Dimensions of Congressional Voting. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of
California Press.
Maddison, Angus. 1995. Monitoring the World Economy. Paris: OECD.
Magdoff, Harry. 1969. The Age of Imperialism. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Maier, Charles. 1997. Dissolution: The Crisis of Communism and the End of East Germany. Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Majone, Giandomenico. 1996. A European Regulatory State? In European Union: Power and Policy-
making, edited by Jeremy J. Richardson, 262–77. London and New York: Routledge.
Malin, Patrick Murphy. 1947. The Refugee: A Problem for International Organization. International Orga-
nization 1:443–459.
Mandel, Ernest. 1976. Late Capitalism. London: New Left Books.
Mandelbaum, Michael. 1981. The Nuclear Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Manicas, Peter T. 1991. The Social Science Disciplines: The American Model. In Sociology of the Sci-
ences—A Yearbook. Vol. 15, Discourses on Society: The Shaping of the Social Sciences, edited by
P. Wagner, B. Wittrock and R. Whitley, 45–72. Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Mann, M. 1993. Nation-States in Europe and Other Continents: Diversifying, Developing, Not Dying.
Daedalus 122:115–40.
Mansbach, Richard W., and John A. Vasquez. 1981. In Search of Theory—A New Paradigm for Global
Politics. New York: Columbia University Press.
Mansbridge, Jane J. 1990. The Rise and Fall of Self-Interest in the Explanation of Political Life. In Beyond
Self Interest, edited by Jane J. Mansbridge, 3–22. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
March, James G. 1955. An Introduction to the Theory and Measurement of In uence. American Political
Science Review 49:431–51.
———. 1970. Politics and the City. In Urban Processes as Viewed by the Social Sciences, edited by K.
Arrow, J. S. Coleman, A. Downs, and James G. March, 23–37. Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute
Press.
———. 1978. Bounded Rationality, Ambiguity, and the Engineering of Choice. Bell Journal of Eco-
nomics 9:587–608.
———. 1981. Footnotes to Organizational Change. Administrative Science Quarterly 26:563–77.
———. 1988. Decisions and Organizations. Oxford: Blackwell.
———. 1991. Exploration and Exploitation in Organizational Learning. Organizational Science 2:71–-87.
———. 1992. The War Is Over and the Victors Have Lost. Journal of Socio-Economics 21:261–67.
———. 1994a. A Primer on Decision Making. New York: Free Press.
———. 1994b.The Evolution of Evolution.In Evolutionary Dynamics of Organizations, edited by J. Baum
and J. Singh, 39–49. New York: Oxford University Press.
———. 1996. Continuity and Change in Theories of Organizational Action. Administrative Science Quar-
terly 41:278–87.
March, James G., and Johan P. Olsen. 1984. The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political
Life. American Political Science Review 78:734–49.
———. 1989. Rediscovering Institutions: The Organizational Basis of Politics. New York: Free Press.
———. 1994. Institutional Perspectives on Governance. In Systemrationalität und Partialinteresse, ed-
ited by H. U. Derlien, U. Gerhardt, and F. W. Scharpf, 249–70. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
———. 1995. Democratic Governance. New York: Free Press.
———. 1996. Institutional Perspectives on Political Institutions. Governance 9:247–64.
Marin, B., and R. Mayntz, eds. 1991. Policy Networks. Frankfurt am Main: Campus.
Marks, Gary. 1993. Structural Policy and Multilevel Governance in the EC. In The State of the European
Community. Vol. 2, The Maastricht Debate and Beyond, edited by Alan W. Cafruny and Glenda G.
Rosenthal, 391–410. Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner and Harlow, England: Longman.
1042 International Organization
Marston, Richard. 1995. International Financial Integration. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Martin, Lisa L. 1992a. Coercive Cooperation: Explaining Multilateral Economic Sanctions. Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1992b. Interests, Power, and Multilateralism. International Organization 46:765–92.
———. 1992c. Institutions and Cooperation: Sanctions During the Falkland Islands Con ict. Interna-
tional Security 16:143–77.
———. 1997. Democratic Commitments: Legislatures and International Cooperation. Unpublished manu-
script, Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass.
Mason, Edward. 1949. American Security and Access to Raw Materials. World Politics 1:147–60.
Mastanduno, Michael. 1991. Do Relative Gains Matter? America’s Response to Japanese Industrial Policy.
International Security 16:73–113.
———. 1992. Economic Containment: CoCom and the Politics of East–West Trade. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell
University Press.
———. 1997. Preserving the Unipolar Moment: Realist Theories and U.S. Grand Strategy After the Cold
War. International Security 21:49–88.
Matecki, B. E. 1956. Establishment of the International Finance Corporation: A Case Study. International
Organization 10:261–75.
Mathiason, John R. 1972. Old Boys, Alumni, and Consensus at ECLA Meetings. In Communications in
International Politics, edited by Richard L. Merritt, 387–404. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.
Max eld, Sylvia. 1997. Gatekeepers of Growth. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Mayer, Peter, Volker Rittberger, and Michael Zürn. 1995. Regime Theory: State of the Art and Perspec-
tives. In Regime Theory and International Relations, edited by Volker Rittberger, with Peter Mayer,
392–430. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
McCloskey, Donald N. 1994. Knowledge and Persuasion in Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
McDermott, Rose. 1992. Prospect Theory in International Relations: The Iranian Hostage Rescue Mis-
sion. Political Psychology 13:237–63.
McKay, David. 1988. Why Is There a European Political Science. PS: Political Science and Politics
21:1051–55.
McKenzie, Richard, and Dwight R. Lee. 1991. Quicksilver Capital: How the Rapid Movement of Wealth
Has Changed the World. New York: Free Press.
McKeown, Timothy J. 1983. Hegemonic Stability Theory and 19th Century Tariff Levels in Europe.
International Organization 37:73–92.
———. 1993. Decision Processes and Co-operation in Foreign Policy. In Choosing to Cooperate, edited
by Louis Pauly and Janice Gross Stein, 202–19. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
McLin, Jon. 1979. Surrogate International Organization and the Case of World Food Security. Interna-
tional Organization 33:35–55.
McMillan, Susan M. 1997. Interdependence and Con ict. Mershon International Studies Review 41:
33–58.
McNamara, Kathleen R. 1992. Common Markets, Uncommon Currencies: System Effects and the Euro-
pean Community. In Coping with Complexity in the International System, edited by Robert Jervis and
Jack Snyder, 303–27. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
———. 1996. Consensus and Constraint: The Politics of Monetary Cooperation in Europe. Unpublished
manuscript, Princeton University, Princeton, N.J.
McNeely, Connie. 1995. Constructing the Nation State: International Organization and Prescriptive Ac-
tion. Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press.
McSweeney, Bill. 1996. Identity and Security: Buzan and the Copenhagen School. Review of Interna-
tional Studies 22:81–93.
Mearsheimer, John J. 1983. Conventional Deterrence. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1990. Back to the Future: Instability in Europe After the Cold War. International Security
15:5–56.
———. 1994. The False Promise of International Institutions. International Security 19:5–49.
Medlicott, W. M. 1952–1959. The Economic Blockade, 2 vols. London: HMSO.
References 1043
Meier-Walser, Reinhard. 1994. Neorealismus ist mehr als Waltz. Der Synoptische Realismus der Münchner
Ansatzes. Zeitschrift für Internationale Beziehungen 1:115–26.
Meinecke, Friedrich. [1924] 1976. Die Idee der Staatsräson in der neuren Geschichte. Werke Bd. 1.
Vienna and Munich: R. Oldenbourg.
Mendoza, Enrique, Giancarlo Milesi-Ferreti, and P. Asea. 1997. On the Effectiveness of Tax Policy in
Altering Long-Run Growth. Journal of Public Economics 66:99–126.
Mercer, Jonathan. 1995. Anarchy and Identity. International Organization 49:229–52.
Merle, Marcel. 1987. The Sociology of International Relations. Translated by Dorothy Parkin. Leamington
Spa, England: Berg.
Merritt, Richard L. 1966. Symbols of American Community 1735–1775. New Haven, Conn.: Yale Univer-
sity Press.
