Notes6 Macro
Notes6 Macro
Notes6 Macro
according to a specific policy rule. Whatever the rule says the interest rate should be, the
central banks sets that interest rate. But what if the rule predicts the central bank should set
Well let’s step back a minute and think about what the interest rate it in our model
actually means. This interest rate appears in the IS curve because we think higher real
interest rates discourage consumption and investment spending by the private sector. So
the relevant interest rates here are interest rates that private sector agents borrow at. And
indeed, if you look at the interest rates that central banks target, they are generally short-term
“money market” interest rates on transactions featuring private sector agents on both sides of
the deal. For example, the Federal Reserve targets the federal funds rate, which is the rate at
which banks borrow and lend short-term funds to and from each other. The ECB also targets
With this in mind, consider why these private sector interest rates are unlikely to ever
be negative. If I loan you $100 and only get $101 back next period, I haven’t earned much
interest but at least I earned some. A negative interest rate would mean me loaning you $100
and getting back less than that next year. Why would I do that? Since money maintains its
nominal face value, I’d be better off just the keep the money in my bank account or under a
mattress.
With this in mind, we are going to adapt our model to take into account that there are
times when the central bank would like to set it below zero but is not able to do so.
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 2
When will the “zero lower bound” become a problem for a central bank? In our IS-MP-
PC model, it depends on the form of the monetary policy rule. Up to now, we have been
it = r∗ + π ∗ + βπ (πt − π ∗ ) (1)
This rule sees the nominal interest rate adjusted upwards and downwards as inflation changes.
So the lower bound problem occurs when inflation goes below some critical value. This
value might be negative, so it may occur when there is deflation, meaning prices are falling.
Amending our model to remove the possibility that interest rates could become negative, our
Because the intended interest rate of the central bank declines with inflation, this means that
there is a particular inflation rate, π ZLB , such that if πt < π ZLB then the interest rate will
equal zero. So what determines this specific value, π ZLB that triggers the zero lower bound?
r∗ + π ∗ + βπ π ZLB − π ∗ = 0 (3)
βπ π ZLB = βπ π ∗ − r∗ − π ∗ (4)
Equation (5) tells us that three factors determine the value of inflation at which the central
1. The inflation target: The higher the inflation target π ∗ is, then the higher is the level
of inflation at which a central bank will be willing to set interest rates equal to zero.
2. The natural rate of interest: A higher value of r∗ , the “natural” real interest rate,
lowers the level of inflation at which a central bank will be willing to set interest rates
equal to zero. An increase in this rate makes central bank raise interest rates and so
they will wait until inflation goes lower than previously to set interest rates to zero.
coefficient on π ∗ in this formula, increasing the first term and it makes the second term
(which has a negative sign) smaller. Both effects mean a higher βπ translates into a
higher value for π ZLB . Central banks that react more aggressively against inflation will
wait for inflation to reach lower values before they are willing to set interest rates to
zero.
Given this characterisation of when the zero lower bound kicks in, we need to re-formulate the
IS-MP curve. Once inflation falls below π ZLB , the central bank cannot keep cutting interest
rates in line with its monetary policy rule. Recalling that the IS curve
We had previously derived the IS-MP curve by substituting in the monetary policy rule
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 4
formula (1) for it term. This gave us the IS-MP curve as:
However, when πt ≤ π ZLB we need to substitute in zero instead of the negative value that the
The effect of inflation on output in this revised IS-MP curve changes when inflation moves
below π ZLB . Above π ZLB , higher values of inflation are associated with lower values of output.
Below π ZLB , higher values of inflation are associated with higher values of output. Graphically,
this means the IS-MP curve shifts from being downward-sloping to being upward-sloping when
inflation falls below π ZLB . Figure 1 provides an example of how this looks.
