DOCUMENT
DE TRAVAIL
N° 276
WEALTH EFFECTS: THE FRENCH CASE
Valérie Chauvin and Olivier Damette
January 2010
DIRECTION GÉNÉRALE DES ÉTUDES ET DES RELATIONS INTERNATIONALES
DIRECTION GÉNÉRALE DES ÉTUDES ET DES RELATIONS INTERNATIONALES
WEALTH EFFECTS: THE FRENCH CASE
Valérie Chauvin and Olivier Damette
January 2010
Les Documents de travail reflètent les idées personnelles de leurs auteurs et n'expriment pas
nécessairement la position de la Banque de France. Ce document est disponible sur le site internet de la
Banque de France « www.banque-france.fr ».
Working Papers reflect the opinions of the authors and do not necessarily express the views of the Banque
de France. This document is available on the Banque de France Website “www.banque-france.fr”.
Wealth effects: the French case∗
Valerie Chauvin†, Olivier Damette‡
∗ All views expressed in the paper are only those of the authors and are not necessarily
those of the Banque de France. We wish to thank warmly Françoise Charpin, Pierre Morin,
John Muellbauer and the participants of the JRP meeting in Banque de France (2009) as well
as participants of the AFSE conference (2009) for helpful comments.
† Banque de France, DGEI-DCPM-SEMAP.
‡ University Paris12, ERUDITE
1
Abstract
This paper studies the relationship between consumption and wealth based
on the concept of cointegration. The analysis focuses on French data over the
1987 - 2006 period. This relationship is expressed in two ways: in terms of
Marginal Propensity to Consume out of wealth (MPC) and in terms of Elasticity of consumption to wealth. Three concepts of consumption are investigated:
total households consumption expenditure, consumption excluding financial services and consumption excluding durable goods. Different estimators are also
considered. Based on the MPC approach, when considered as permanent by
households, an increase (decrease) in total wealth of one euro would lead to an
increase (decrease) of 1 cent in total consumption. In terms of elasticity, an
increase (decrease) of 10% in wealth would imply also a relatively small impact
of 0.8 to 1.1% on consumption depending on the concept of consumption considered. In most cases, the effect of a change in financial wealth is bigger than of a
change in housing wealth. The results indicate that the wealth effects in France
are smaller than in the UK and US but close to what is observed in Italy. In
addition, any deviation of the variables from their common trends is corrected
at first by adjustments in disposable income in line with what has been uncovered by studies on Germany and consistent with the ”saving for the rainy days”
approach of Campbell (1987). But our results contrast with the seminal study
of Lettau and Ludvigson (2004) in the US where asset prices make the bulk of
the adjustment.
Keywords: consumption, wealth effect, France
JEL classification: E21 E32 C22 G12 G20
Résumé
Alors que les prix des actifs ont considérablement baissé suite à la crise
des subprimes, cet article étudie le lien entre la richesse et la consommation.
Plus spécifiquement, nous estimons les effets richesse en France sur la période
1987-2006 par le bais des techniques de cointégration en séries temporelles.
L’approche est comparative car les estimations sont réalisées à partir des deux
principales approches théoriques de la littérature sur les effets richesse, prennent en considération plusieurs concepts de consommation et reposent sur trois
méthodes d’estimation différentes. Au final, les estimations sont stables et convergentes et les effets richesse en France apparaissent significatifs mais modérés.
Mots-clés: consommation, effet de richesse, France
Codes JEL: E21 E32 C22 G12 G20
2
1
Introduction
Following the subprime crisis, asset prices lost more than half their value between June 2007 and April 2009. At the same time, activity and both business
and consumer surveys plummeted. Hence a crucial question for monetary policy: is the impact of the financial crisis on activity permanent and what is its
magnitude? Asset prices may impact economic activity via different channels.
In this paper, we will focus on the wealth effect in France, restricted to the link
between asset prices and households’ consumption.
Using cointegration techniques, we estimate the relationship between households’ consumption, disposable income and wealth. Aggregated and disaggregated (financial and housing) measures of wealth are considered and several
concepts of consumption are analyzed. Furthermore, two different functional
forms (marginal propensity to consume and elasticity) are tested here, contrary
to other studies on this topic, especially considering the French case. Besides,
a comparison of several estimators is derived. Following several papers in the
literature (e.g. Lettau and Ludvigson, 2004) we try to assess how much of the
wealth movements are considered as permanent and thus may influence consumption. All in all, there is some evidence of a small but robust wealth effect
in France, whatever the approaches considered.
The remainder of this article is organized as follows. In the first part, we
present the theoretical models underlying our approach. The second part describes the existing results concerning the French case. Finally, our results are
derived and analyzed in the third part.
2
Theoretical background
The theoretical models developed in order to assess the impact of asset prices
on consumption can be divided in two main categories.
2.1
Models based on budget constraint
Following Campbell and Mankiw (1989), Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) derived
from the household budget constraint the existence of a cointegrating relationship between consumption, income and the components of wealth. As long
as consumers are forward-looking, the gap between the observed variables and
their long term equilibrium may convey information on the future development
of consumption but also asset prices and income (Lettau and Ludvigson, 2004).
Campbell and Mankiw (1989), by rearranging the log-linearized budget constraint for total wealth which is defined as the sum of observable assets and
human capital, found the following relationship:
(ct − wt ) ≈ Et
∞
X
w
ρkw (rt+k
− ∆ct+k )
(1)
k=1
where ct , wt and rt denote the log of consumption, total wealth and gross return
on total wealth, and ρw ≡ 1 − exp(c − w). The ratio of consumption to total
wealth on the left hand side of the equation gives information on the future
3
developments of consumption and asset prices on the right hand side of the
equation.
Moreover, if the term on the right hand side of equation (1) is stationary, then
consumption and wealth (broadly defined) should be cointegrated. The problem
is that, with the inclusion of human wealth, total wealth is not observable,
so that the link cannot be tested empirically. Lettau and Ludvigson (2001)
modified equation (1) by making assumptions about the unobserved human
wealth. They first assume that the share ω of observable asset value at in total
wealth is approximately constant and that the average return of overall wealth
is a weighted sum of return on assets. They also assume that the nonstationary
component of human wealth can be captured by aggregate labour income Yt .
So that they obtain the following equation linking observable data:
cayt ≡ ct −ωat −(1−ω)yt ≈ Et
∞
X
a
h
ρkw [ωrt+k
+(1−ω)rt+k
−∆ct+k ]+(1−ω)zt (2)
k=1
where zt is a stationary zero-mean variable. One of the pitfalls of this approach
is that ω cannot be observed. However, if the return on wealth and expected consumption growth are assumed to be stationary, cayt is stationary as well. This
implies a cointegration relationship between log consumption, assets and labor
income. ω can then be estimated superconsistently by cointegration methods.