Merton, R. K. 1942. Science and Technology in a Democratic Order. Journal of Legal and Political
Sociology 1:115–26.
Meyer, John W. 1980. The World Polity and the Authority of the Nation-State. In Studies of the Modern
World-System, edited by A. Bergesen, 109–58. New York: Academic Press.
Meyer, John W., John Boli, and George M. Thomas. 1987. Ontology and Rationalization in the Western
Cultural Account. In Institutional Structure: Constituting State, Society, and Individual, edited by
George M. Thomas, John W. Meyer, Francsico Ramirez, and John Boli, 12–37. Newbury Park, Calif.:
Sage Publications.
Meyer, John W., John Boli, George M. Thomas, and Francisco O. Ramirez. 1997. World Society and the
Nation-State. American Journal of Sociology 103:144–81.
Meyer, John, and Michael T. Hannan, eds. 1979. National Development and the World-System: Educa-
tional, Economic, and Political Change, 1950–1970. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Meyers, Reinhard. 1990. Metatheoretische und methodologische Betrachtungen. In Theorie der Interna-
tionalen Beziehungen: Bestandsaufnahme und Forschungsperspektiven, edited by Volker Rittberger,
(Politiche Vierteljahresschrift, Sonderheft 21):48–68. Opladen, Germany: Westdeutscher Verlag.
Milgrom, Paul, Douglass North, and Barry Weingast. 1990. The Role of Institutions in the Revival of
Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Campagne Fairs. Economics and Politics 2:1–23.
Millar, Thomas B. 1962. The Commonwealth and the United Nations. International Organization 16:
736–57.
Miller-Adams, Michelle. 1997. The World Bank in the 1990s: Understanding Institutional Change. Ph.D.
diss., Columbia University, New York.
Milner, Helen V. 1987. Resisting the Protectionist Temptation: Industry and the Making of Trade Policy in
France and the United States During the 1970s. International Organization 41:639–66.
———. 1988. Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade. Prince-
ton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1990. The Political Economy of U.S. Trade Policy: A Study of the Super 301 Provision. In
Aggressive Unilateralism: America’s 301 Trade Policy and the World Trading System, edited by Jag-
dish Bhagwati and Hugh T. Patrick, 163–80. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
———. 1991. The Assumption of Anarchy in International Politics: A Critique. Review of International
Studies 17:67–85.
———. 1997. Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Milner, Helen V., and B. Peter Rosendorff. 1996. Trade Negotiations, Information, and Domestic Politics.
Economics and Politics 8:145–89.
———. 1997. Elections and International Cooperation. Journal of Con ict Resolution 41:117–46.
Milward, Alan. 1977. War, Economy, and Society, 1939–1945. Berkeley: University of California Press.
———. 1992. The European Rescue of the Nation-State. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Mirowski, Philip. 1991. When Games Grow Deadly Serious: The Military In uence on the Evolution of
Game Theory. In Economics and National Security: A History of Their Interaction, edited by Craufurd
D. Goodwin. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press.
Mitrany, David. 1925. The Problem of International Sanctions. London: Oxford University Press.
———. 1966. A Working Peace System. Chicago: Quadrangle Books.
1044 International Organization
Monroe, Kristen Renwick. 1995. Psychology and Rational Actor Theory. Political Psychology 16:1–21.
———. 1996. The Heart of Altruism: Perceptions of a Common Humanity. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Moore, Barrington, Jr. 1966. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the
Making of the Modern World. Boston: Beacon Press.
Moran, Theodore H. 1996. Grand Strategy: The Pursuit of Power and the Pursuit of Plenty. International
Organization 50:175–205.
Moravcsik, Andrew. 1991. Negotiating the Single European Act: National Interests and Conventional
Statecraft in the European Community. International Organization 45:19–56.
———. 1993. Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal Intergovernmentalist Ap-
proach. Journal of Common Market Studies 31:473–524.
———. 1995. Explaining International Human Rights Regimes: Liberal Theory and Western Europe.
European Journal of International Relations 1:157–89.
———. 1997. Taking Preferences Seriously: A Liberal Theory of International Politics. International
Organization 51:513–53.
———. 1998. The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Morgenthau, Hans J. 1946. Scienti c Man Versus Power Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
———. 1948. Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace. New York: Knopf.
———. 1962. The Trouble with Kennedy. Commentary 33:51–55.
———. 1978. Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, 5th ed. New York: Knopf.
———. 1985. Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace. 6th ed., revised by Kenneth
Thompson. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Morici, Peter. 1997. Barring Entry? China and the WTO. Current History 96:274–77.
Morrow, James D. 1994a. Game Theory for Political Scientists. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press.
———. 1994b. Modeling the Forms of International Cooperation: Distribution Versus Information. Inter-
national Organization 48:387–423.
Morse, Edward L. 1970. The Transformation of Foreign Policies: Modernization, Interdependence, and
Externalization. World Politics 22:371–92.
———. 1972. Transnational Economic Processes. In Transnational Relations and World Politics, edited
by Robert O. Keohane and Joseph S. Nye, Jr., 23–47. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
———. 1976. Modernization and the Transformation of International Relations. New York: Free Press.
Moses, Jonathan. 1994. Abdication from National Policy Autonomy: What’s Left to Leave? Politics and
Society 22:125–148.
Mowers, A. Glenn. 1964. The Official Pressure Group of the Council of Europe’s Consultative Assembly.
International Organization 18:292–306.
Mueller, John. 1989. Retreat from Doomsday: The Obsolescence of Major War. New York: Basic Books.
Müller, Harald. 1994. Internationale Beziehungen als Kommunikativen Handeln: Zur Kritik der Utilita-
rischen Handlungstheorien. Zeitschrift für Internationale Beziehungen 1:15–44.
———. 1995. Spielen Hilft Nicht Immer: Die Grenzen des Rational-Choice-Ansatzens Under der Platz
der Theorie Kommunikativen Handelns in der Analyse International Beziehungen. Zeitschrift für Inter-
nationale Beziehungen 2:371–91.
Mundell, Robert. 1962. A Theory of Optimal Currency Areas. American Economic Review 51:657–65.
Murphy, Craig. 1996. Seeing Women, Recognizing Gender, Recasting International Relations. Interna-
tional Organization 50:513–38.
Nadelmann, Ethan. 1990. Global Prohibition Regimes: The Evolution of Norms in International Society.
International Organization 44:479–526.
Nagel, Ernest. [1942] 1961. The Structure of Science. New York: Harcourt, Brace and World.
Nagel, Jack. 1975. The Descriptive Analysis of Power. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Nathan, James A., and James K. Oliver. 1987. Foreign Policy Making and the American Political System.
Boston: Little, Brown.
References 1045
National Research Council. 1995. Maximizing U.S. Interests in Science and Technology Relations with
Japan. Report of the Defense Task Force. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.
Nau, Henry R. 1990. The Myth of America’s Decline: Leading the World Economy into the 1990s. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
———. 1995. Trade and Security: U.S. Policy at Cross-Purposes. Washington, D.C.: AEI Press.
———. 1997. Power and Legitimacy: Combining Realist and Constructivist Perspectives. Unpublished
paper, George Washington University, Washington, D.C.
Nauta, L. 1992. Changing Conceptions of Citizenship. Praxis International 12:20–34.
Nelson, R. R., and S. G. Winter. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, Mass.:
Harvard University Press.
Nettl, J. P. 1968. The State as a Conceptual Variable. World Politics 20:559–92.
Neu eld, Mark. 1993. Interpretation and the ‘‘Science’’ of International Relations. Review of International
Studies 19:39–61.
Neumann, Iver B. 1997. Conclusion. In The Future of International Relations: Masters in the Making?,
edited by Iver B. Neumann and Ole Wæver, 359–70. London: Routledge.
Neumann, Iver B., and Jennifer M. Welsh. 1991. The ‘‘Other’’ in European Self-De nition:An Addendum
to the Literature on International Society. Review of International Studies 17:327–48.
