Get EU Public Procurement Law 2nd Edition Edition Christopher Bovis Free All Chapters
Get EU Public Procurement Law 2nd Edition Edition Christopher Bovis Free All Chapters
Get EU Public Procurement Law 2nd Edition Edition Christopher Bovis Free All Chapters
com
https://ebookname.com/product/eu-public-procurement-law-2nd-
edition-edition-christopher-bovis/
OR CLICK BUTTON
DOWLOAD NOW
https://ebookname.com/product/regulating-procurement-
understanding-the-ends-and-means-of-public-procurement-
regulation-1st-edition-trepte/
https://ebookname.com/product/a-practical-guide-to-public-
procurement-1st-edition-semple/
https://ebookname.com/product/eu-law-9th-edition-josephine-
steiner/
https://ebookname.com/product/eu-distribution-law-fourth-edition-
joanna-goyder/
EU Shipping Law 3rd Edition Vincent Power
https://ebookname.com/product/eu-shipping-law-3rd-edition-
vincent-power/
https://ebookname.com/product/oxford-european-union-law-library-
eu-procedural-law-1st-edition-koen-lenaerts/
https://ebookname.com/product/law-in-public-health-practice-2nd-
edition-richard-a-goodman/
https://ebookname.com/product/complete-public-law-text-cases-and-
materials-2nd-edition-lisa-webley/
https://ebookname.com/product/health-care-and-eu-law-1st-edition-
johan-van-de-gronden/
EU Public Procurement Law
ELGAR EUROPEAN LAW
Founding editor: John Usher, formerly Professor of European Law and Head,
School of Law, University of Exeter, UK
European integration is the driving force behind constant evolution and change in the
laws of the member states and the institutions of the European Union. This important
series will offer short, state-of-the-art overviews of many specific areas of EU law,
from competition law to consumer law and from environmental law to labour law.
Whilst most books will take a thematic, vertical approach, others will offer a more
horizontal approach and consider the overarching themes of EU law.
Distilled from rigorous substantive analysis, and written by some of the best names
in the field, as well as the new generation of scholars, these books are designed both to
guide the reader through the changing legislation itself, and to provide a firm theoreti-
cal foundation for advanced study. They will be an invaluable source of reference for
scholars and postgraduate students in the fields of EU law and European integration, as
well as lawyers from the respective individual fields and policymakers within the EU.
Titles in the series include:
EU Labour Law
A.C.L. Davies
Christopher H. Bovis
H.K. Bevan Chair in Law, Law School, University of Hull, UK
Edward Elgar
Cheltenham, UK • Northampton, MA, USA
© Christopher H. Bovis 2012
Published by
Edward Elgar Publishing Limited
The Lypiatts
15 Lansdown Road
Cheltenham
Glos GL50 2JA
UK
Preface viii
Acknowledgements xii
Table of cases before the European Court of Justice xiii
Introduction 1
1. Public procurement and the single market 11
2. The legal framework of public sector procurement 59
3. The legal framework of utilities procurement 128
4. Redress and remedies in public procurement 194
5. The doctrines and principles of public procurement 250
6. The notion of contracting authorities 286
7. The notion of public contracts 333
8. The award of public procurement contracts 376
9. Procurement and partnerships 426
Conclusion 482
Index 501
vii
Preface
The 21st century has begun with European Institutions striving for compet-
itiveness and growth in the European Union. One of the most important
drivers for both competitiveness and growth in the Member States is the
regulation of public procurement.
The regulation of public procurement in the European Union has multiple
dimensions, as a discipline of European law and policy, directly relevant to the
fundamental principles of the common market and as a policy instrument in
the hands of Member States. Its purpose is to insert a regime of competitive-
ness in the relevant markets and eliminate all non-tariff barriers to intra-
community trade that emanate from preferential purchasing practices which
favour national undertakings. The regulation of public procurement represents
best practice in the delivery of public services by the state and its organs and
facilitates the observance of well-embedded principles such as accountability
for public expenditure, avoidance of corruption and political manipulation.
This book aims to provide the reader with a comprehensive analysis of
the law and jurisprudence which have shaped the landscape of the regulation
of public procurement in the European Union and its Member States.
In Chapter 1 public procurement is positioned within the context of the
single market in the European Union. The objective of this chapter is to
provide the necessary links between the regulation of public procurement
and the remit of European law. This chapter reveals the concept of public
markets and the economic policy dimension in the regulation of public
procurement. It also points out the policy rationale of the relevant legal
structure and the overall framework of Community and national compe-
tence. Chapter 1 examines the anti-trust dimension in public procurement
regulation and justifies the influence of neo-classical economic theory upon
the integration of public markets. This finding also reflects on the public
policy dimension of public procurement and the interplay of public purchas-
ing with state aid. As a result, the industrial policy dimension in public
procurement emerges and the remit of public procurement regulation
demonstrates its flexibility and complementary relation with other policies
in the European integration process.