Lettau and Ludvigson (2004) estimate the parameters of the cayt series following Stock and Watson (1993). In a VECM (Vector Error Correction Model)
framework, they find that departures of cayt from its long run value in the US
help forecast the returns on SP 500 stock index rather than consumption.
2.2
Models based on the consumption function
The approach developed above is very parsimonious, which makes it attractive.
However, as it uses only the information contained in the budget constraint,
it obviously misses some characteristics of the consumer behaviour that can be
assessed for instance via the complete analysis of the consumer’s program at the
aggregate level. Moreover, the analytical resolution of the consumer’s program
may lead to a different functional link between consumption and wealth. Three
features seem important in that respect.
Firstly, if the consumer utility function is quadratic or isoelastic, its consumption is equal to his/her permanent income and thus proportional to its
total wealth, which can be separated in assets and human wealth. Considering
that human wealth is determined by the current non property income:
Wt
At + W ht
At
Yt
(3)
=
=
+
κ
κ
κ
κh
where Ct , Wt , At , W ht and Yt denote respectively consumption, total wealth,
assets, human wealth and non property income. According to Altissimo et alii
(2005), theoretical models would set potential values of κ1 between 3 and 10.1
Ct =
1 More precisely, in the case of a constant risk aversion, 1 tend to ra
as the horizon of
κ
1+ra
the consumer tends towards infinity, where Ra = 1 + ra denotes the average return of non
human wealth. In the case of an isoelastic utility function and Blanchard’s(1985) finitely
1
living overlapping generations model, κ
≈ σ · ρ + (1 − σ) · ra + π where ρ, σ and π respectively
denote the subjective discount rate, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (the inverse
of risk aversion) and the constant probability of death. Usual values of these parameters lead
to the range mentioned before.
4
Secondly, households consume housing services whereas they do not consume
services from their non housing assets. In autarky, households are either renters
or owners. If housing prices rise, owners are better off, whereas renters (or
future owners) are worse off, preferring that housing prices fall. Thus housing
prices play a role in the distribution of wealth, but not necessarily on aggregate
consumption, if all consumers have the same utility function for example. The
only potential source of wealth effect is a bubble in the housing market. In
the recent literature, both Muellbauer (2008)2 and Buiter (2008)3 stress the
difference between both kind of assets. The results above are partly due to the
fact that the financial markets are assumed to be perfect. Credit constraints
may change the role of housing prices on consumption in two opposite ways.
Credit constraints for the first time buyers, who must save for the minimum
deposit required to get onto the owner-occupied housing ladder, oblige the young
to save all the more as prices are high. Thus, these constraints reinforce the
negative impact of housing prices on consumption, compared to the results
of the theoretical models developed above, but consumption smoothing is not
affected. On the contrary, higher housing prices boost home equity loans and
consumption in some countries such as the US, where housing wealth may be
used as collateral to buy consumer goods.
Thirdly, Carroll, Otsuka, Slacalek (2006) remind that taxes4 , demographics,
productivity growth, financial structure and regulation, interest rates, social
insurance among others have changed, so that the cointegrating vector between
consumption, income and wealth may not be stable. Indeed, Rudd and Whelan
(2006) do not find any cointegrating vector for the US. Muellbauer (2008) and
Barrell and Davis (2007) insist on the fact that the estimation of wealth effects
may be biased by omitted variables. These previous studies lead us to carefully
assess the robustness of our results, both over time and by controlling for omitted
variables.
3
Wealth effect approach debate and empirical
estimations for France
We first discuss the respective merits of consumption elasticities and marginal
propensity to consume out of wealth as measures of wealth effect and then, in
the light of the previous debate, the existing literature for France.
3.1
Elasticities versus marginal propensity to consume
As seen in section 2, the effect of wealth on consumption may be measured via
two methods, which have been indifferently developed by various authors. One
measure is the elasticity of consumption to wealth (section 2.1), which is the
percentage change of consumption to be expected after a 10 percentage point
2 In a life-cycle permanent income model for a single representative agent where the future
relative price of housing is expected to be constant.
3 In a more developed framework, such as the general equilibrium model where there is no
life-cycle-related effects on the demand for housing service (the Yaari-Blanchard overlapping
generations model).
4 In France, owner occupiers do not pay taxes on their housing and can even deduct part
of the interests paid for housing loans from income taxes. On the other hand, transactions on
housing are taxed.
5
change in wealth. The other measure (section 2.2) is the marginal propensity to
consume (mpc) out of wealth, which is the marginal increase in consumption in
euro due to a marginal increase in wealth of 1 euro. Formally, these measures,
elasticity and mpc, are respectively defined by:
∂C
C
ǫC/A = ∂A
and mpc = ∂C
∂A
A
If asset prices are unchanged relative to consumer prices, the elasticity may
be deduced from mpc by: ǫC/A = mpc · C
A
The two different measures are equivalent as far as the ratio of consumption
to assets ( C
A ) is stable. But this is not the case: the ratio of net wealth or
housing wealth over consumption in France varied from respectively 3.9 and 2.6
in 1980 to 8.2 and 5.9 in 2007. Therefore, the specification choice is not without
consequences on the results.
From a technical point of view, there are pros and cons for each approach.
• Elasticities are preferred by econometricians because of the good properties of estimation in log. There is a long term log-linear equilibrium (ie
consumption, income and wealth grow at the same rate), provided that the
sum of the two elasticities of consumption to wealth and to income is equal
to 1, as shown in appendix 6.3.2, which can be tested. One disadvantage
is, the equilibrium cannot be derived in an analytical way. Muellbauer
and Lattimore (1995) and Altissimo et alii (2005) show that the log-linear
specification leads to problems, especially when we try to estimate the
impact of different kinds of wealth on consumption.
• The marginal propensity to consume is preferred by modelers because the
long term equilibrium can be derived analytically, as shown in appendix
6.3.1.
3.2
Empirical results for France
Empirical work on the wealth effect in France has only been conducted on
macro-data, because there is no common source of micro-data on households
consumption, income and wealth. The estimations for the long term impact are
presented in table 1. The various methodologies used across studies, as well as
the sample chosen, may impact the results and are pointed out hereafter.
Table 1: Long term impact of wealth on consumption in France
Sample
MPC
Elasticity
Studies Wealth
total
financial
housing
total
financial
Aviat et alii (2007)
1985q1-2006q1
0.4
2.3
Barrell and Davis (2007)
1980q1-2001q4
3.1
17.8
Barrell and Davis (2007)
1980q1-2001q4
3.6
20.8
Slacalek (2006)
1970q2-2003q2
3.2
2.6
2.0*
18.5
5.5
Slacalek (2006)
1970q2-2003q2
4.6*
2.9
2.3*
26.6
6.1
Catte et alii (2004)
1979q2-2002q1
1.4
0.0
3.0
IMF country report (2004)
1982q1-2003q4
2.5
0.5
5.3
Fraisse (2004)
1971q4-2003q2
1.6
9.2
Beffy and Monfort (2003)
1978q1-2000q4
2.5
14.0
Byrne et alii (2003)
1972q2-1998q4
3*
16.3
Bertaut (2002)
1978q1-1998q4
4.7
10.0
Boone et alii (2001)
1970q1-1996q2
2.5
6.8
4.2
12.3
12.0
Note : According to Aviat et alii, an increase in wealth by 100% implies an increase in
consumption by 2.4%. Taking into account the average ratio of wealth over consumption during
1995-2005, this means that an increase by 1 euro of financial wealth induces an increase by 0.4
cents in annual consumption. Estimation results stated by the authors are in bold. * estimates are
not significant.