Neumann, Iver B., and Ole Wæver, eds. 1997. The Future of International Relations: Masters in the
Making? London: Routledge.
Neustadt, Richard. 1960. Presidential Power. New York: Wiley.
Niemeyer, Gerhart. 1952. The Balance Sheet of the League Experiment. International Organization
6:537–58.
Ninkovich, Frank. 1994. Modernity and Power: A History of the Domino Theory in the Twentieth Century.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Nisbett, R. E., and L. Ross. 1980. Human Inference: Strategies and Shortcomings of Human Judgment.
Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall.
Niskanen, W. A. 1971. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago: Rand McNally.
Nordlinger, Eric A. 1995. Isolationism Recon gured: American Foreign Policy for a New Century. Prince-
ton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton.
———. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
North, Douglass C., and Robert Paul Thomas. 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic
History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C., and Barry Weingast. 1989. Constitutions and Credible Commitments. Journal of
Economic History 49:803–32.
Nowotny, Helga, and Klaus Taschwer. 1996. The Sociology of the Sciences. Vol. 1. Cheltenham, U.K.:
Edward Elgar.
Nye, Joseph S., Jr. 1971. Peace in Parts: Integration and Con ict in Regional Organization. Boston:
Little, Brown.
———. 1990. Bound to Lead: The Changing Nature of American Power. New York: Basic Books.
———. 1995. The Case for Deep Engagement. Foreign Affairs 74:90–102.
O’Halloran, Sharyn. 1994. Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy. Ann Arbor: University of
Michigan Press.
Obstfeld, Maurice. 1997. Open-Economy Macroeconomics, Developments in Theory and Policy. NBER
Working Paper 6319. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Alan M. Taylor. 1997. The Great Depression as a Watershed: International Capital
Mobility over the Long Run. NBER Working Paper 5960. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Odell, John S. 1982. U.S. InternationalMonetary Policy: Markets, Power, and Ideas as Sources of Changes.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1997. Military-Political Conditions and International Economic Negotiations. Unpublished manu-
script, University of Southern California, Los Angeles.
1046 International Organization
Pauly, Louis W., and Janice Gross Stein, eds. 1993. Choosing to Cooperate: How States Avoid Loss.
Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Peck, Connie. 1996. The United Nations as a Dispute Settlement System. The Hague: Kluwer Law Interna-
tional.
Peck, Richard. 1979. Socialization of Permanent Representatives in the United Nations: Some Evidence.
International Organization 33:365–90.
Peirce, Charles S. [1940] 1955. Philosophical Writings of Peirce. Edited by Justus Buchler. Reprint, New
York: Dover.
Pendergast, William R. 1976. Roles and Attitudes of French and Italian Delegates to the European Com-
munity. International Organization 30:669–67.
Pentland, C. 1973. International Theory and European Integration. London: Faber and Faber.
Pérez-D´õ az, V. M. 1993. The Return of Civil Society. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Perkins, Whitney. 1958. Sanctions For Political Change—The Indonesian Case. International Organiza-
tion 12:26–42.
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini. 1994. Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? American Economic
Review 84:600–21.
Peterson, Peter G., and James Sebenius. 1992. The Primacy of the Domestic Agenda. In Rethinking
America’s Security: Beyond Cold War to New World Order, edited by Graham Allison and Gregory
Treverton, 57–93. New York: Norton.
Peterson, V. Spike, and Anne S. Runyan. 1993. Global Gender Issues. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
Pfaller, Alfred, Ian Gough, and Göran Therborn, eds. 1991. Can the Welfare State Compete? London:
Macmillan.
Pfetsch, Frank R., ed. 1993. International Relations and Pan-Europe—Theoretical Approaches and Em-
pirical Findings. Münster and Hamburg: Lit Verlag.
Pierson, Christopher. 1991. Beyond the Welfare State? Cambridge: Polity Press.
Pierson, Paul. 1996a. The New Politics of the Welfare State. World Politics 48:143–79.
———. 1996b. The Path to European Integration: A Historical Institutionalist Analysis. Comparative
Political Studies 29:123–63.
Polanyi, Karl. 1944. The Great Transformation. New York: Farrar and Rinehart.
———. [1944] 1957a. The Great Transformation. Boston: Beacon Press.
———. 1957b. Aristotle Discovers the Economy. In Trade and Markets in the Early Empires, edited by
Karl Polanyi, Conrad M. Arensberg, and Harry W. Pearson. Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press.
Pollack, Mark A. 1997. Delegation, Agency, and Agenda Setting in the European Community. Interna-
tional Organization 51:99–134
Pollard, Robert A. 1985. Economic Security and the Origins of the Cold War, 1945–1950. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Pontusson, Jonas, and Peter Swenson. 1996. Labor Markets, Production Strategies, and Wage-Bargaining
Institutions. Comparative Political Studies 29:223–50.
Porter, Tony. Forthcoming. Can There Be National Perspectives on International Relations? In Interna-
tional Relations: Still an American Social Science? Towards Diversity in International Thought, edited
by Robert M. A. Crawford and Darryl S. L. Jarvis. Albany, N.Y.: SUNY Press.
Posen, Barry R. 1984. The Sources of Military Doctrine: France, Britain, and Germany Between the
World Wars. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1993. The Security Dilemma and Ethnic Con ict. In Ethnic Con ict and International Security,
edited by M. Brown, 103–24. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1993c. Nationalism, the Mass Army, and Military Power. International Security 18:80–124.
Posen, Barry R., and Andrew L. Ross. 1997. Competing U.S. Grand Strategies. In Eagle Adrift: American
Foreign Policy at the End of the Century, edited by Robert J. Lieber, 100–34. New York: Longman.
Powell, Charles. 1992. What the PM Learnt About the Germans. In When the Wall Came Down: Reactions
to German Uni cation, edited by Harold James and Marla Stone, 233–39. New York: Routledge.
Powell, Robert. 1990. Nuclear Deterrence Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1991. Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory. American Political Science
Review 85:1303–20.
1048 International Organization
———. 1996. Bargaining in the Shadow of Power. Games and Economic Behavior:255–89.
Powell, Walter W., and Paul J. DiMaggio, eds. 1991. The New Institutionalism in OrganizationalAnalysis.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Prebisch, Raul. 1959. Commercial Policy in the Underdeveloped Countries. American Economic Review
49:251–73.
Prestowitz, Clyde, Jr. 1990. Trading Places: How We Are Giving Our Future to Japan and How to Reclaim
It. 2d ed. New York: Basic Books.
Price, Richard. 1995. A Genealogy of the Chemical Weapons Taboo. International Organization 49:73—
103.
———. 1997. The Chemical Weapons Taboo. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1998. Reversing the Gun Sights: Transnational Civil Society Targets Land Mines. International
Organization 52:613–44.
Price, Richard M., and Christian Reus-Smit. 1998. Constructivism and Critical International Theory.
European Journal of International Relations 4.
Price, Richard M., and Nina Tannenwald. 1996. Norms and Deterrence: The Nuclear and Chemical Weapons
Taboos. In The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by Peter J.
Katzenstein, 114–52. New York: Columbia University Press.
Prigogine, Ilya. 1980. From Being to Becoming: Time and Complexity in the Physical Sciences. New
York: W. H. Freeman.
Przeworski, Adam. 1991. Democracy and the Market. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Przeworski, Adam, and Michael Wallerstein. 1982. The Structure of Class Con ict in Democratic Capi-
talist Societies. American Political Science Review 76:215–38.
Putnam, Robert D. 1988. Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games. Interna-
tional Organization 42:427–60.
———. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Quattrone, George A., and Amos Tversky. 1988. Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analyses of
Political Choice. American Political Science Review 82:719–36.
Quinn, Dennis. 1997. The Correlates of Changes in International Financial Regulation. American Political
Science Review 91:531–52.
Quinn, Dennis, and Carla Inclan. 1997. The Origins of Financial Openness. American Journal of Political
Science 41:771–813.
Ra’anan, Gavriel. 1983. International Policy Formation in the USSR. Hamden, Conn.: Archon Books.