Chapter 2 covers the applicability of the public sector rules, the coverage
and scope of the new Public Sector Directive, the requirements for adver-
viii
Preface ix
xii
Table of cases before the European Court
of Justice
C-21–24/72, International Fruit Co C-18/84, Commission v. France,
NV v. Produktschap voor [1985] ECR 1339 36, 342
Groenten en Fruit, [1972] ECR C-103/84, Commission v. Italy,
1236 202 [1986] ECR 1759 36, 342
C-127/73, BRT v. SABAM, [1974] C-234/84, Belgium v. Commission,
ECR 313 47, 269, 359 [1986] ECR 2263 40, 265, 342,
C-173/73, Italy v. Commission, 343, 349
[1974] ECR 709 20, 42, 43, 44, C-24/85, Spijkers v. Gebroders
353 Benedik Abbatoir CV, [1986]
C-36/74, Walrave and Koch v. ECR 1, 1123 283, 299
Association Union Cycliste C- 40/85, Belgium v. Commission.
International et al, (1974) ECR [1986] ECR I-2321 43
1423 256, 288 C-67/85, 68/85 and 70/85, Van der
C-74/76, Ianelli & Volpi Spa v. Ditta Kooy and Others v. Commission,
Paola Meroni, [1977] 2 CMLR [1988] ECR 219 40, 343, 350
688 36, 342 C-199/85, Commission v. Italy,
C-249/81, Commission v. Ireland, [1987] ECR 1039 398, 400, 444
[1982] ECR 4005 256, 288 C-310/85, Deufil v. Commission,
C-244/81, Commission v. Ireland, [1987] ECR 901 40, 42, 43, 44,
1982, ECR 4005 36, 342 343, 350
C-76/81, SA Transporoute et C-66/86, Ahmed Saeed Flugreisen v.
Travaux v. Minister of Public Commission, [1989] ECR 803
Works, [1982] ECR 457 24, 26, 269, 359, 479
45, 253, 272, 275, 345, 354, 378, C-27/86, 28/86, 29/86,
410, 423 Constructions et Enterprises
C-323/82, Intermills v. Commission Industrielles SA (CEI) v.
[1984] ECR 3809 43 Association Intercommunale pour
C-240/83, Procureur de la les Autoroutes des Ardennes, CEI
République v. ADBHU, [1985] and Bellini, [1987] ECR 3347
ECR 531 38, 264, 348, 359 23, 272, 273, 379, 380, 396, 413
C-152/84, Marshall v. Southampton C-84/86, Commission v. Hellenic
and South West Hampshire Area Republic, not reported 35, 341
Health Authority, [1986] ECR C-27/86, Constructions et
723 257, 290 Enterprises Industrielles SA
xiii
xiv EU public procurement law
Milano and C-260/99 Excelsior GmbH (HI) and Stadt Wien, ECR
Snc di Pedrotti Runa & C v. Ente [2002] I-5553 213, 214, 227,
Autonomo Fiera Internazionale di 229, 233, 243, 245, 285, 371,
Milano, [2001] ECR 3605 11, 395, 408, 487, 496
18, 41, 261, 262, 266, 293, 294, C-283/00, Commission of the
325, 339, 343, 350, 482, 484 European Communities v.
C-237/99, Commission v. France, Kingdom of Spain, [2003] ECR I-
[2001] ECR 934 29, 257, 278, 11697 301, 303, 322, 324
290, 292, 312, 315, 325, 412, 484 C-327/00, Santex SpA and Unità
C-285/99 & 286/99, Impresa Socio Sanitaria Locale n. 42 di
Lombardini SpA v. ANAS, [2001] Pavia, [2003] ECR I-1877 232,
ECR I-9233 25, 26, 276, 383, 244, 246
393, 408, 424, 484 C-373/00, Adolf Truley GmbH and
C-513/99, Concordia Bus Finlandia Bestattung Wien GmbH, [2003]
v. Helsingin Kaupunki et HKL- ECR I-1931 292, 310, 312, 323,
Bussiliikenne, [2000] ECR I-7213 346, 484
25, 274, 283, 381, 384, 406, 414, C-411/00, Felix Swoboda GmbH and
415, 484 Österreichische Nationalbank,
C-470/99, Universale-Bau AG, [2002] ECR I-10567 360, 362
Bietergemeinschaft, ECR [2002] C-5/01, Belgium v. Commission,
I-11617 205, 224, 228, 239, 246, [2002] ECR I-3452 42, 43, 44,
285, 301, 312, 313, 320, 322, 231, 240, 353, 380, 382, 481, 484
323, 407, 408, 421, 484 C-83/01 P, C-93/01 P and C-94/01.