6
housing
7.3
8.4
0.0
1.9
13.1
Many papers estimate wealth effect for France in a context of international
comparison by estimating a consumption function for each country separately,
without taking into account the cross-country dispersion. To our knowledge,
Boone et alii (2001) were among the first ones. However, they estimate the
cointegration vector between consumption, wealth and income without taking
into account the potential endogeneity of the variables, which is also the case of
Fraisse (2004). Bertaut (2002), Beffy and Monfort (2003), IMF (2004), Catte
et alii (2004), Slacalek (2006) and Aviat et alii (2007) take into account this
problem by using dynamic ordinary least squares (DOLS). In some cases, the
sum of the parameters is constrained to one as in Beffy and Monfort (2003) and
Aviat et alii (2007).
Barrell and Davis (2007) and Byrne et alii (2003) use unrestricted Error
Correction Models (ECM) estimated via non linear least squares. Barrell and
Davis used dummy variables to account for the impact of financial liberalisation.
However, if they do consider the increasing oustanding amount of credit in the
second half of the eighties, they do not take into account the reversal that came
in 1991-1992, when banks restricted housing credits after having liberalised too
much. Byrne et alii also test the impact of illiquid versus liquid wealth.
All these studies estimate only the impact of permanent change in wealth
on consumption. Most of the authors find a significant impact of wealth on
consumption in France, albeit smaller than in the United States. The lack of
robustness of the results is highlighted in Bertaut (2002) and Byrne and Davis
(2003). This may be due to the fact that these papers were among the first ones
and the dataset they used stops at the end of the nineties.
None of the studies have analysed the sensitivity of the results to different
approaches. Most of them make use of univariate methods and they never
quantify how much of the adjustment to the long run equilibrium may come not
from a change in consumption, but in wealth, as it is suggested by Lettau and
Ludvigson (2001) and Whelan (2008), or in income.
4
Econometric results
Our empirical framework starts from the now well-known concept of cointegration. Two or more variables which are integrated to the same order and drift
randomly are said to be cointegrated if there exists a linear combination between them which is stationary; in this case the series can deviate from the
equilibrium in the short run but will return to it in the long run.
Concerning the data we used in this analysis (see appendix, tables 7a and
7b), most of them come from financial and non financial quarterly national accounts (Institut National de la Statistique et des Etudes Economiques, INSEE5 ,
2008 and Banque de France, 2008). As developed in the first section, income is
the flow of human wealth and thus is measured here by disposable income net
of property and housing (imputed rents) income.
Three concepts of consumption are of interest. Total households expenditure
is the most popular one.6 However, as income is net of property income and
5 INSEE
is the French National Statistic Institute.
for households expenditures excluding housing services were also computed, as
housing services might not be well measured. They are also available on request; they are
very close to that of total households consumption expenditure as long as a trend is added
6 Results
7
in particular net of FISIM (Financial Intermediation Services Indirectly Measured), we considered also consumption excluding financial services.7 Finally,
textbooks usually stress that simple consumer models consider a separable consumption utility function and exclude liquidity constraints so that they are more
adapted to describe non durable consumption than overall consumption. We
then tested consumption excluding durables, although wealth was not adjusted
for the stock of durables.8
As explained above, the link between consumption and wealth may be expressed in two manners: marginal propensity to consume (MPC hereafter) and
elasticities. While only the second approach is analyzed in most empirical studies, we test and estimate both in the following sections.
4.1
Empirical MPC model investigation
We first investigate the existence of a long run relationship along the MPC
pattern over 1987-2006. Although the data set starts in 1978, the estimation
period starts in 1987, to avoid the financial liberalisation episode (lifting of
credit controls...). In this case, based on the equation (3) in section 2.2, the
following relationship is analyzed:
Ct
At−1
Ct
Ht−1
Ft−1
=α+β
+ ǫor
=α+β
+γ
Yt
Yt
Yt
Yt
Yt
(4)
where α is a constant and β the marginal propensity to consume out of
wealth. In the first step, we use At as the aggregate non human wealth, in a
second step, we test its disaggregation in two different components: housing Ht
and financial wealth Ft .
Before testing the existence of one or more cointegration relationship(s), we
need to investigate the order of integration of the series. They are the ratio over
income net of property income of total consumption/non durable consumption/consumption net of financial services consumption, financial wealth and
housing wealth/total wealth. Usual unit root tests - Augmented Dickey-Fuller
(ADF, 1979) and DF-GLS from Elliot Rothenberg Stock (ERS, 1996) are performed using the usual selection criteria (LR, AIC, SIC, HQ).9 Note that the
last one is the most powerful and has been found to dominate the others under
certain conditions.
Table 9 (see appendix) outlines the usual unit root statistics results for consumption and wealth ratios. Following the usual unit root tests, we do not reject
the null hypothesis of unit root at 1% apart from the housing wealth/income
to estimations. The estimates for this trend are in line with the relative evolution of rents
compared to overall deflator.
7 These FISIM behave erratically particularly since 2000 in line with the difference between
long term and short term interest rates, which may not be relevant for consumption behavior.
Financial services represent only 5 to 7.5% of total consumption.
8 It is difficult to assess the impact of this lack of adjustment on the estimated mpc and
elasticity, as the dynamics of the stock of durables is different from that of wealth.
9 It is well known that the determination of the number of lags is very important because
unit root tests are sensitive to it. The number of lags is determined by comparing the different
criteria.
8
ratio.10 In the wealth income ratio series (in level and difference), one or two
structural breaks seem nevertheless present. To avoid problems of bias rejections
and to take account potential structural breaks, we performed the endogenous
two-break LM unit root test derived in Lee and Strazicich (2003). This test is
an extension of the LM unit root test developed by Schmidt and Phillips (1992).
As compared with the Zivot and Andrews (1992) test assuming no break under the null, the Lee and Strazicich one allows for breaks both under the null
and the alternative hypothesis. The results of the LM unit root test with two
structural breaks are reported in table 10. According to it, the unit root of the
housing wealth/income ratio is rejected at the 5% level. Hence, the unit root
test of Lee and Strazicich (2003) provides evidence in favor of the stationarity
of the housing wealth ratio in difference. All of the series are therefore I(1) and
cointegration methods are warranted in our view. Note finally that considering
the other series (consumption and financial wealth ratios), the conclusions are
similar when the unit root with breaks tests are used.