Ramirez, Francisco, Yasemin Soysal, and Suzanne Shanahan. 1997. The Changing Logic of Political
Citizenship: Cross-National Acquisition of Women’s Suffrage Rights, 1890–1990. American Socio-
logical Review 62:735–45.
Ramseyer, J. Mark, and Frances McCall Rosenbluth. 1993. Japan’s Political Marketplace. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Rapoport, Anatol. 1973. Games Nations Play. Semiotica 9:272–86.
Rapoport,Anatol, and Albert M. Chammah. 1965. Prisoners’Dilemma. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan
Press.
Rawls, John. 1955. Two Concepts of Justice. Philosophical Review 64:3–33.
Ray, James Lee. 1989. The Abolition of Slavery and the End of International War. International Organiza-
tion 43:405–39.
Reich, Robert B. 1990. Who Is Us? Harvard Business Review 68:53–64.
———. 1991. Who Is Them? Harvard Business Review 69:77–88.
Remmer, Karen L. 1997. Theoretical Decay and Theoretical Development: Resurgence of Institutional
Analysis. Comparative Politics 50:34–61.
Rengger, Nick. 1988. Going Critical (and reply by Mark Hoffman, Conversation on Critical International
Relations Theory). Millennium: Journal of International Studies 17: 81–96.
Renouvin, Pierre, ed. 1954. Histoire des relations internationales. 8 vols. Paris: Hachette.
Renouvin, Pierre, and Jean-Baptiste Duroselle. 1964. Introduction à l’histoire des relations internation-
ales. Paris: A. Colin.
References 1049
Restivo, Sal. 1994. The Theory Landscape. In Handbook of Science and Technology Studies, edited by
Sheila Jasanoff, Gerald E. Markle, James C. Peterson, and Trevor Pinch, 95–110. Thousand Oaks,
Calif.: Sage.
Reus-Smit, Christian. Forthcoming. The Moral Purpose of the State: Culture, Institutional Rationality,
and International Relations. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Rhodes, Edward. 1996. Sea Change: Interest-based Versus Cultural-CognitiveAccounts of Strategic Choice
in the 1890s. Security Studies 5:43–72.
Rhodes, R. A. W. 1997. Understanding Governance. Policy Networks, Governance, Re exivity, and Ac-
countability. Buckingham: Open University Press.
Rieselbach, Leroy N. 1960. Quantitative Techniques for Studying Voting Behavior in the United Nations
General Assembly. International Organization 14:291–306.
Riggs, Robert. 1958. Politics in the United Nations: A Study of United States In uence in the General
Assembly. Champaign: University of Illinois Press.
———. 1977. One Small Step for Functionalism: UN Participation and Congressional Attitude Change.
International Organization 31:515–39.
Riggs, Robert E., Karen Hanson, Mary Heinz, Barry Huges, and Thomas Volgy. 1970. Behavioralism in
the Study of the United Nations. World Politics 22:197–236.
Riker, William H. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
———. 1995. The Political Psychology of Rational Choice Theory. Political Psychology 16:23–44.
Ringer, Fritz. 1997. Max Weber’s Methodology: The Uni cation of the Cultural and Social Sciences.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Ripsman, Norrin, and Jean-Marc Blanchard. 1996. Commercial Liberalism Under Fire: Evidence from
1914 and 1936. Security Studies 6:4–50.
Risse, Thomas. 1997. Let’s Talk! Insights from the German Debate on Communicative Behavior and
International Relations. Paper presented at the 93d Annual Convention of the American Political Sci-
ence Association, 27–31 August, Washington D.C.
Risse, Thomas, Stephen Ropp, and Kathryn Sikkink, eds. Forthcoming. The Power of Human Rights:
International Norms and Domestic Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Risse-Kappen, Thomas. 1994. Ideas Do Not Float Freely: Transnational Coalitions, Domestic Structures,
and the End of the Cold War. International Organization 48:185–214.
———. 1995a. Reden Ist Nicht Bilig: Zur Debate Um Kommunkation Und Rationalität. Zeitschrift für
Internationale Beziehungen 2:171–84.
———. 1996a. Exploring the Nature of the Beast: International Relations Theory and Comparative Policy
Analysis Meet the European Union. Journal of Common Market Studies 34:53–80.
———. 1996b. Collective Identity in a Democratic Community. In The Culture of National Security:
Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by Peter J. Katzenstein, 357–99. New York: Columbia
University Press.
Risse-Kappen, Thomas, ed. 1995b. Bringing Transnational Relations Back In: Non-State Actors, Do-
mestic Structures, and International Institutions. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Rittberger, Volker, and Hartwig Hummel. 1990. Die Disziplin ‘‘Internationale Beziehungen’’ im deut-
schsprachigen Raum auf der Suche nach ihrer Identität: Entwicklung und Perspektiven. In Theorie der
Internationalen Beziehungen: Bestandsaufnahme und Forschungsperspektiven, edited by Volker Ritt-
berger, (Politiche Vierteljahresschrift, Sonderheft 21):17–47. Opladen, Germany: Westdeutscher Verlag.
Rittberger, Volker, ed., with Peter Mayer. 1993. Regime Theory and International Relations. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Robles, Alfredo C., Jr. 1993. How ‘‘International’’ Are International Relations Syllabi? PS: Political
Science and Politics 26:526–28.
Rochester, J. Martin. 1986. The Rise and Fall of International Organization as a Field of Study. Interna-
tional Organization 40:777–814.
Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Eco-
nomics.
Rogoff, Kenneth. 1985. The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target. Quar-
terly Journal of Economics 100:1169–89.
1050 International Organization
Rogowski, Ronald. 1987. Trade and the Variety of Democratic Institutions. International Organization
41:203–24.
———. 1989. Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments. Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. Forthcoming. Institutions as Constraints on Strategic Choices. In Strategic Choice and Interna-
tional Relations, edited by David A. Lake and Robert Powell. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press.
Rohrlich, Paul E. 1987. Economic Culture and Foreign Policy: The Cognitive Analysis of Economic
Policymaking. International Organization 41:61–92.
Rometsch, D., and W. Wessels. 1996. Conclusion: European Union and National Institutions. In The
European Union and Member States, edited by D. Rometsch and W. Wessels, 328–65. Manchester:
Manchester University Press.
Ron, James. 1997. Varying Methods of State Violence. International Organization 51:275–300.
Röpke, Wilhelm. 1942. International Economic Disintegration. London: William Hodge.
Rosecrance, Richard. 1963. Action and Reaction in World Politics. Boston: Little, Brown.
———. 1986. The Rise of the Trading State. New York: Basic Books.
Rosecrance, Richard, and Arthur A. Stein. 1973. Interdependence: Myth or Reality? World Politics 26:
1–27.
Rosecrance, Richard, and Arthur A. Stein, eds. 1993. The Domestic Bases of Grand Strategy. Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press.
Rosen, Jeffrey. 1997. The Social Police: Following the Law Because You’d Be Too Embarrassed Not To.
The New Yorker, 20 October, 170–81.
Rosen, Stephen Peter. 1991. Winning the Next War: Innovation and the Modern Military. Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press.
———. 1996. Societies and Military Power: India and Its Armies. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Rosenau, James N. 1966. Pre-Theories and Theories of Foreign Policy. In Approaches to Comparative and
International Politics, edited by R. Barry Farrell, 27–92. Evanston, Ill.: Northwestern University Press.
———. 1969a. Linkage Politics. New York: Free Press.
———. 1969b. Toward the Study of National-International Linkages. In Linkage Politics, edited by James
N. Rosenau, 44–63. New York: Free Press.
———. 1986. Before Cooperation: Hegemons, Regimes, and Habit-Driven Actors in World Politics.
International Organization 40:849–94.
———. 1990. Turbulence in World Politics: A Theory of Change and Continuity. Princeton, N.J.: Prince-
ton University Press.
———. 1997. Along the Domestic-Foreign Frontier: Exploring Governance in a Turbulent World. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rosenau, James N., Gary Gartin, Edwin P. McClain, Dona Stinziano, Richard Stoddard, and Dean Swanson.
1977. Of Syllabi, Texts, Students, and Scholarship in International Relations. World Politics 29:263–
340.