Equation (8) also explains the conditions under which the zero lower bound is likely to
be relevant. If there are no aggregate demand shocks, so yt = 0, then the zero lower bound
is likely to kick in at a point where output is above its natural rate; see Figure 1 for an
illustration of this case. But this combination of high output and low inflation is unlikely to
be an equilibrium in the model unless the public expects very low inflation or deflation so the
Phillips curve intersects the IS-MP curve along the section that has output above its natural
However, if we have a large negative aggregate demand shock, so that yt < 0, then it is
possible to have output below its natural rate and inflation falling below π ZLB . As illustrated
in Figure 2, this situation is more likely to be an equilibrium (i.e. this position for the IS-MP
curve is more likely to intersect with the Phillips curve) even if inflation expectations are close
IS-MP ( =0)
Inflation
Output
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 6
IS-MP ( =0)
Inflation
PC ( )
IS-MP ( < 0)
Output
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 7
Using the expression for the output gap when the zero lower bound limit has been reached
from equation (9) we get an expression for inflation under these conditions as follows
1 αγ ∗ γ 1
πt = πte + r + yt + πt (12)
1 − αγ 1 − αγ 1 − αγ 1 − αγ
1
The coefficient on expected inflation, 1−αγ
is greater than one. So, just as with the Taylor
principle example from the last notes, changes in expected inflation translate into even bigger
changes in actual inflation. As we discussed the last time, this leads to unstable dynamics.
Because these dynamics take place only when inflation has fallen below the zero lower bound,
the instability here relates to falling inflation expectations, leading to further declines in
inflation and further declines in inflation expectations. Because output depends positively
on inflation when the zero-bound constraint binds, these dynamics mean falling inflation (or
This position in which nominal interest rates are zero and the economy falls into a defla-
tionary spiral is known as the liquidity trap. Figures 3 and 4 illustrate how the liquidity trap
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 8
operates in our model. Figure 3 shows how a large negative aggregate demand shock can lead
to interest rates hitting the zero bound even when expected inflation is positive.
Figure 4 illustrates how expected inflation has a completely different effect when the zero
lower bound has been hit. It shows a fall in expected inflation after the negative demand shock
(this example isn’t adaptive expectations because I haven’t drawn inflation expectations falling
all the way to the deflationary outcome graphed in Figure 3). In our usual model set-up, a
fall in expected inflation raises output. However, once at the zero bound, a fall in expected
IS-MP ( =0)
Inflation
PC ( )
IS-MP ( < 0)
Output
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 10
IS-MP ( =0)
Inflation
PC ( )
IS-MP ( < 0)
PC ( )
Output
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 11
For the simple monetary policy rule that we have been using, the zero lower bound is hit for
a particular trigger level of inflation. Plugging in reasonable parameter values into equation
(5) this trigger value will most likely be negative. In other words, with the monetary policy
rule that we have been using, the zero lower bound will only be hit when there is deflation.
However, if we have a different monetary policy rule this result can be overturned. For
example, remember the Taylor-type rule we considered in the first set of notes
In other words, there are a series of different combinations of inflation gaps and output gaps
that can lead to monetary policy hitting the zero lower bound. For example, if yt = yt∗ the
lower bound will be hit at the value of inflation given by equation (5), i.e. the level we have
defined as π ZLB . In contrast, inflation could equal its target level but policy would hit the
r∗ +π ∗
zero bound if output fell as low as yt∗ − βy
.
Graphically, we can represent all the combinations of output and inflation that produce
zero interest rates under the Taylor rule as the area under a downward-sloping line in Inflation-
Output space. Figure 5 gives an illustration of what this area would look like. We showed
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 12
in the first set of notes that when we are above the zero bound, the IS-MP curve under the
Taylor rule is of the same downward-sloping form as under our simple inflation targeting rule.
At the zero bound, the arguments we’ve already presented here also apply so that the IS-MP
Figure 6 illustrates two different cases of IS-MP curves when monetary policy follows a
Taylor rule. The right-hand curve corresponds to the case yt = 0 (no aggregate demand
shocks) and this curve only interests with the zero bound area when there is a substantial
deflation. In contrast, the left-hand curve corresponds to the case in which yt is highly negative
(a large negative aggregate demand shocks) and this curve interests with the zero bound area
even at levels of inflation that are positive and aren’t much below the central bank’s target.