C-53/00, Ferring SA v. Agence Chronopost and Others, [2003]
centrale des organismes de ECR I-6993 41, 266, 351
s?curit? sociale (ACOSS), [2001] C-126/01, Ministre de l’economie,
ECR I-09067 38, 264, 348 des finances et de l’industrie v.
C-280/00, Altmark Trans GmbH and GEMO SA, [2003] ECR 3454 42
Regierungspräsidium Magdeburg C-314/01, Siemens AG Österreich,
v. Nahverkehrsgesellschaft ARGE Telekom & Partner and
Altmark GmbH and Hauptverband der österreichis-
Oberbundesanwalt beim chen Sozialversicherungsträger,
Bundesverwaltungsgericht, [2004] ECR I-2549 219, 340,
[2003] ECR 1432 38, 39, 264, 341, 389, 484
268, 348, 358 C-448/01, EVN AG, Wienstrom
C-214/00, Commission of the GmbH and Republik Österreich,
European Communities v. [2003] ECR I-14527 220, 274,
Kingdom of Spain, ECR [2003] I- 419, 422
4667 207, 241, 301, 309, 322, C-249/01, Werner Hackermüller and
323 Bundesimmobiliengesellschaft
C-92/00, Hospital Ingenieure mbH (BIG), Wiener
Krankenhaustechnik Planungs- Entwicklungsgesellschaft mbH für
xviii EU public procurement law
1
2 EU public procurement law
4 See the Green Paper on Public Procurement in the European Union: Exploring
the way forward, European Commission, 1996.
5 See European Commission, Communication on Public Procurement in the
European Union, COM(98) 143.
6 See Green Paper on the modernisation of EU public procurement policy:
Towards a more efficient European Procurement Market, COM (2011) 15/47.
7 See European Commission, Communication to the European Parliament, the
Council, the Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions,
Towards a Single Market Act, COM(2010) 608 final.
8 See European Commission, Communication, Europe 2020, A strategy for
smart, sustainable and inclusive growth, 3.3.2010, COM (2010) 2020 final.
9 See European Commission, Guide to the application of the European Union
rules on state aid, public procurement and the internal market to services of general
economic interest, and in particular to social services of general interest, 7.12.2010,
SEC(2010) 1545 final. See European Commission, Buying Social: A Guide to Taking
Account of Social Considerations in Public Procurement, SEC(2010) 1258, final.
10 See European Commission, Communication to the European Parliament, the
Council, the Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions,
Towards a Single Market Act, COM(2010) 608 final.
4 EU public procurement law
However, Member States retain full discretion for the regulation of public
procurement outside the scope of the EU Directives.11 Several Member States
regulate public procurement below EU thresholds within the same act as the
contracts covered by the EU Directives and also require the use of open, fair
and competitive procedures, which have similar features to those laid down in
the Directives. There are areas where national rules and procedures are often
similar for contracts above and below the EU thresholds, such as rules for
qualitative selection, evaluation of tenders, award criteria, abnormally low
tenders, technical specifications, framework agreements and electronic
procurement. Other Member States provide a lighter regime for contracts
below the EU thresholds, which may take the form of administrative guidance
rather than formal legislation and offer shorter time limits for submission of
applications and tenders and less demanding rules for publication and for
selection of tenders.
Historically, two strategic plans have facilitated the economic integration of
the EU Member States. These plans were enacted by European institutions and
have been subsequently transposed into national laws and policies by Member
States. The first plan included a series of actions and measures aiming at the
abolition of all tariff and non-tariff barriers to intra-community trade. The
second plan has focused on the establishment of an effective, workable and
undistorted regime of competition within the common market, in order to
prevent potential abuse of market dominance and market segmentation,
factors which could have serious economic implications in its functioning. The
first plan, the abolition of all tariff and non-tariff barriers to intra-community
trade, reveals a static effect which aimed at eliminating all administrative and
legal obstacles to free trade and had as its focal point Member States and their
national administrations. The second plan, the establishment of an effective,
workable and undistorted regime of competition within the common market,
has been implemented at industry level and has a dynamic effect.