Rosenau, James N., and Ernst-Otto Czempiel, eds. 1992. Governance Without Government. Order and
Change in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rosenberg, Shawn W. 1995. Against Neoclassical Political Economy: A Political Psychological Critique.
Political Psychology 16:99–136.
Ross, Dorothy. 1991. The Origins of American Social Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rothstein, B. 1992. Labor-Market Institutions and Working-Class Strength. In Structuring Politics. His-
torical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, edited by S. Steinmo, K. Thelen, and F. Longstreeth,
33–56. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rothstein, Robert L. 1984. Consensual Knowledge and International Collaboration: Some Lessons from
the Commodity Negotiations. International Organization 38:733–62.
Rothwell, Charles Eaton. 1949. International Organization in World Politics. International Organization
3:605–19.
Rubinstein, Alvin Z. 1964. Soviet and American Policies in International Economic Organizations. Inter-
national Organization 18:29–52.
References 1051
Rudzinski, Alexander W. 1951. The In uence of the United Nations on Soviet Policy. International Orga-
nization 5:282–99.
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1972. Collective Goods and Future International Collaboration. American Political
Science Review 66:874–93.
———. 1975. International Responses to Technology: Concepts and Trends. International Organization
29 (3):557–83.
———. 1983a. Continuity and Transformation in the World Polity: Toward a Neorealist Synthesis. World
Politics 35:261–385.
———. 1983b. International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar
Economic Order. In International Regimes, edited by Stephen D. Krasner, 195–231. Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press.
———. 1986. Social Time and International Policy: Conceptualizing Global Population and Resource
Issues. In Persistent Patterns and Emergent Structures in a Waning Century, edited by Margaret P.
Karns, 211–36. New York: Praeger.
———. 1989. International Structure and International Transformation: Space, Time, and Method. In
Global Changes and Theoretical Challenges: Approaches To World Politics for the 1990s, edited by
Ernst-Otto Czempiel and James N. Rosenau, 21–35. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.
———. 1992. Multilateralism: The Anatomy of an Institution. International Organization 46:561–98.
———. 1993. Territoriality and Beyond: Problematizing Modernity in International Relations. Interna-
tional Organization 47:139–74.
———. 1995a. The False Premise of Realism. International Security 20:62–70.
———. 1995b.At Home Abroad, Abroad at Home: International Liberalization and Domestic Stability in
the New World Economy. Millennium: Journal of International Studies 24:507–26.
———. 1995c. Peace in Our Time? Causality, Social Facts, and Narrative Knowing. American Society of
International Law Proceedings 89th Annual Meeting: 93–100.
———. 1996a. Globalization and the Embedded Liberalism Compromise: The End of an Era? Working
Paper 97/1. Cologne: Max Planck Institut für Gesellschaftsforschung.
———. 1996b. Winning the Peace: America and World Order in the New Era. New York: Columbia
University Press.
———. 1997a. Consolidating the European Pillar: The Key to NATO’s Future. Washington Quarterly
20:109–24.
———. 1997b. The Past as Prologue? Interests, Identity, and American Foreign Policy. International
Security 21:89–125.
———. 1998. Constructing the World Polity: Essays on International Institutionalization. London/New
York: Routledge.
Rummel, R. J. 1994. Power, Genocide, and Mass Murder. Journal of Peace Research 31:1–10.
———. 1995. Democracy, Power, Genocide, and Mass Murder. Journal of Con ict Resolution 39:3–26.
Russell, Robert W. 1973. Transgovernmental Interaction in the International Monetary System, 1960–
1972. International Organization 27:431–64.
Russett, Bruce M. 1963. Community and Contention: Britain and America in the Twentieth Century.
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
———. 1985. The Mysterious Case of Vanishing Hegemony. International Organization 39:207–31.
———. 1993. Grasping the Democratic Peace. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Sabine, G. H. 1952. The Two Democratic Traditions. The Philosophical Review 61:493–511.
Sagan, Scott. 1989. Moving Targets: Nuclear Strategy and National Security. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
———. 1993. The Limits of Safety: Organizations, Accidents, and Nuclear Weapons. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Samuels, Richard J. 1994. Rich Nation, Strong Army: National Security, Ideology, and the Transformation
of Japan. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Sandel, M. J. 1982. Liberalism and the Limits of Justice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1984. The Procedural Republic and the Unencumbered Self. Political Theory 12:81–96.
1052 International Organization
Sandholtz, Wayne. 1993. Choosing Union: Monetary Politics and Maastricht. International Organization
47:1–39.
Sandholtz, Wayne, and John Zysman. 1989. 1992: Recasting the European Bargain. World Politics 42:95–
128.
Sassen, Saskia. 1996. Losing Control? Sovereignty in an Age of Globalization. New York: Columbia
University Press.
———. 1997. The Urban Complex in a World Economy. International Social Science Journal 46:43–62.
Sbragia, Alberta M., ed. 1992. Europolitics: Institutions and Policymaking in the ‘‘New’’ European Com-
munity. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Schaller, Michael. 1997. Altered States: The United States and Japan Since the Occupation. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Scharpf, Fritz W. 1991. Crisis and Choice in European Social Democracy. Translated by Ruth Corwley
and Fred Thompson. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1996. Negative and Positive Integration in the Political Economy of European Welfare States. In
Governance in the European Union, edited by Gary Marks, Fritz W. Scharpf, P. C. Schmitter, and W.
Streeck, 15–39. London: Sage.
Schelling, Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Con ict. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
———. 1966. Arms and In uence. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Schelling, Thomas C., and Morton Halperin. 1961. Strategy and Arms Control. New York: Twentieth
Century Fund.
Schlesinger, P. R. 1991. Media, State, and Nation. London: Sage.
———. 1993. Wishful Thinking: Cultural Politics, Media, and Collective Identities in Europe. Journal of
Communication 43:6–17.
———. 1994. Europe’s Contradictory Communicative Space. Daedalus 123:25–52.
Schluchter, Wolfgang. 1989. Rationalism, Religion, and Domination: A Weberian Perspective. Berkeley:
University of California Press.
Schmalz-Bruns, Rainer. 1995. Die Theorie Kommunikativen Handelns: Eine Flaschenpost? Zeitschrift für
Internationale Beziehungen 2:347–70.
Schmidt, Brian C. 1998. The Political Discourse of Anarchy: A Disciplinary History of International
Relations. Albany, N.Y.: SUNY Press.
Schneider, Gerald. 1994. Getting Closer at Different Speeds. In Game Theory and International Relations,
edited by P. Allan and C. Schmidt, 125–55. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Schneider, Gerald, Patricia Weitsman, and Thomas Bernauer. 1995. Towards a New Europe: Stops and
Starts in Regional Integration. Westport, Conn.: Praeger.
Scho eld, Norman. 1985. Anarchy, Altruism, and Cooperation. Social Choice and Welfare 2:207–19.
Schroeder, Paul. 1976. Munich and the British Tradition. Historical Journal 19:223–43.
———. 1992. Did the Vienna Settlement Rest on a Balance of Power? American Historical Review
97:683–706.
———. 1994. The Transformation of European Politics, 1763–1848. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Schultz, Kenneth A. 1996. Domestic Political Competition and Bargaining in International Crises. Ph.D.
diss., Stanford University, Stanford, California.
Schwartz, Herman. 1994. Small States in Big Trouble. World Politics 46:527–55.
Schweller, Randall L. 1996. Neorealism’s Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma? Security Studies
5:90–121.
Schweller, Randall L., and David Priess. 1997. A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions De-
bate. Mershon International Studies Review 41:1–32.
Scott, James C., and David A. Lake. 1989. The Second Face of Hegemony: Britain’s Repeal of the Corn
Laws and the American Walker Tariff of 1846. International Organization 43:1–29.
Scott, W. Richard, and John W. Meyer, eds. 1994. Institutional Environment and Organizations: Struc-
tural Complexity and Individualism. Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage.
Searing, D. D. 1991. Roles, Rules, and Rationality in the New Institutionalism. American Political Sci-
ence Review 85:1239–60.