Using the Johansen (1988) methodology, we test the existence of the exact
number of cointegrating relationships in a multivariate VAR (Vector AutoRegressive) model by performing the Johansen and Juselius Trace and Maximum
Eigenvalue Statistics. Considering both nondurable consumption and net of financial services consumption ratios during 1987-2006, we find strong evidence
of the existence of a cointegrating vector among the ratio of consumption and
the aggregate wealth ratio.We also find strong evidence of a single cointegrating
vector among the consumption ratio and the disaggregated wealth ratio. On
both data sets, one can reject indeed the null hypothesis of no cointegration
at the 1% level. (In addition, these conclusions are robust to the cointegration
recursive test we performed. The tests are not reported here but available upon
request). We can consequently estimate this cointegrating vector in order to
evaluate the marginal propensity to consume.
There are two main cointegration approaches to estimate the long-run model
(3): single equation approaches and multivariate VAR approaches. The oldest
single equation approach is the Engle and Granger 2 step method (1987) which
consists in using OLS to obtain a cointegrating vector (or a long-run estimate)
and then testing for cointegration using ECM cointegration tests. Indeed, OLS
provide superconsistent estimates when the data seem to support the assumption of a single cointegration vector. However, we have to assume that all
regressors are exogenous, which is not the case as the dynamics of wealth and
income depends on that of consumption. An estimation method taking into account the possible endogeneity of the regressors (wealth, income) and improving
the Engle and Granger single equation approach is thus needed. We consequently performed the DOLS method proposed by Stock and Watson (1993)
via a dynamic OLS (DOLS) regression and the VECM Johansen approach by
ML (Maximum Likelihood) estimation in line with Johansen (1995). Note that
in small sample, the DOLS estimator is more precise, as it has a smaller mean
squared-error than the MLE, see Stock and Watson (1993). In order to test the
stability of the long term results, a Generalized Least Squares (GLS) system
10 Only non durable consumption and excluding financial services consumption specifications
are presented in table 9 because the total consumption expenditure ratio is stationary. Therefore, no long run relationship in the equation (3) is possible considering the total consumption
concept.
9
approach is also proposed for comparison11 .
The following table 3 summarizes the estimated cointegrating vectors:
Table 3: Estimates of long run MPC
Total Wealth
Wealth 1
Wealth 2
Disagr. Wealth
Housing wealth 1
Housing wealth 2
Financial wealth 1
Financial wealth 2
OLS
1.83 (0.73)
3.06 (1.22)
OLS
0.83 (0.33)
0.79 (0.32)
4.55 (1.82)
11.93 (4.77)
DOLS
1.73* (0.69)
3.45* (1.38)
DOLS
4.33* (1.73)
1.74* (0.70)
4.43* (1.77)
9.71* (3.88)
VECM-ML
1.79* (0.72)
3.27* (1.31)
VECM-ML
2.76* (1.10)
0.96 (0.38)
4.40* (1.76)
9.51* (3.80)
VECM-GLS
0.437* (0.17)
1.329 (0.53)
VECM-GLS
2.73* (1.09)
0.85 (0.34)
4.58* (1.83)
9.8* (3.92)
*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively and (.) indicate the
annualized results that is the increase in cents in annual consumption induced by an increase by
one euro in wealth.
3 or 6 lags for disaggregate, 1 or 2 lags for aggregate. We do not introduce any deterministic
term in the VECM model.
1=nondurable consumption ratio 2= excluding financial consumption ratio
Our results seem rather robust to the estimator used. We describe our
methodology for the elasticity approach before concluding for both sets of results.
4.2
Logarithm or elasticity approach
Following the Lettau and Ludvingson (2001) approach presented in 2.1, we
estimate here:
ct = α + β1 at−1 + β2 yt + ǫ or ct = α + β1 ft−1 + β2 ht−1 + β3 yt ,
(5)
where c, a , f , h, y are the log of the consumption, aggregate non human
wealth, financial wealth, housing wealth and disposable income.12
The time series properties of the log variables are first tested. The study of
the non stationary properties of the variables is crucial in the investigation of
cointegration relationships. We find evidence in favour of a single unit root test
in the stochastic process of most log variables (see table 9). Nevertheless, the
housing wealth seems to be integrated of order two while the other variables are
integrated of order one, whatever the deflator considered. As in the previous
section, the Lee and Strazicich unit root test (2003) test was performed to
check this conclusion. The results of table 10 show that the log of the real
housing wealth considering the non durable consumption concept is difference
stationary at 10% level. However, the housing wealth deflated by consumption
excluding financial services is still I(2). Thereafter we will test the existence of
a cointegrating relationship between consumption, disposable income, financial
wealth and housing wealth in a ”‘disaggregated”’ analysis.
11 This
remark is analysed in section 4.3.
f , h, y are computed as the value deflated by the deflator coherent with the concept
of consumption used.
12 a,
10
As in the previous approach, Johansen and Juselius Trace and Maximum
Eigenvalue statistics are performed. Some evidence of two cointegrating relationships arises in aggregate and disaggregate analysis (statistic values are not
reproduced here). More over, the sum of the elasticity of income and wealth is
far from one in most cases, which shows the weakness of this approach. It is
indeed particularly true for our estimations concerning consumption excluding
durable goods, but this variable is integrated with total consumption with an
elasticity of 0.9, which explains why elasticities with income and wealth are so
low in that case.
Table 4: Estimates of the long run elasticity of total consumption
Total Wealth
Wealth
Income
Disagr. Wealth
Housing
Financial
Income
DOLS
0.11*
0.66*
VECM-ML
0.10*
0.75*
VECM-GLS
0.11*
0.75*
0.08*
0.08*
0.63*
0.08*
0.09*
0.62*
0.08*
0.09*
0.60*
*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively
2 lags for disaggregate (results no sensitive), 2 lags for aggregate
Table 5: Estimates of the long run elasticity of non-durables consumption
Total Wealth
Wealth
Income
Disagr. Wealth
Housing
Financial
Income
DOLS
0.08**
0.90*
VECM-ML
0.08*
0.58*
VECM-GLS
0.09
0.53*
0.05*
0.11*
0.73*
0.06*
0.10*
0.63*
0.06*
0.12*
0.62*
*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively
6 or 1 lags for disaggregate (results no sensitive), 5 lags for aggregate
Table 6: Estimates of the long run elasticity of total consumption excluding
financial services
Total Wealth
Wealth
Income
Disagr. Wealth
Housing
Financial
Income
DOLS
0.08*
0.92*
VECM-ML
0.07*
0.67*
VECM-GLS
0.08*
0.65*
0.08*
0.11*
0.65*
0.06*
0.12*
0.66*
0.06*
0.13*
0.64*
*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively
2 lags for disaggregate and aggregate wealth
Considering long term relationship between log of total/non durable consumption, wealth (total and disaggregated) and income, it is possible to outline
11
the joint dynamics of these variables by a vector error correction model. The
vector of estimated adjustments (or loading) coefficients associated with the
long run relationship, which are also the coefficients on the lagged cointegrating
residuals, is the most interesting feature of the dynamics analysis (that is the
reason why all the coefficients of the lagged variables are not reproduced here).