The regulation of public procurement in the European Union has been
significantly influenced by the internal market project. The White Paper for
the Completion of the Internal Market12 and the Single European Act repre-
sent the conceptual foundations of the regulation of public markets of the
17 The term implies a firm with more than a third of its turnover made in its own
country and has enjoyed formal or informal government protection. The term has been
defined by Abravanel and Ernst (1992), ‘Alliance and acquisition strategies for
European national champions’, The McKinsey Quarterly, no. 2, pp. 45–62.
18 See Nicolaides (ed.), Industrial Policy in the European Community: A
Necessary Response to Economic Integration, Martinus Nijhoff, 1993.
19 See Communication from the European Commission to the Council, the
European Parliament, the Economic and Social Committee, and the Committee of the
Regions, ‘Working together to maintain momentum’, 2001 Review of the Internal
Market Strategy, Brussels, 11 April 2001, COM(2001)198 final. Also European
Commission, Commission Communication, Public procurement in the European
Union, Brussels, 11 March 1998, COM (98) 143.
20 See the recital of Directive 89/440, OJ L 210/1 1989 amending the original
works Directive 71/305 concerning co-ordination of procedures for the award of public
works contracts, stating that ‘…it is necessary to improve and extend the safeguards in
the directives that are designed to introduce transparency into the procedures and prac-
tices for the award of such contracts, in order to be able to monitor compliance with the
prohibition of restrictions more closely and at the same time to reduce disparities in the
competitive conditions faced by nationals of different Member States’.
Introduction 7
Court to continue its rule of reason approach into the legitimacy of policies,
other than economic ones, through public procurement regulation.
The regulation of public procurement reflects on two opposite dynamics:
one of a community-wide orientation and one of national priorities. The influ-
ence of neo-classical economic theory on public procurement regulation has
taken the relevant regime through the paces of the liberalization. However, we
have witnessed the emergence of a sui generis market place where the mere
existence and functioning of anti-trust is not sufficient to achieve the envis-
aged objectives. Public markets require a positive regulatory approach in order
to enhance market access. Whereas anti-trust and the neo-classical approach to
economic integration depend heavily on price competition, public procure-
ment regulation requires a system which primarily safeguards market access.
In the author’s argument, such regulatory system could be described as public
competition law.
The above scenario represents a departure from the stricto sensu neo-clas-
sical perspective of public procurement. A policy orientation has emerged
mainly through the jurisprudential approach of the regime and the willingness
of the Court to expand on the element of flexibility that is inherent in the
public procurement Directives. The Court has allowed for a flexible policy-
oriented application of public procurement, where in anti-trust the
Commission has eroded the strict neo-classical approach of controlling market
power with the plethora of policy considerations.
Litigation and jurisprudential inferences will be extremely important in
understanding the thrust of the new regime. The role of the Court has been
instrumental in shaping many of the newly introduced concepts and in the
future will be invaluable in interpreting the new regime and pronouncing on
the compatibility of national provisions with acquis communautaire.
1. Public procurement and the single
market
11
12 EU public procurement law
risk. They also provide for an indication as to the different methods and
approaches employed in their regulation.4
Private markets are generally structured as a result of competitive pressures
originating in the interaction between buyers and supplier and their configura-
tion can vary from monopoly or oligopoly conditions to models representing
perfect competition. Demand arises from heterogeneous buyers with a variety
of specific needs, is based on expectations and is multiple for each product.
Supply, on the other hand, is offered through various product ranges, where
products are standardized using known technology, but constantly improved
through research and development processes. The production process is based
on mass-production patterns and the product range represents a large choice
including substitutes, whereas the critical production factor is cost level. The
development cycle appears to be short- to medium-term and finally, the tech-
nology of products destined for the private markets is evolutionary. Purchases
are made when an acceptable balance between price and quality is achieved.
Purchase orders are multitude and at limited intervals. Pricing policy in private
markets is determined by competitive forces and the purchasing decision is
focused on the price-quality relation, where the risk factor is highly present.
On the other hand, public markets tend to be structured and to function in
a different way. The market structure often reveals monopsony characteris-
tics.5 In terms of its origins, demand in public markets is institutionalized and
operates mainly under budgetary considerations rather than price mechanisms.
It is also based on fulfilment of tasks (pursuit of public interest) and it is single
for many products. Supply also has limited origins, in terms of the establish-
ment of close ties between the public sector and industries supplying it and
there is often a limited product range. Products are rarely innovative and tech-
nologically advanced and pricing is determined through tendering and negoti-
ations. The purchasing decision is primarily based upon the life-time cycle,
reliability, price and political considerations. Purchasing patterns follow
tendering and negotiations and often purchases are dictated by policy rather
than price/quality considerations.