References 1053
Searle, John R. 1995. The Construction of Social Reality. New York: Free Press.
———. 1997. Consciousness and the Philosophers. New York Review of Books, 6 March, 43–50.
Sen, Amartya. 1994. The Formulation of Rational Choice. American Economic Review 84:385–90.
———. 1995. Rationality and Social Choice. American Economic Review 85:1–24.
Senghaas, Dieter. 1969. Abschreckung und Frieden: Studien zur Kritik organisierter Friedlosigkeit. Frank-
furt am Main: Europäische Verlagsanstatt.
Shapiro, I., and R. Hardin. 1996. Introduction. In Political Order, edited by I. Shapiro and R. Hardin,
1–15. New York: New York University Press.
Sharp, Walter R. 1953. The Institutional Framework for Technical Assistance. International Organization
7:342–79.
Shaw, Martin. 1994. Global Society and International Relations. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Shepherd, William F. 1994. International Financial Integration. Aldershot: Avebury.
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979. Institutional Arrangements and Equilibria in Multidimensional Voting Models.
American Journal of Political Science 23:27–59.
———. 1986. Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions. In Political Science: The Science of
Politics, edited by Herbert Weisberg. New York: Agathon Press.
———. 1989. Studying Institutions: Some Lessons from the Rational Choice Approach. Journal of Theo-
retical Politics 1:131–47.
———. 1990. Perspectives on Positive Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Barry R. Weingast, eds. 1995. Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions.
Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Sherif, Muzafer. 1966. Group Con ict and Cooperation: Their Social Psychology. London: Routledge
and Kegan Paul.
Sherif, Muzafer, and Carolyn Sherif. 1953. Groups in Harmony and Tension. New York: Harper and Row.
Shimko, Keith. 1992. Realism, Neorealism, and American Liberalism. Review of Politics 54:281–301.
Shoemaker, Nancy. 1997. How Indians Got to Be Red. American Historical Review 102:625–44.
Shon eld, Andrew. 1965. Modern Capitalism. New York: Oxford University Press.
Shugart, Matthew, and John Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral
Dynamics. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Sikkink, Kathryn. 1991. Ideas and Institutions: Developmentalism in Brazil and Argentina. Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press.
———. 1993a. Human Rights, Principled Issue-Networks, and Sovereignty in Latin America. Interna-
tional Organization 47:411–41.
———. 1993b. The Power of Principled Ideas: Human Rights Policies in the United States and Western
Europe. In Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change, edited by Judith
Goldstein and Robert O. Keohane, 139–170. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Simmel, George. 1955. Con ict and the Web of Group Affõliations. New York: Free Press.
Simmons, Beth A. 1993. Why Innovate? Founding the Bank for International Settlements. World Politics
45:361–405.
———. 1994. Who Adjusts? Domestic Sources of Foreign Economic Policy During the Interwar Years,
1924–1939. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1998. See You in ‘‘Court?’’ The Appeal to Quasi-Judicial Legal Processes in the Settlement of
Territorial Disputes. In A Roadmap to War: Territorial Dimensions of International Con ict, edited by
Paul F. Diehl, chap. 8. Nashville, Tenn.: Vanderbilt University Press.
Simon, H. A. 1955. A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics 69:99–118.
———. 1956. Rational Choice and the Structure of the Environment. Psychological Review 63:129–38.
Simon, Herbert A. 1986. Rationality in Psychology and Economics. Journal of Business 59:S209–S224.
———. 1993a. The State of American Political Science: Professor Lowi’s View of Our Discipline. PS:
Political Science and Politics 26:49–51.
———. 1993b. Reply to the Letter Professor Lowi Kindly Wrote Me. PS: Political Science and Politics
26:539.
1054 International Organization
Snyder, Jack. 1984. The Ideology of the Offensive: Military Decisionmaking and the Disasters of 1914.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1991. Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell
University Press.
Snyder, Jack, and Robert Jervis. Forthcoming. Civil War and the Security Dilemma. In Civil War, Insecu-
rity, and Intervention, edited by Barbara Walter and Jack Snyder. New York: Columbia University
Press.
Snyder, Richard. 1955. Toward Greater Order in the Study of World Politics. World Politics 7:461–78.
Snyder, Richard C., H. W. Bruck, and Burton Sapin. 1954. Decision-Making as an Approach to the Study
of International Politics. Foreign Policy Analysis Series, 3. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University.
———. 1962. Foreign Policy Decision-Making. New York: Free Press.
Sobel, Andrew. 1994. Domestic Choices, International Markets. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Soskice, David. 1990. Wage Determination: The Changing Role of Institutions in Advanced Industrialized
Countries. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 6:36–61.
Spero, Joan. 1981. The Politics of International Economic Relations. New York: St. Martin’s.
Spirtas, Michael. 1998. With or Without: British and French Policies Toward Economic and Military
Cooperation. Ph.D. diss., Department of Political Science, Columbia University, New York.
Spruyt, Hendrik. 1994. The Sovereign State and Its Competitors: An Analysis of System Change. Prince-
ton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Staley, Eugene. 1935. War and the Private Investor. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
———. 1939. World Economy in Transition. Technology Versus Politics, Laissez-faire Versus Planning,
Power Versus Welfare. New York: Council on Foreign Relations.
Starbuck, W. H., A. Greve, and B. L. Hedberg. 1978. Responding to Crises. Journal of Business Adminis-
tration 9:111–37.
Stein, Arthur A. 1980. The Politics of Linkage. World Politics 33:62–81.
———. 1983. Coordination and Collaboration: Regimes in an Anarchic World. In International Regimes,
edited by Stephen D. Krasner, 115–40. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1984. The Hegemon’s Dilemma: Great Britain, the United States, and the International Economic
Order. International Organization 38:355–86.
———. 1990. Why Nations Cooperate: Circumstance and Choice in International Relations. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1993. Governments, Economic Interdependence, and International Cooperation. In Behavior,
Society, and Nuclear War. Vol. 3, Behavior, Society, and International Con ict., edited by Philip E.
Tetlock, Jo L. Husbands, Robert Jervis, Paul C. Stern, and Charles Tilly, 241–324. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Stein, Janice Gross. 1994. Political Learning By Doing: Gorbachev as an Uncommitted Thinker and a
Motivated Learner. International Organization 48:155–83.
Steinbruner, John D. 1974. The Cybernetic Theory of Decision. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press.
Steinmo, Sven. 1993. Taxation and Democracy. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Steinmo, Sven, Kathleen Thelen, and Frank Longstreth. 1992. Structuring Politics: Historical Institution-
alism in Comparative Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Stephanson, Anders. 1989. Kennan and the Art of Foreign Policy. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press.
Sterling-Folker, Jennifer. 1997. Realist Environment, Liberal Process, and Domestic-Level Variables.
International Studies Quarterly 41:1–26.
Stevenson, David. 1996. Armaments and the Coming of War: Europe, 1904–1914. Oxford: Clarendon
Press.
Stinchcombe, A. L. 1965. Social Structure and Organizations. In Handbook of Organizations, edited by
James G. March, 142–93. Chicago: Rand McNally.
———. 1986. Reason and Rationality. Sociological Theory 4:151–66.
———. 1997. On the Virtues of the Old Institutionalism. Annual Review of Sociology 23:1–18.
1056 International Organization
Stokke, O. S. 1997. Regimes as Governance Systems. In Global Governance: Drawing Insights from the
Environmental Experience, edited by Oran R. Young, 27–63. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Stone, A. 1994. What Is a Supranational Constitution? An Essay in International Relations Theory. The
Review of Politics 56:441–74.
Strang, David. 1991.Anomaly and Commonplace in European Political Expansion: Realist and Institution-
alist Accounts. International Organization 45:143–62.
Strang, David, and Patricia Mei Yin Chang. 1993. The International Labor Organization and the Welfare
State: Institutional Effects on National Welfare Spending, 1960–1980. International Organization 47:
235–62.
Strange, Susan. 1970. International Economics and International Relations: A Case of Mutual Neglect.
International Affairs 46:304–315.