Our results suggest that any deviations of the variables from their common
trends are corrected at first by adjustments in disposable income. The coefficient of adjustment for wealth is only slightly significant in one case (elasticity
of non durable consumption) and always smaller than that of income. This is
in line with the study for Germany conducted by Hamburg et al. (2006) but in
contrast with the seminal study of Lettau and Ludvigson (2001, 2004) for the
US, where asset prices adjusted.
Table 7: Coefficients of the lagged cointegrating residuals
MPC Consumption to income ratio Wealth to income ratio
1
-0.19*
0.001
2
-0.38*
-0.0007
Elasticity
Consumption
Wealth
1
-0.24*
0.56***
2
-0.24*
0.25
3
-0.07
0.27
Income
0.66***
0.66*
0.72*
*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively
1=nondurable consumption ratio 2=excluding financial consumption ratio 3=total consumption
ratio
4.3
Main conclusions of both approaches
Overall, estimates are in general statistically significant and economically plausible in terms of sign and magnitude of estimated coefficients given the level of
interest rates (Altissimo et alii, 2005).
Robustness tests and stability analysis are performed for both approaches.
First, eigenvalue recursive and CUSUM tests suggest that the estimated relationship between consumption and wealth (disaggregated or not) is rather stable
over the sample period (squared CUSUM tests are presented in appendix). Second, Portmanteau and LM test for residual autocorrelation, Heteroskedasticity
ARCH test and Jarque Bera normality test show that models seem to be robust
to various departures from the standard linear model assumptions (see table
10 in appendix). Third, the vector of regressors has been extended by adding
unemployment rate, change in unemployment rate, real interest rate and delinquency rates (considering these variables as strictly exogenous and consequently
out of the VECM cointegrating space estimated) without any significant change
in the estimated coefficients of the cointegrating vector (ie the long run link between consumption, income and wealth).13 Fourth, all the computations have
been made on the sample extended to include preliminary data for 2007 and
13 Concerning the change in unemployment rate, it appeared significantly with the expected
negative signs in most of the estimations for the elasticity approach (values stated in appendix). Results are more mixed in the MPC approach, with instability and/or the wrong
sign of the coefficient. This does not mean that the change in unemployment rate is not a
significant determinant of consumption. However, it does not appear significant in our framework where we favoured wealth effects and with a very short sample which does not encourage
a large number of exogenous variables.
12
2008. The Lee and Strazicich results concerning the stationarity of housing
wealth (not reproduced here) are still more significant. The estimation results
are also robust to this change.
In addition, the estimates of wealth effect are very similar with a given specification, whatever the estimating method, DOLS, Maximum Likelihood and
Generalize Least Squares. In particular, Maximum Likelihood and Generalize
Least Squares estimates are very close: this is an indicator of robustness in
accordance to Bruggemann and Lutkepohl (2005).14
However, DOLS results seem to draw a more realistic picture than the ML
and GLS ones in the elasticity approach. The sum of elasticity coefficients is
indeed closer to one, especially when analysing the impact of total wealth on
total consumption or on non durables . It may be due to the the satisfactory
small sample properties of the DOLS estimator - we worked with only 80 observations. As pointed out by Stock and Watson (1993), the Johansen estimators
exhibit more dispersion than the DOLS one in small samples.15
Estimates for disaggregated wealth are somewhat less robust than the ones
for aggregated wealth and need to be cautiously interpreted, although they pass
many tests. In particular, the elasticity approach may be weaker than the mpc
approach, for two reasons. On the one hand, the cointegration tests imply the
existence of two rather than one cointegrating vector. On the other hand, the
sum of the elasticity of consumption to wealth and to income is not equal to one
except in two DOLS regressions (see tables 5 and 6), which is the condition of
long-term equilibrium. It may be so because elasticity is not the best approach
with disaggregated wealth or because the housing wealth is not clearly integrated
of order one.
Finally, considering both approaches, there is some evidence that the estimated long run relation between financial wealth, housing wealth and aggregate
consumption is significantly positive but weak. Based on the MPC estimates, an
increase (decrease) in one euro in total asset wealth considered as permanent by
households would lead to an increase (decrease) of about 1 cent in annual consumption, which is equivalent to an 5 to 8 % elasticity, given the average wealth
to consumption ratio over the period 1995-2005. The estimated long run elasticity of consumption with respect to the total wealth is somewhat higher, about
8-11% (which means a MPC of about 2 cents); the estimated long run elasticity
of consumption with respect to the housing effect is very weak (at most 6%,
that is a MPC of 2 cents) and the estimated long run elasticity of consumption
with respect to the financial wealth is about 10%, which is a MPC of 4 cents.
This order of magnitude is coherent with theory, according to which consumption is equal to permanent income. Also consistently with economic theory, the
financial effect is bigger than the housing effect whatever the approaches and
the concepts of consumption used. This dampens the overall impact of wealth
on consumption as housing wealth is a bigger component of non human wealth
than financial wealth.
All these estimates are smaller than in the US and the UK, but close to
14 They have indeed shown that GLS system estimator has better properties than the dominant Johansen MLE in small samples and/or in situations where the MLE produces extreme
estimates. The convergence between the results of the two different estimators is thus a
robustness indicator.
15 It is well known that the Johansen estimates are somewhat sensitive to the sample and
to the lag length choice and that the small sample properties of the MLE are not very good.
13
the Italian ones. With the greatest importance of wealth in the US and the
UK, this dissimilarity is likely to explain the fact that the saving rate is more
important in France than in the US. On the whole, our result is not surprising
as the financing system in France is more based on banks, as in Italy, than on
the market, as in the US and the UK. Ludwig and Slok (2004) indeed showed
that wealth effects were less important in countries where finance was bankbased. Moreover, the retirement system is nearly only based on pay-as-you-go
schemes.16 Concerning the impact of housing wealth, ECB(2009) showed that
in the euro area and in France, non interest loan conditions were tighter and
mortgage equity withdrawal less common than in the US and the UK, although
some financial innovations took place in the recent past. Finally, our results are
near the theoretical values (Altissimo et alii, 2005) and near the average of the
results of earlier studies for the French case reported in table 1.