Article 106 TFEU6 (formerly Article 90 EEC) represents the legal corner-
service obligations refers to specific quality and price requirements that are
imposed by public authorities on the provider of the service in order to ensure
that certain public interest objectives applicable at Community, national or
regional level are met.12 The term universal service obligations denotes
contractual or regulatory requirements imposed by public authorities upon
undertakings with a view to maintaining regularity and affordability13 in the
provision of the relevant services.14 Alongside public service obligations and
universal service obligations, Article 106(2) TFEU has introduced the term of
services of general economic interest, a term which its significance has been
augmented by virtue of Article 16 EC.15 The term services of general
economic interest is not defined further in the Treaty or in secondary legisla-
tion. The term refers to services of an economic nature which the Member
States or the Community subject to specific public service obligations or
universal service obligations by virtue of a general interest criterion. Thus,
services of general economic interest cover services provided by utilities or
network industries such as transport, water, postal services, energy and
communications but also extend to any other economic activities which may
be subject to public service obligations.
Services of general interest are in particular mentioned in Protocol No 26
to the TFEU. However, the latter does not define the concept, which in prac-
tice refers to services, whether ‘economic’ or not, that the Member States
regard as being of general interest, and which they therefore subject to specific
public service obligations. The concept covers services of general economic
interest (SGEIs) that fall within the scope of the TFEU and non-economic
services of general interest, which are not subject to the rules in the TFEU.
18 See joined cases C-180/98 to C-184/98, Pavlov, [2000] ECR I-6451, para-
graph 118; case C-218/00, INAIL,,[2002] ECR I-691, paragraph 37; and case C-355/00,
Freskot, [2003] I-5263.
19 See case T-17/02, Fred Olsen, [2005] ECR II-2031, paragraph 216; case T-
289/03, BUPA and Others v. Commission, [2008] ECR II-81, paragraphs 166–169; case
T-309/04, TV2, [2008] ECR II-2935, paragraphs 113 et seq.
20 For example, telecommunications and the postal and energy sectors have been
harmonized at Union level. See Directive 2002/22/EC of the European Parliament and
of the Council of 7 March 2002 on universal service and users’ rights relating to elec-
tronic communications networks and services (Universal Service Directive), OJ L 108,
24.4.2002, p. 51 (as amended by Directive 2009/136/EC, OJ L 337, 18.12.2009, p. 11);
Directive 97/67/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 15 December
1997 on common rules for the development of the internal market of Community postal
services and the improvement of quality of service, OJ L 15, 21.1.1998, p. 14 (as
amended by Directives 2002/39/EC, OJ L 176, 5.7.2002, p. 21 and 2008/06/EC, OJ L
52, 27.2.2008, p. 3); Directive 2009/72/EC of the European Parliament and of the
Council of 13 July 2009 concerning common rules for the internal market in electric-
ity, OJ L 211, 14.8.2009, p. 55.
Public procurement and the single market 17
of general interest have been taken into account,21 the Member States’ discre-
tion cannot be exercised contrary to the rules governing such harmonization.
Where Union harmonization rules refer only to certain specific services, the
Member States have considerable discretion in defining additional services as
SGEIs, subject to the review of the European Commission and the EU
Courts.22
It is entirely up to the public authorities to decide whether to provide a
service themselves or to entrust it to a third party (externalization). The public
procurement rules only apply if the public authority decides to externalize the
service provision by entrusting it to a third party against remuneration.
One of the fundamental characteristics of public services is their economic
nature. The funding of public services, which may emerge through different
formats such as payment or remuneration under a contract, payment of annual
subsidies, preferential fiscal treatment or lower social security contributions to
an entrusted undertaking, reveals such a characteristic. This means that public
services have a cost and a value attached to them. Cost reflects upon capital
considerations, whereas value reflects upon revenue considerations. Even the
provision of social services of general interest23 which include health services,
long-term care, social security, employment services, and social housing is
compatible with their economic character assessment.24
However, public services lack industrial or commercial character. The ECJ
ruled25 that the non-commercial or industrial character of a service is a neces-
sary criterion intended to clarify needs in the general interest. The Court
recognized that there might be needs of general interest, which have an indus-
trial and commercial character and that it is also possible private undertakings
can meet needs of general interest, which do not have industrial and commer-
cial character. Nevertheless, the test for needs in the general interest which do
not possess industrial or commercial character is that the state or other public
authorities choose themselves to meet these needs or to have a decisive influ-
ence over their provision. In parallel, the Court indicated26 that if an activity
which meets general needs is pursued in a competitive environment, there is a
strong indication that it possesses commercial characteristics.