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 13
Inflation
Output
Zero Lower
Bound Area
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 14
IS-MP ( =0)
Output
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 15
An important aspect of this model of the liquidity trap is it shows that some of the predictions
that our model made (and which are now part of the conventional wisdom among monetary
Up to now we have seen that as long as the central bank maintains its inflation targets,
then the model with adaptive expectations predicts that deviations of the public’s inflation
expectations from this target will be temporary and the economy will tend to converge back
towards its natural level of output. However, once interest rates have hit the zero bound,
this is no longer the case. Instead, the adaptive expectations model predicts the economy can
Similarly, our earlier model predicted that a strong belief from the public that the central
bank would keep inflation at target was helpful in stabilising the economy. However, once
you reach the zero bound, convincing the public to raise its inflation expectations (perhaps
The most obvious way that a liquidity trap can end is if there is a positive aggregate demand
shock that shifts the IS-MP curve back upwards so that the intersection with the Phillips
curve occurs at levels of output and inflation that gets the economy out of the liquidity trap.
However, in reality, liquidity traps have often occurred during periods when there are
ongoing and persistent slumps in aggregate demand. For example, after decades of strong
growth, the Japanese economy went into a slump during the 1990s. Housing prices crashed
and businesses and households were hit with serious negative equity problems. This type of
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 16
“balance sheet” recession doesn’t necessarily reverse itself quickly. The result in Japan has
been a persistent deflation since the mid-1990s (see Figure 7) combined with a weak economy.
The Bank of Japan has set short-term interest rates close to zero throughout this period (see
Figure 8).
Given that economies in liquidity traps tend not to self correct with positive aggregate
demand shocks from the private sector, governments can try to boost the economy by us-
ing fiscal policy to stimulate aggregate demand. Japan has used fiscal stimulus on various
What about monetary policy? With its policy interest rates at zero, can a central bank
do any more to boost the economy? Debates on this topic have focused on two areas.
The first area relates to the fact that while the short-term interest rates that are controlled
by central banks may be zero, that doesn’t mean the longer-term rates that many people
borrow at will equal zero. By signalling that they intend to keep short-term rates low for a
long period of time and perhaps by directly intervening in the bond market (i.e. quantitative
The second area relates to inflation expectations. Our model tells us that output can be
boosted when the economy is in a liquidity trap by raising inflation expectations. This acts
to raise inflation (or reduce deflation) and this reduces real interest rates and boost output.
As an academic and during his early years as a member of the Federal Reserve Board of
Governors (prior to becoming Chairman) Ben Bernanke advocated that the Bank of Japan
above their target level of 1%. In a 2003 speech titled “Some Thoughts on Monetary Policy
What I have in mind is that the Bank of Japan would announce its intention to
restore the price level (as measured by some standard index of prices, such as the
consumer price index excluding fresh food) to the value it would have reached if,
instead of the deflation of the past five years, a moderate inflation of, say, 1 percent
The Bank of Japan did not take Bernanke’s advice. More recently, however, under pressure
from the new Japanese government, the Bank of Japan have changed their inflation target from
1% per year to 2% per year. Though not as radical as the steps recommended by Bernanke
and others, it is clear that the current Japanese authorities recognise the importance of raising
inflation expectations.
A third area relates to exchange rates. To raise inflation, a central bank could announce
targets for its exchange rate that would see it fall in value relative to the its major trading
partners. Such a programme could be implemented by the central bank announcing that it
is willing to buy and sell unlimited amounts of foreign exchange at an announced exchange
rate e.g. The ECB could announce that it is willing to swap a euro for $1. Even though the
market rate may have been higher than this, nobody will now pay more for a euro than the
rate available from the ECB. This currency depreciation would make imports more expensive,
which would raise inflation. This latter approach has been labelled the “foolproof way to
escape from a liquidity trap” by leading monetary policy expert Lars Svensson.1
1
Lars Svensson (2003). “Escaping from a Liquidity Trap and Deflation: The Foolproof Way and Others.”