5
Conclusions
Based on the elasticity strategy, an increase (decrease) of 10% in wealth would
imply a relatively small impact, of 0.8 to 1.1% on households consumption,
according to the concept of consumption considered. Considering the MPC
estimates, an increase (decrease) in one euro in total asset wealth would lead
to an increase (decrease) of about 1 cent in consumption. Therefore, there is
somewhat convergence between the different specifications we tested here (MPC
and elasticity) in the sense that the wealth effects are quite weak. In most cases,
the financial effect is bigger than the housing one. Nevertheless, this result
should be considered very cautiously. Firstly, we only analysed the impact of
a change in wealth considered as permanent by the consumers. Secondly, the
results are somewhat sensitive to the econometric framework, especially when
the total wealth effect is considered. In addition, MPC results are more robust
than Elasticity results in our case (especially, the housing wealth ratio is clearly
I(1)).
All in all, this analysis extends the existing papers about the wealth effect
in European countries by focusing on the special case of France. This is the
first paper to compare different specifications for France, using the latest and
an original dataset and confronting several cointegration approaches and estimators. Moreover, this is the first attempt to evaluate the dynamics of the
wealth effects in France. And income seems to adjust in the short term rather
than non human wealth of consumption. At this stage, an interesting further research direction would be to address a variance decomposition analysis in order
to identify permanent and transitory components in the consumption dynamics.
6
6.1
Appendix
Data
Most of the data come from the national accounts (see table 7). Interest rates
are those agreed for new housing loans, as most housing loans have fixed interest
16 The comparison with Germany is more difficult as estimates may differ widely: Barrell
and Davis (2007), Catte et alii (2004) and Byrne and Davis (1998) find results similar to ours,
whereas Slacalek (2006) and Hamburg et alii (2008) find much higher estimates.
14
rates in France. Current series of MFI interest rates starting in 2003 have been
backdated by different vintages of data, see Boutillier and Rousseaux (2005) in
particular.
Table 8a: Data sources (1)
Series name
Consumption
Household income
Consumption deflator
Net financial wealth
Housing wealth
Interests paid for housing loans
Interest rates paid for housing loans
Default rate for households
Unemployment rate
Full denomination
Households consumption expenditures
Households disposable income (B6) excluding net property income (d40)
and imputed rents (part of b2)
Households consumption expenditures deflator
Households financial assets net of debts
Households’ tangible assets: land and housing
Interest paid for housing loans
Interest rates paid for housing loans
Write-offs over total households loans
Unemployment rate
Table 8b: Data sources (2)
Series name
Consumption
Household income
Consumption deflator
Net financial wealth
Housing wealth
Interest paid for housing loans
Interests rates paid for housing loans
Default rate for households
Unemployment rate
Treatment if any
Quarterly national accounts, INSEE
Quarterly national accounts, INSEE
Quarterly national accounts, INSEE
Quarterly financial accounts, Banque de France
Wealth account, converted to quarterly data with a housing price index as a guide
Bank accounts annual data converted to quarterly data without guide(*)
Monetary data from Banque de France
Monetary data from Banque de France
INSEE
(*) Note: see Demuynck et alii (2008), Kierzenkowski and Oung (2007), Wilhelm (2005).
6.2
Unit root tests and specifications tests
Table 9: Usual unit root tests
Variables
Consumption/Income 1
Consumption/Income 2
Aggregate Wealth/Income
Housing Wealth/Income
Financial Wealth/Income
Log Real Financial Wealth
Log Real Financial Wealth 1
Log Real Financial Wealth 2
Log Real Housing Wealth
Log Real Housing Wealth 1
Log Real Housing Wealth 2
Log Aggregate Wealth
Log Aggregate Wealth 1
Log Aggregate Wealth 2
Log Real Income
Log Real Income 1
Log Real Income 2
Log Aggregate Real Income
Intercept
-2.36 (-12.25)
-2.25 (-13.37)
3.74 (-3.13)
-2.48 (-2.65)
-1.44 (-8.17)
-1.44 (-8.23)
-1.69 (-8.38)
-1.47 (-8.12)
0.52 (-1.65)
-0.23 (-0.99)
1.61 (-1.44)
0.96 (-5.83)
2.54 (-2.43)
1.96 (-6.21)
-1.38 (-12.39)
0.60 (-4.11)
0.53 (-11.04)
-1.38 (-12.40)
ADF
Intercept/Trend
-3.16 (-12.24)
-3.21 (-13.37)
1.49 (-7.42)
0.68 (-2.20)
2.02 (-8.16)
-2.44 (-8.27)
-2.58 (-8.43)
-2.53 (-8.16)
-1.57 (-2.10)
-0.08 (-1.50)
-1.67 (-1.66)
-0.27 (-5.93)
0.87 (-8.19)
0.45 (-6.59)
-1.87 (-12.43)
-1.96 (-4.18)
-1.22 (-11.05)
-1.87 (-12.42)
DF-GLS
Intercept
Intercept/Trend
0.21 (-4.54)
-1.72 (-4.79)
-2.43 (-12.95)
-0.45 (-12.22)
5.77 (-2.82)
-1.14 (-7.51)
0.34 (-2.04)
-2.12 (-2.65)
0.62 (-8.20)
-1.84 (-8.20)
1.91 (-8.06)
-1.85 (-8.12)
-1.71 (-8.50)
1.80 (-8.22)
-1.85 (-8.02)
1.84 (-7.98)
-2.05 (-1.79)
0.43 (-1.63)
-1.75 (-1.67)
-2.13 (-1.70)
-2.09 (-1.68)
-0.13 (-0.96)
1.37 (-5.87)
-1.43 (-5.97)
6.36 (-2.45)
-1.41 (-2.73)
3.32 (-2.26)
-0.92 (-6.44)
1.93 (-10.96)
-1.34 (-12.31)
-2.02 (-2.11)
-2.20 (-3.00)
3.37 (-2.43)
-1.35 (-10.33)
-1.33 (-12.31)
1.93 (-10.96)
Note: (.) are unit root statistics (Augmented Dickey Fuller and DF-GLS) referring differences
variables. Bold results denotes I(2) variables. 1=non durable consumption used 2=excluding
financial services consumption used.
15
Table 10: Lee and Strazicich LM unit root test with two breaks
Variables
Housing Wealth/Income
Log Real Housing Wealth 1
Log Real Housing Wealth 2
k
0
6
3
Tc
B
1997:01, 2004:04
1996:01, 2003:02
1991:02, 1997:04
Statistics
-9.39***
-5.76**
-5.12
Note: Statistics refer to variables in first difference. k is the number of lagged first-differenced
c
terms included to correct the serial correlation and T
B denotes the estimated break points. 1=non
durable consumption used 2=excluding financial services consumption used.