The absence of commerciality from a public service or the absence of
competitive forces within the markets it is delivered represents a strong indi-
cation of the sui generis market place public services are delivered or orga-
nized. The first implication of such nature is the non-applicability of general
competition law. In addition to the provisions of Article 106 TFEU, sector-
specific regulation has removed the treatment of financing public services
from the general provisions of competition law and placed it within the state
aid regime.27 Furthermore, the sui generis nature of public service markets
provide the conceptual bridge to engage the public procurement regime as a
guardian of the principles of accountability and transparency in the delivery of
services of ‘general interest having non industrial or commercial charac-
ter’.28
State aid acquis and jurisprudence have validated that services of general
economic interest, which embrace the specific concept of public service oblig-
ations29 project certain characteristics, such as the compensatory nature of
their reimbursement and the need for market-oriented prerequisites for the
selection of the entrusted undertaking for their delivery. These characteristics
coincide conceptually with the repercussions of the sui generis market place
of public services: their placement within state aid regulation and the need of
the existence of public procurement as a competition benchmark.
This is reflected in the Commission’s vision to utilize state aid regulation
as a platform for the provision of essential public services through public
service contracts.30 The Liikenne31 ruling verifies the above approach, as the
essential character of public service obligations for the provision of adequate
services must be assessed by reference to elements that exceed the stricto
sensu commerciality of the venture and instead must demonstrate a combina-
tion of factors which include the public interest, substitutability of services,
price comparisons and the competitive environment in the relevant market.
The leap from the stricto sensu commercial assessment of a venture which
embraces public service obligations to the elaborate appraisal of substitutabil-
ity assessment under a public service contract reveals that the competent
authorities of Member States will choose the lowest cost service, if all avail-
able services can be offered under equivalent conditions. Such observation
brings into play the compensatory characteristics of services of general
economic interest and public service obligations.
The compensatory element of public service contracts is clearly demon-
strable in air transport services, where public service obligations32 can only be
there is clear evidence that the Member State has not selected the best offer, the
Commission may request information from the Member State in order to examine
whether the award of a public service obligation includes, in addition to their compen-
sation, state aid elements. Such elements are likely to occur where a Member State has
selected not the lowest offer in relation to the financial compensation to be paid to the
air carrier.
40 See Posner, Antitrust Law, 2nd Edition, Chicago, 2000.
22 EU public procurement law
45 The demand side often omits risk assessment tests during the evaluation
process. The Directives remain vague as to the methods for assessing financial risk,
leaving a great deal of discretion in the hands of contracting authorities. Evidence of
financial and economic standing may be provided by means of references including: i)
appropriate statements from bankers; ii) the presentation of the firm’s balance sheets or
extracts from the balance sheets where these are published under company law provi-
sions; and iii) a statement of the firm’s annual turnover and the turnover on construc-
tion works for the three previous financial years. See case C-27/86, Constructions et
Enterprises Industrielles SA (CEI) v. Association Intercommunale pour les Autoroutes
des Ardennes; case C-28/86, Ing.A. Bellini & Co. S.p.A. v. Regie de Betiments; case C-
29/86, Ing.A. Bellini & Co. S.p.A. v. Belgian State, [1987] ECR 3347.
24 EU public procurement law
Minister of Public Works, [1982] ECR 457; case C-103/88, Fratelli Costanzo S.p.A. v.
Comune di Milano, [1989] ECR 1839; case C-296/89, Impresa Dona Alfonso di Dona
Alfonso & Figli s.n.c. v. Consorzio per lo Sviluppo Industriale del Comune di
Monfalcone, [1991] ECR 2967; case C-285/99 & 286/99, Impresa Lombardini SpA v.
ANAS, [2001] ECR 9233.
48 See Commission Communication, Public Procurement, 22 September 1989,
C 311 89.
49 See the Commission’s arguments in the Bentjees (case C-31/87, Gebroeders
Beentjes B.V. v. State of Netherlands, [1988] ECR 4635), Nord-Pas-de-Calais, (case C-
225/98, Commission v. French Republic, [2000] ECR 7445), and the Concordia, case
C-513/99, Concordia Bus Finlandia v. Helsingin Kaupunki et HKL-Bussiliikenne,
[2002] ECR 7213.
26 EU public procurement law
50 See case C-45/87, Commission v. Ireland, [1988] ECR 4929; also case C-
359/93, Commission v. the Netherlands, [1995] ECR 151.
51 See case C-76/81, SA Transporoute et Travaux v. Minister of Public Works,
[1982] ECR 457; case C-103/88, Fratelli Costanzo S.p.A. v. Comune di Milano, [1989]
ECR 1839; case C-296/89, Impresa Dona Alfonso di Dona Alfonso & Figli s.n.c. v.