———. 1976. International Monetary Relations. In International Economic Relations of the Western
World 1959–1971, edited by Andrew Shon eld, vol. 2, 3–359. London: Oxford University Press.
———. 1979. The Management of Surplus Capacity: Or How Does Theory Stand Up to Protectionism
1970s Style? International Organization 33:303–334.
———. 1983. Cave! hic Dragones: A Critique of Regime Analysis. In International Regimes, edited by
Stephen D. Krasner, 337–54. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1986. Casino Capitalism. Oxford: Blackwell.
———. 1988. States and Markets. London: Frances Pinter.
———. 1995. 1995 Presidential Address: ISA as a Microcosm. International Studies Quarterly 39:
289–95.
———. 1996. The Retreat of the State: The Diffusion of Power in the World Economy. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Sugden, Robert. 1989. Spontaneous Order. Journal of Economic Perspectives 3:85–97.
Suhr, Michael. 1997. Robert O. Keohane: A Contemporary Classic. In The Future of International Rela-
tions: Masters in the Making?, edited by Iver B. Neumann and Ole Wæver, 90–120. London: Rout-
ledge.
Sunstein, Cass. 1997. Free Markets and Social Justice. New York: Oxford University Press.
Swank, Duane. 1998. Funding the Welfare State. Political Studies 46: 671–92.
Swedberg, Richard. 1991. ‘‘The Battle of the Methods’’: Toward a Paradigm Shift? In Socio-Economic
Trends: Toward a New Synthesis, edited by Amitai Etzioni and Paul R. Lawrence, 13–33. Armonk,
N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe.
Swenson, Peter. 1991. Bringing Capital Back In, or Social Democracy Reconsidered. World Politics
43:513–34.
Taylor, C. 1985. Philosophy and the Human Sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Taylor, Michael. 1967. Anarchy and Cooperation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Tetlock, Philip E., and Charles McGuire, Jr. 1986. Cognitive Perspectives on Foreign Policy. In Political
Behavior Annual, edited by Samuel Long, 147–79. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
Teubner, G. 1993. Law as an Autopoietic System. Oxford: Blackwell.
Thomas, Daniel C. 1997. Norms and Change in World Politics: Human Rights, the Helsinki Accords, and
the Demise of Communism, 1975–1990. Ph.D. diss., Cornell University, Ithaca, N.Y.
Thomas, George M., John W. Meyer, Francisco O. Ramirez, and John Boli, eds. 1987. Institutional Struc-
ture: Constituting State, Society, and Individual. Newbury Park, Calif.: Sage Publications.
Thomson, Janice E. 1994. Mercenaries, Pirates, and Sovereigns: State-Building and Extraterritorial Vio-
lence in Early Modern Europe. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Tickner, J. Ann. 1992. Gender in International Relations. New York: Columbia University Press.
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion, Capital, and European States, A.D. 990–1990. Cambridge: Basil Black-
well.
———. 1993. Coercion, Capital, and European States, A.D. 990–1990. Rev. ed. Cambridge: Blackwell.
Tilly, Charles, ed. 1975. The Formation of National States in Western Europe. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Tirole, Jean. 1989. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
References 1057
Tonra, B. 1996. Dutch, Danish, and Irish Foreign Policy in the EPC/CFSP 1970–1996. Ph.D. diss., Univer-
sity of Dublin, Trinity College.
Toulmin, Stephen. 1972. Human Understanding. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Trachtenberg, Marc. 1989. Strategic Thought in America, 1952–1966. Political Science Quarterly 104:
301–44.
Tsebelis, George. 1990. Nested Games. Berkeley: University of California Press.
———. 1994. The Power of the European Parliament as a ConditionalAgenda-Setter. American Political
Science Review 88:128–47.
———. 1995. Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentari-
anism, Multicameralism, and Mutlipartyism. British Journal of Political Science 25:289–325.
Tsebelis, George, and Jeannette Money. 1995. Bicameral Negotiations: The Navette System in France.
British Journal of Political Science 25:101–29.
———. 1997. Bicameralism. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Tucker, Robert C. 1978. The Marx–Engels Reader. 2d ed. New York: Norton.
Tully, James, ed. 1988. Meaning and Context: Quentin Skinner and His Critics. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Tyson, Laura D’Andrea. 1992. Who’s Bashing Whom? Trade Con ict in High Technology Industries.
Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
Ullman, Richard. 1983. Rede ning Security. International Security 8:129–53.
U.S. Department of Defense. 1995. Report, Assistant Secretary of Defense for United States Security
Strategy for the East Asia–Paci c Region. Office of International Security Affairs, February. Wash-
ington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of State. 1997. Office of European Union and RegionalAffairs. New Transatlantic Agenda.
Senior Level Group Report to the U.S.–E.U. Summit, The Hague, 28 May.
Van Evera, Stephen. 1984a. Causes of War. Ph.D diss., University of California, Berkeley.
———. 1984b. The Cult of the Offensive and the Origins of the First World War. International Security
9:58–107.
———. 1990. Primed for Peace: Europe After the Cold War. International Security 15:7–57.
Vasquez, John A. 1997. The Realist Paradigm and Degenerative Versus Progressive Research Programs:
An Appraisal of Neotraditional Research on Waltz’s Balancing Proposition. American Political Sci-
ence Review 91:899–913. Followed by reactions from Kenneth N. Waltz, Thomas J. Christensen and
Jack Snyder, Colin and Miriam Fendius Elman, Randall L. Schweller, and Stephen M. Walt.
Vaubel, Roland. 1986. A Public Choice Approach to International Organization. Public Choice 51:39–57.
Verba, Sidney. 1961. Assumptions of Rationality and Non-Rationality in Models of the International
System. In The International System: Theoretical Essays, edited by Klaus Knorr and Sidney Verba,
93–117. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Vernon, Raymond. 1971. Sovereignty at Bay. New York: Basic Books.
Viner, Jacob. 1948. Power Versus Plenty as Objectives of Foreign Policy in the Seventeenth and Eigh-
teenth Centuries. World Politics 1:1–29.
Vogel, David. 1995. Trading Up: Consumer and Environmental Regulation in a Global Economy. Cam-
bridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Volgy, Thomas. 1973. The Role of the Outsider in Quasi-Legislative Systems: The Potential Utility of a
Legislative Model. International Organization 27:85–98.
Volgy, Thomas J., and Jon E. Quistgard. 1974. Correlates of Organizational Rewards in the United Na-
tions: An Analysis of Environmental and Legislative Variables. International Organization 28:179–
205.
———. 1975. Learning About the Value of Global Cooperation: Role-Taking in the United Nations as a
Predictor of World-Mindedness. Journal of Con ict Resolution 19:349–76.
Vout, Malcolm. 1991. Oxford and the Emergence of Political Science in England 1945–1960. In Sociology
of the Sciences—A Yearbook. Vol. 15, Discourses on Society: The Shaping of the Social Sciences,
edited by P. Wagner, B. Wittrock, and R. Whitley, 163–194. Dordrecht: Kluwer.
1058 International Organization
Wade, Robert. 1990. Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian
Industrialization. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
———. 1996a. Globalization and Its Limits. In National Diversity and Global Capitalism, edited by
Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, 60–88. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1996b. Japan, The World Bank, and the Art of Paradigm Maintenance. New Left Review 217:
3–36.
Wæver, Ole. 1992. Introduktion til Studiet af International Politik. Copenhagen: Forlaget Politiske Studier.
———. 1996. The Rise and Fall of the Inter-Paradigm Debate. In International Theory: Positivism and
Beyond, edited by Steve Smith, Ken Booth, and Marysia Zalewski, 149–85. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
———. 1997. Figures of International Thought: Introducing Persons Instead of Paradigms. In The Future
of International Relations. Masters in the Making?, edited by Iver B. Neumann and Ole Wæver, 1–37.
London: Routledge.
Wagner, Peter. 1989. Social Science and the State in Continental Western Europe: The Political Structura-
tion of Disciplinary Discourse. International Social Science Journal 122:509–28.
———. 1990a. Sozialwissenschaften und Staat: Frankreich, Italien, Deutschland 1870–1980. Frankfurt
and New York: Campus Verlag.