Table 11: Specifications tests
Elasticity 1 Disaggregated
DOLS
ML
GLS
Portmanteau
0.00
0.00
0.53
LM
0,02
0,98
0,05
JB
0,80
0,00
0,15
Elasticity 2 Disaggregated
DOLS
ML
GLS
Portmanteau
0,00
0,14
0,00
LM
0,01
0,36
0,00
JB
0,32
0,01
0,49
Elasticity 1 Aggregated
DOLS
ML
GLS
Portmanteau
0,00
0,01
0,21
LM
0,00
0,42
0,01
JB
0,99
0,02
0,79
Elasticity 2 Aggregated
DOLS
ML
GLS
Portmanteau
0,00
0,06
0,22
LM
0,00
0,14
0,03
JB
0,36
0,13
0,74
MPC 1 Disaggregated
DOLS
ML
GLS
Portmanteau
0,00
0,00
0,01
LM
0,09
0,00
0,00
JB
0,85
0,01
0,45
MPC 2 Disaggregated
DOLS
ML
GLS
Portmanteau
0,00
0,00
0,01
LM
0,01
0,26
0,00
JB
0,32
0,01
0,50
MPC 1 Aggregated
DOLS
ML
GLS
Portmanteau
0,00
0,00
0,99
LM
0,00
0,48
0,00
JB
0,08
0,15
0,04
MPC 2 Aggregated
DOLS
ML
GLS
Portmanteau
0,00
0,00
0,99
LM
0,00
0,47
0,22
JB
0,26
0,37
0,01
Note: Portmanteau and LM refer to Portmanteau and Breush-Godfrey Lagrange Multiplier test
for residual autocorrelation and JB refers to the Jarque-Bera statistic of the test for normal
residuals. All results are p-values. Note that the LM test is more suitable to test for low order
autocorrelation, contrary to the Portmanteau test (see for instance Lutkepohl, 2008).
1=nondurable consumption 2= excluding financial consumption.
16
6.3
Conditions for long term equilibrium
6.3.1
Marginal propensity to consume
If the estimation of the wealth effect is based on a marginal propensity to consume, then the joint dynamics of consumption and non human wealth is given
by
Ct = αYt + βAt−1
(6)
At = (1 + ρ)At−1 + Yt − Ct
where ρ is the real total return on wealth; Ct , the consumption in volume; Yt ,
the real income net of property income and At , real non human wealth. In the
long run, the first equality insures that A, C and Y grow at the same rate.
The dynamics of wealth is described by:
At = (1 + ρ)At−1 + Yt − αYt − βAt−1
(7)
which can be expressed in terms of the ratio wealth/income:
Yt−1 At−1
At
= (1 + ρ − β) ·
·
+ (1 − α)
Yt
Yt
Yt−1
(8)
t
The ratio A
Yt converges towards the fixed point of this equation and this
fixed point is positive if and only if
0 < (1 + ρ − β) ·
Yt−1
<1
Yt
(9)
These conditions are usually verified as β is estimated small compared to ρ and
the product is inferior to 1.
t
In the long run, the ratio A
Yt converges towards the fixed point, dependant
on the constant growth rate of real income:
A
(1 − α)
=
Y
1 − (1 + ρ − β) ·
(10)
Yt−1
Yt
From ( 6) the consumption ratio is:
Yt−1 At−1
Ct
=α+β·
·
Yt
Yt
Yt−1
(11)
The consumption ratio at the equilibrium depends on the rate of return of
assets ρ, and in particular on the interest rates.
Ct
β · (1 − α)
=α+
Yt
(1 + ρ − β)
6.3.2
(12)
Elasticity
β
Ct = γ · Ytα · Wt−1
Wt = (1 + ρ)Wt−1 + Yt − Ct
(13)
In the long run, the first equality insures that A, C and Y grow at the same
rate if β = 1 − α, which will be assumed subsequently.
The dynamics of wealth is described by:
(1−α)
At = (1 + ρ)At−1 + Yt − γ · Ytα · At−1
17
(14)
which can be expressed in terms of the ratio wealth/income:
Yt−1 At−1
Yt−1 (1−α) At−1 (1−α)
At
= 1 + (1 + ρ) ·
·
−γ
·
Yt
Yt
Yt−1
Yt
Yt−1
The ratio
At
Yt
(15)
at equilibrium verifies f (x) = 0 where
f (x) = x−1−(1+ρ)·
If 1 − (1 + ρ) ·
Yt−1
Yt
Yt−1 (1−α) (1−α)
Yt−1
Yt−1 (1−α) (1−α)
Yt−1
·x+γ
·x
= 1−(1+ρ)·
·x−1+γ
·x
(16)
Yt
Yt
Yt
Yt
≥ 0, then there always exists a fixed point. Otherwise,
there may exist situations where there is none. In any case, if 1−(1+ρ)· YYt−1
6= 0
t
the equilibrium value of the saving rate cannot be computed literally.
6.4
Robustness checks for omitted variables: change in
unemployment rate
Table 12: Coefficient of change in unemployment rate, elasticity approach
Aggregated wealth, tot
Aggregated wealth, 1
Aggregated wealth, 2
Disaggregated wealth, tot
Disaggregated wealth, 1
Disaggregated wealth, 2
DOLS
-0.07 (-1.7)
ns
ns
ns
0.08 (1.8)
-0.04 (-1.8)
VECM-ML
-0.08 (-2.7)
-0.06 (-3.2)
-0.08 (-2.8)
-0.08 (-3.1)
-0.07 (-3.9)
-0.07 (-2.3)
Note: ns is non significant. (.) are t-statistics. In bold are the coefficients with a wrong sign. tot=
total consumption 1=nondurable consumption 2= excluding financial consumption.
18
6.5
Squared Cusum tests
DOLS Elasticity Consumption excluding durables
(disaggregated)
DOLS Elasticity Consumption excluding durables
(aggregated)
1.6
1.2
1.0
1.2
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.4
-0.2
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
DOLS MPC Consumption excluding durables
(disaggregated)
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
DOLS MPC Consumption excluding durables
(aggregated)
1.2
1.2
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
DOLS Elasticity excluding FISIM (disaggregated)
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
DOLS Elasticity excluding FISIM (aggregated)
1.4
1.2
1.2
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
19
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
DOLS MPC excluding FISIM (disaggregated)
DOLS MPC excluding FISIM (aggregated)
1.4
1.2
1.2
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
-0.2
88
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
DOLS Elasticity Total consumption (disaggregated)
92
94
96
98
00
02
04
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
DOLS Elasticity Total consumption (aggregated)
1.4
1.2
1.2
1.0
1.0
90
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
20
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
CUSUM of Squares
5% Significance
06
References
[1] Altissimo, F., Georgiou, E., Sastre, T. , Valderrama, M. T.,
Sterne, G., Stocker, M., Weth, M., Whelan, K., Willam, A. (2005),
“Wealth and asset price effects on economic activity”, ECB occasional paper series, 29.
[2] Aviat, A., Bricongne, J-C., Pionnier, P-A. (2007), “Richesse patrimoniale et consommation : un lien tenu en France, fort aux Etats-Unis”, Note
de conjoncture INSEE, 208.