Consorzio per lo Sviluppo Industriale del Comune di Monfalcone, [1991] ECR 2967;
case C-285/99 & 286/99, Impresa Lombardini SpA v ANAS, [2001] ECR 9233.
52 See Jacquemin and de Jong, European Industrial Organization, Macmillan,
1997; Möschel, ‘Competition Law from an Ordo Point of View’, in Peacock and
Willgerodt, German Neo-Liberals and the Social Market Economy, Macmillan, 1989.
53 See Commission Interpretative Communication on the Community law
applicable to public procurement and the possibilities for integrating social considera-
tions into public procurement, COM (2001) 566, 15 October 2001. Also, Commission
Interpretative Communication on the Community law applicable to public procurement
and the possibilities for integrating environmental considerations into public procure-
ment, COM(2001) 274, 4 July 2001.
Public procurement and the single market 27
choice of the two above-mentioned award criteria has been intentional with a
view to providing contracting authorities a margin of discretion to take into
account social policy objectives when awarding their public contracts, or if it
merely reflects an element of flexibility which is considered necessary in
modern purchasing transactions. If the most economically advantageous offer
represents elements relating to quality of public purchasing other than price,
an argument arises here supporting the fact that the enhancement of the socio-
economic fabric is a ‘qualitative’ element which can fall into the framework of
the above criterion. This argument would take away the assumption that the
award of public contracts is a pure economic exercise. On the other hand, if
one is to insist that public procurement should reflect only economic choices,
the social policy considerations that may arise from the award of public
contracts would certainly have an economic dimension attached to them, often
in public service activities which are parallel to public procurement. To what
extent contracting authorities should contemplate such elements remains
unclear.
The regulation of public procurement and the integration of the public
markets of the Member States do not operate in a vacuum. Irrespective of the
often-publicized nature of public procurement as the most significant non-
tariff barrier for the functioning of the common market and the clinical presen-
tation of the arguments in favour of an integrated public market across the
European Union,54 public purchasing is indissolubly linked with national poli-
cies and priorities.55 In the history of European economic integration, public
procurement has been an important part of the Member States’ industrial poli-
cies. It has been utilized as a policy tool56 in order to support indigenous
suppliers and contractors and protect national industries and the related work-
force.
57 See case C-380/98, The Queen and H.M. Treasury, ex parte University of
Cambridge, judgment of 3 October 2000 at paragraph 17; case C-44/96, C-44/96,
Mannesmann Anlangenbau Austria AG et al. v. Strohal Rotationsdurck GesmbH, judg-
ment of 15 January 1998, paragraph 33; case C-360/96, Gemeente Arnhem Gemeente
Rheden v. BFI Holding BV, judgment of 10 November 1998 at paragraphs 42 and 43;
case C-237/99, Commission v. France, judgment of 1 February 2001, at paragraphs 41
and 42.
58 See Bovis, ‘The Compatibility of Compulsory Tendering with Transfer of
Undertakings: the case of Contract Compliance and the Acquired Rights Directive’,
Chapter 21, Legal Regulation of the Employment Relations, Collins, Davies and
Rideout (eds), Kluwer, 2000.
59 See ILEA Contract Compliance Equal Opportunities Unit, Contract
Compliance: a brief history, London, 1990.
60 In particular in the US, see case 93-1841, Adarand Constructors v. Pena,
1995 Annual Volume of US Supreme Court. The United States Supreme Court ques-
tioned the constitutionality in the application of contract compliance as a potential
violation of the equal protection component of the Fifth Amendment’s Due Process
Clause and ordered the Court of Appeal to re-consider the employment of socio-
economic policy objectives in the award of federal public procurement contracts.
61 For an overview of the Social Policy in North American systems, see Cnossen
30 EU public procurement law
and Bovis, ‘The framework of social policy in federal states: An analysis of the law and
policy on industrial relations in USA and Canada’, (1996) 12, International Journal of
Comparative Labour Law and Industrial Relations.
62 For example, in the United Kingdom, every initiative relating to contract
compliance has been outlawed by virtue of the Local Government Act 1988. Contract
compliance from a public law perspective has been examined by Daintith, in
‘Regulation by Contract: the new prerogative’, (1979) 32 C.L.P, 41.
63 See case C-31/87, Gebroeders Beentjes BV v. the Netherlands, [1989] ECR
4365. Also see case C-360/89, Commission v. Italy, judgment of 3 July 1992.
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
"They said I was a thief—they said I had taken
something of Lady Millicent's. They were coming to search
my box, and I ran away."
She nodded.