In recent years, the US economy has been in a position that, in some ways, resembles the
position of the Japanese economy during its long liquidity trap period. The economic recov-
ery that started in 2009 has been very weak by historical standards and unemployment has
remained fairly high. In response to this weakness, the Federal Reserve has kept its policy
rate (the federal funds rate) at close to zero since late 2008.
Has the US been in a liquidity trap and should the Fed have been considering more radical
policies such as signalling its intent to allow a temporary rise in inflation? Once Ben Bernanke
became Chairman of the Fed, he was not as keen to implement the ideas he recommended as
an academic. One argument that Bernanke advanced against providing price level guidance
was that the US was not in a liquidity trap because inflation is still positive. However, as
we’ve seen above, for a central bank that responds to deviations of output from its natural
rate (and clearly the Fed does this) then you can have liquidity-trap conditions even with
positive inflation. The key feature of the liquidity trap is zero short-term rates, not deflation.
And this feature has held in the U.S. for a number of years.
Why did Bernanke not adopt the policy he had recommended to the Japanese? The
explanation seems to be that he was concerned that non-standard policies will undermine the
I guess the question is, does it make sense to actively seek a higher inflation rate
reduction in the unemployment rate? The view of the Committee is that that
building up credibility for low and stable inflation, which has proved extremely
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 21
valuable in that we’ve been be able to take strong accommodative actions in the
last four or five years to support the economy without leading to an unanchoring
what I think would be quite tentative and perhaps doubtful gains on the real side
This suggests that Chairman Bernanke was still more focused on the benefits of well-anchored
low inflation expectations during normal times than on the potential benefits of non-standard
Nobel prize winner Paul Krugman, Bernanke’s former colleague at Princeton, was critical
the website to Krugman’s article recommending that “Chairman Bernanke should listen to
Academic Bernanke”. From his research on Japan in the late 1990s, Krugman has discussed
the tension that central bankers feel when in a liquidity trap. When up against the zero
bound, they might like to raise inflation expectations but then they are concerned that this
could make inflation go higher than they would like. The public’s awareness that the central
bank will clamp down on inflation if the economy picks up then prevents there being a sufficient
increase in inflation rates to get the economy out of the liquidity trap. Krugman thus stresses
the need for central banks facing a liquidity trap to “‘commit to being irresponsible” as
a way out of these slumps—commit to a temporary period of inflation being higher than
you would normally like. But central bankers are a conservative crowd and even temporary
The Fed has adopted a number of new policies in recent years such as quantitative easing
and “enhanced forward guidance” in which they signal that rates will stay low for a long
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 22
period. More recently, they have discussed conditions under which they will reduce their QE
purchases and outlined the conditions under which they will keep rates at zero. So there
are signs that the Fed is willing to be flexible. Time will tell if the debate about price-
level targeting or raising the target inflation rate produces a change in policy at the Fed.
With many unconventional tools having been introduced over the past few years, it will be
interesting to see if any of the leading central banks will consider moving away from narrow
Short-term interest in the euro area are also essentially equal to zero. While Mario Draghi
argues there is no cause for concern because there is no deflation as of yet, inflation is extremely
low and the ECB has effectively run out of room for influencing the economy through the
regular interest rate channel. So the euro area also appears to be resemble the liquidity trap
situation we have described here. Given the ECB’s legal requirement to place price stability
above all other goals, they seem unlikely to adopt the kind of policies that can take an economy
Figure 9: The Fed Has Been at the Lower Bound Since 2008
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 24
Figure 10: The ECB Has Also Hit the Lower Bound
University College Dublin, MA Macroeconomics Notes, 2014 (Karl Whelan) Page 25
Here’s a brief summary of the things that you need to understand from these notes.
2. The factors that influence when the central bank sets zero rates.
3. How the IS-MP curve changes when incorporating the zero lower bound.
4. How changes in inflation expectations affect the economy above and below the zero lower
bound.
5. What is meant by the liquidity trap, i.e. why the economy doesn’t automatically recover
6. How the IS-MP-PC graphs work when we incorporate the zero bound.
8. Bernanke’s advice to the Bank of Japan and change of mind as Fed Chairman.
9. Why the US and Euro Area economies could be considered to be in a liquidity trap.