———. 1990b. The Place of the Discourse on Politics Among the Social Sciences: Political Science in
Turn-of-the-Century Europe. In Texts, Contexts, Concepts: Studies in Politics and Power in Language,
edited by Sakari Hänninen and Kari Palonen, 262–281. Jyväskylä, Finnland: Finnish Political Science
Association.
Wagner, Peter, and Björn Wittrock. 1991. Analyzing Social Science: On the Possiblity of a Sociology of
the Social Sciences and States, Institutions, and Discourses: A Comparative Perspective on the Structu-
ration of the Social Sciences. In Sociology of the Sciences—A Yearbook. Vol. 15, Discourses on So-
ciety: The Shaping of the Social Sciences, edited by P. Wagner, B. Wittrock, and R. Whitley, 3–22,
331–58. Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Wagner, Peter, Carol H. Weiss, Björn Wittrock, and Hellmut Wollmann, eds. 1991. Social Sciences and
Modern States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wagner, R. Harrison. 1974. Dissolving the State: Three Recent Perspectives on International Relations.
International Organization 28:435–66.
Walker, R. B. J. 1989. History and Structure in the Theory of International Studies. Millennium: Journal of
International Studies 18:163–83.
———. 1993. Inside/Outside: International Relations as Political Theory. New York: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Wallace, William, ed. 1990. The Dynamics of European Integration. London: Pinter, for the Royal Insti-
tute of International Affairs.
Wallander, Celeste. 1998. Balancing Acts: Security, Institutions, and German–Russian Relations After the
Cold War. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Wallensteen, P., and M. Sollenberg. 1997. Armed Con icts, Con ict Termination, and Peace Agreements,
1989–1996. Journal of Peace Research 34:339–58.
Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1974. The Modern World System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the
European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York: Academic Press.
———. 1979. The Capitalist World-Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 1991. Geopolitics and Geoculture: Essays on the Changing World System. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Wallwork, Ernest. 1972. Durkheim: Morality and Milieu. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Walt, Stephen M. 1987. The Origins of Alliances. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1991. The Renaissance of Security Studies. International Studies Quarterly 35:211–39.
Walter, Barbara. 1994. The Resolution of Civil Wars: Why Negotiations Fail. Ph.D. diss., Department of
Political Science, University of Chicago, Chicago, Ill.
Walter, Barbara, and Jack Snyder, eds. Forthcoming. Civil War, Insecurity, and Intervention. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Waltz, Kenneth N. 1959. Man, the State, and War. New York: Columbia University Press.
References 1059
———. 1991. Bridging the Theory/Meta-Theory Gap in International Relations. Review of International
Studies 17:383–92.
———. 1992. Anarchy Is What States Make of It: The Social Construction of Power Politics. Interna-
tional Organization 46:391–425.
———. 1994. Collective Identity Formation and the International State. American Political Science Re-
view 88:384–96.
———. 1995. Constructing International Politics. International Security 20:71–81.
———. Forthcoming. Social Theory and International Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Wendt, Alexander, and R. Duvall 1989. Institutions and International Order. In Global Changes and
Theoretical Challenges: Approaches to World Politics for the 1990s, edited by Ernst-Otto Czempiel
and James N. Rosenau, 51–73. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.
Wessels, W. 1990. Administrative Interaction. In Dynamics of European Integration, edited by W. Wal-
lace, 229–41. London: Pinter.
———. 1997. An Ever Closer Fusion. Unpublished manuscript, Universität zu Köln.
Whitehead, Laurence. 1996. Three International Dimensions of Democratization. In The International
Dimensions of Democratization: Europe and the Americas, edited by Laurence Whitehead, 3–25. Ox-
ford: Oxford University Press.
The White House. 1996. Report: A National Security Strategy of Engagement and Enlargement. Wash-
ington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
Whitley, Richard. 1984. The Intellectual and Social Organization of the Sciences. Oxford: Clarendon
Press.
———. 1986. The Structure and Context of Economics as a Scienti c Field. In Research in the History of
Economic Thought and Methodology: A Research Annual, edited by Warren J. Samuels, 4:179–209.
Greenwich, Conn., and London: JAI Press.
Wight, Martin. 1977. Systems of States. Leicester: Leicester University Press.
Wilcox, Clyde, and Leonard Williams. 1990. Taking Stock of Schema Theory. Social Science Journal
27:373–93.
Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York:
Free Press.
———. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.
———. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. New York: Oxford University Press.
Winters, Jeffrey. 1996. Power in Motion: Capital Mobility and the Indonesian State. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell
University Press.
Wittrock, Björn. 1992. Discourse and Discipline: Political Science as Project and Profession. In European
Social Science in Transition: Assessment and Outlook, edited by Meinolf Dierkes and Bernd Biervert,
268–308. Frankfurt am Main: Campus Verlag and Boulder Colo.: Westview Press.
———. 1993. The Modern University: The Three Transformations. In The European and American Uni-
versity Since 1800: Historical and Sociological Essays, edited by Sheldon Rothblatt and Björn Wit-
trock, 303–62. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wohlforth, William C. 1994. Realism and the End of the Cold War. International Security 19:96–100.
Wohlstetter, Albert. 1959. The Delicate Balance of Terror. Foreign Affairs 37:211–34.
Wolf, Peter. 1974. International Organization and Attitude Change: A Re-Examination of the Functionalist
Approach. International Organization 28:352–53.
Wolfers, Arnold. 1952. National Security as an Ambiguous Symbol. Political Science Quarterly 67: 481–
502.
———. 1956. Introduction. In The Anglo-American Tradition in Foreign Affairs, edited by Arnold Wolfers
and Laurence W. Martin. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press. Reprinted in Wolfers, Discord and
Collaboration, 233–51.
———. 1962. Discord and Collaboration: Essays on International Politics. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hop-
kins University Press.
Wood, Adrian. 1994. North-South Trade, Employment, and Inequality. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Wood, Robert J. 1952. The First Year of Shape. International Organization 6:175–91.
References 1061
Wooley, John. 1984. Monetary Politics: The Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
World Bank. 1997. World Development Report 1997: The State in a Changing World. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
World Commission on Environment and Development. 1987. Our Common Future. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
versity Press.
Wright, Quincy. 1952. Realism and Idealism in International Politics. World Politics 5:116–28.
Yack, Bernard. 1996. The Myth of the Civic Nation. Critical Review 10:193–211.
Yarbrough, Beth, and Robert Yarbrough 1992. Cooperation and Governance in International Trade. Prince-
ton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Yee, Albert S. 1996. The Causal Effects of Ideas on Policies. International Organization 50:69–108.
Young, Oran R. 1972. The Perils of Odysseus: On Constructing Theories of International Relations. World
Politics 24:179–203.
———. 1979. Compliance with Public Authority: A Theory with International Applications. Baltimore,
Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
———. 1986. International Regimes: Toward a New Theory of Institutions. World Politics 39:104–22.
———. 1989. International Cooperation: Building Regimes for Natural Resources and the Environment.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
———. 1994. International Governance: Protecting the Environment in a Stateless Society. Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press.
———. 1996. Institutional Linkages in International Society: Polar Perspectives. Global Governance
2:1–24.
Young, Oran R., ed. 1997. Global Governance: Drawing Insights from the Environmental Experience.
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Zakaria, Fareed. 1992. Realism and Domestic Politics. International Security 17:177–98.
Zelikow, Philip, and Condoleezza Rice. 1995. Germany Uni ed and Europe Transformed. Cambridge,
Mass: Harvard University Press.
Zuckerman, Harriet. 1989. The Sociology of Science. In Handbook of Sociology, edited by Neil Smelser,
511–74. Newbury Park, Calif: Sage.
Zürn, Michael. 1994. We Can Do Much Better! Aber Muss es auf amerikanisch sein? Zeitschrift für
Internationale Beziehungen 1:91–114.
Zysman, John. 1977. Political Strategies for Industrial Order: State, Market, and Industry in France.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
———. 1983. Governments, Markets, and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of Industrial Change.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.