"Most of the way," she said. "I didn't dare to take a train
on their line, for fear they should telegraph and have me
stopped at the station. I lay under a hedge last night, and
as soon as it was light, I got up and walked on. Then a
carrier's cart overtook me, and I got a lift. It was going to
Weybridge, and there I took the train for London."
She sent for the parish doctor, but he did not come till
the afternoon, and meanwhile Bert suffered an agony of
suspense. Again the terrible question, "What if Prin should
die?" pierced his heart.
"So she did," said Bert; "but she came back the day
before yesterday."
Bert nodded.
"Yes; they said she had stolen something. Prin could not
stand that. She always was a spirit. So she ran away."
"Bert, Bert," she cried; "don't let them have it! It's
mine, I tell you. See how it sparkles! They're diamonds, real
diamonds, worth ever so much money. I only wish—"
CHAPTER XII
At the Last Extremity
Yet if she lived, would not the police be sure to find her
and the stolen brooch, and take her off to prison? Bert had
great faith in the omnipotence of the police. The thought of
the Princess in prison was terrible. Yet scarcely less
grievous was the thought of her guilt. God knew what she
had done. God's eye could see the glittering thing hidden
beneath the mattress. And God would punish sin. Was it too
late to pray, "Deliver her from evil"?
"She has not been here, Prin. You are mistaken. It is all
a dream."
"Oh no, not now, Prin," cried Bert; "you are better, I am
sure. And the doctor will be here directly. He said he would
look in again to-night."
"If he does not come soon, I shall die," she said faintly.
"Oh, Bert, I don't want to die—I am so afraid!"
She would have said more, but utterance failed her. Her
voice died away. She drew one deep breath, and then there
was a stillness which appalled Bert. He bent over her in
terror. He tried to force milk down her throat, but it ran out
of her mouth as fast as he put it in. He laid his hand on her
forehead, and it felt cold and clammy. He called to her
loudly, but her ears were deaf to his cry.
Then his heart sank very low, and hope died within him.
He caught up the candle, and held it so that its light fell full
on Prin's face. The features were set, the eyes half-closed,
the mouth a little open, and the countenance was ghastly in
its pallor. Just so had he seen his father look when he was
dead. So, it was all over. Prin too was dead! With a cry of
despair, Bert cast himself face downwards on the bed.
He was roused by a resounding knock on the door. He
started up in a dazed condition and went to open it. Two
men stood at the foot of the steps. They were not attired as
police officers, yet instinctively Bert divined their errand.
Bert nodded.
"It's true, she took it," said Bert sadly. "I have it here,
and I'll give it to you. But you can't take Prin, for she's
gone."
"All right, I'll see about it," said the man, conscious of a
queer lump in his throat as he spoke. "And now, what are
you going to do? You must get some woman to come and
help you."
"Come, this won't do," he said. "You must not give way.
Just let me have a look at her. It's all over, they tell me."
"She lives yet! I can feel her heart beat. Quick, boy,
give me the brandy, quick!"
The nurse sat up with the patient that night, for her
weakness was extreme, and she might yet slip away if she
were not assiduously cared for. But the hours of the night
brought no relapse, and the morning found Prin better.
"Ah! But she might have been!" said the doctor. "'Tis
only noble to be good. Every good, true woman is of royal
lineage, no matter who her parents were."
"And Prin was not good and true," said Bert sadly; "I
will never call her Princess again."
Just then there was a rap on the door. Bert ran to open
it. A gentleman stood in the narrow space at the foot of the
steps. His bearing was such that he looked strangely out of
place in that dingy spot, and catching sight of him, the
doctor hastened forward.
"Is there not a girl lying dead here whose name was
Sinclair?" he asked, with some hesitation of manner.
The doctor shook his head. "I dare not risk the effect of
excitement," he said.
"No doubt you are right," said the gentleman. "I must
wait till another time. I am Lord Ravenscourt. The
policeman brought me last night the diamond brooch found
here, which the girl stole from my daughter."
Bert from time to time had good news of his old friend,
Mr. Corney, or, as he now signed his letters, "Cornelius
Theophilus Grant." His hopes for his sister were fulfilled,
and she too was climbing the ladder and trampling under
foot the sins of the past, strengthened by the Mighty Friend,
whose hand she grasped as she toiled upward.
THE END.
Butler & Tanner, The Selwood Printing Works, Frome,
and London.
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK A SHAM PRINCESS
***
Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.
1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the
terms of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or
expense to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or
a means of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original
“Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must
include the full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in
paragraph 1.E.1.
• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive
from the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”
• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.
1.F.
1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth
in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.
Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation
methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of
other ways including checks, online payments and credit card
donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate.
Most people start at our website which has the main PG search
facility: www.gutenberg.org.