[3] Barrell, R., Davis, E. P. (2007), “Financial liberalisation, consumption
and wealth effects in seven OECD countries”, Scottish Journal of Political
Economy, 54, 2, pp. 254-267.
[4] Bassanetti, A., Zollino, F. (2008), “The effects of housing and financial wealth on personal consumption: aggregate evidence for italian households”, in Household wealth in Italy, Banca d’Italia.
[5] Beffy, P.O., Montfort, B. (2003), “Patrimoine des menages, dynamique
d allocation et comportement de consommation”, Document de travail INSEE, G2003/08.
[6] Bertaut, C. (2002), “Equity prices, household wealth, and consumption
growth in foreign industrial countries: wealth effects in the 1990s”, Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion
Papers, 2002-724.
[7] Blanchard, O.J. (1985), “Debt, deficits, and finite horizons”, Journal of
Political Economy, 93,pp. 223-247.
[8] Boone, L., Giono, C., Richardson, P. (1998), “Stock market fluctuations and consumption behaviour: some recent evidence”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, 208.
[9] Boutillier, M., Rousseaux, P. (2005), “ Loan Interest Rates : a Spread
Analysis using French data from 1993 to 2004”, colloque du GdR “Economie
Monétaire et Financière ”, Strasbourg, June 2005 ; European Economic Association, Econometric Society European Meetings (EEA-ESEM), Vienna,
August 2006.
[10] Bruggemann, R., Lutkepohl, H. (2005), “Practical Problems with
Reduced-rank ML Estimators for Cointegration Parameters and a Simple Alternative”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 67, 5, pp.
673-690.
[11] Buiter, W.H. (2008), “Housing wealth isn’t wealth”, CEPR Discussion
paper, 6920.
[12] Byrne, J. P., Davis, E. P. (2003), “Disaggregate wealth and aggregate
consumption: an investigation of empirical relationships for the G7”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65, 2, pp. 197-220.
21
[13] Campbell (1987), “Does saving anticipate declining labor income? An
alternative test of permanent income hypothesis”, Econometrica, 55 ,6, pp
1249-1273.
[14] Campbell, J. Y., Mankiw, N. G. (1989), “Consumption, income and
interest rates: reinterpreting the time series evidence”, NBER macroeconomics annual, 25, 2, pp. 185-216.
[15] Carroll, C., Otsuka, M., Slacalek, J. (2006), “How large is the housing wealth effect? A new approach”, NBER Working Paper, 12746.
[16] Case, K. E., Quigley, J. M., Shiller, R. J. (2005), “Comparing wealth
effects: the stock market versus the housing market”, Advances in Macroeconomics, 5, 1, pp. 1-32.
[17] Catte, P., Girouard, N., Price, R., Andre, C. (2004), “Housing markets, wealth and the business cycle”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, 394.
[18] Demuynck, J., Mosquera-Yon, T., Duquerroy, A. (2008), ”Evolutions recentes du credit aux ménages en France”, Bulletin de la Banque de
France, janvier 2008
[19] ECB, (2009), ”Housing finance in the euro area”, ECB occasional paper,
March 2009
[20] Fraisse, H. (2004), “Du nouveau sur le taux d’epargne des menages francais ?”, Banque de France, Bulletin mensuel, 130, pp. 33-56.
[21] Gonzalo, J. (1994), “Five alternative methods of estimating long-run
equilibrium relationships”, Journal of Econometrics, 60, pp. 203-233.
[22] Gregory, A., Hansen, B. (1996), “Residual-based tests for cointegration
in models with regimeshifts”, Journal of Econometrics, 70, pp. 99-126.
[23] Hamburg, B., Hoffmann, M., Keller, J. (2008), “Consumption, wealth
and business cycles in Germany”, Empirical Economics, 34, 3, pp. 451-476.
[24] IMF, W.H. (2004), “Modelling consumption behavior”, IMF country report, Selected issues, 04/346, pp. 6-18.
[25] Johansen, S. (1995), Likelihood-based Inference in Cointegrating Vector
Autoregressive Models, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
[26] Kierzenkowski, R., Oung, V. (2007), ”L evolution des credits à l habitat
en France : une grille d analyse en termes de cycles”, NER Banque de
France n◦ 172, Juillet 2007.
[27] Lee, J., Strazicich, M.C. (2003), ”Minimum LM unit root test with two
structural breaks”, Review of Economics and Statistics n◦ 85, pp. 10821089.
[28] Lee, J., Strazicich, M.C. (2004), ”Minimum LM unit root test with one
structural break”, Working Paper Department of Economics, Applachian
State University.
22
[29] Lettau, M., Ludvigson, S. (2001), “Consumption, aggregate wealth, and
expected stock returns”, Journal of Finance, 56, pp. 815-849.
[30] Lettau, M., Ludvigson, S. (2004), “Understanding trend and cycle in
asset values: reevaluating the wealth effect on consumption”, American
Economic Review, 94, 1 pp. 276-299.
[31] Ludwig, A., Slok, T. (2004), “The relationship between stock prices,
house prices and consumption in OECD countries”, Mannheim university
working paper.
[32] Lutkepohl, H., Krazig,H. (2008), “Vector autoregressive and vector error correction models”, in Applied Time Series Econometrics, Lutkepohl
and Krazig ed., Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 86-158.
[33] Muellbauer, J. (2008), “Housing, credit and consumption expenditure”,
CEPR Discussion paper, 6782.
[34] Muellbauer, J., Lattimore, R. (1995), “The consumption function: a
theoretical and empirical overview”, in Handbook of applied econometrics:
macroeconomics, Pesaran M. H. and Wickens M. ed., Blackwell, Oxford,
pp. 221-311.
[35] Rudd, J., Whelan, K. (2006), “Empirical proxies for the consumption
wealth ratio”, Review of economic dynamics, 9, pp. 34-51.
[36] Schmidt, P., Phillips,P.C.B. (1992), “LM tests for a unit root in the presence of deterministic trends”, Oxford Bulletin of Economic and Statistics,
54, pp. 257-287.
[37] Slacalek, J. (2006), “What drives personal consumption? The role of
housing and financial wealth”, DIW working paper, 647.
[38] Stock, J. H., Watson,M. W. (1993), “A simple estimator of cointegrating
vectors in higher order integrated systems”, Econometrica, 61, pp. 783-820.
[39] Whelan, K. (2008), “Consumption and expected asset returns without
assumptions about unobservables”, Journal of monetary economics, 55,
pp. 1209-1221.
[40] Wilhelm, F. (2005), “L evolution actuelle du credit à l habitat en France
est-elle soutenable ?”, Bulletin de la Banque de France, août 2005
[41] Zivot, E., Andrews,D. W.K. (1992), “Further Evidence on the Great
Crash, the Oil-Price Shock, and the Unit-Root Hypothesis”, Journal of
Business and Economic Statistics, 10, 3, pp. 251-270.
23
Documents de Travail
250.
A. Monfort, «Une modélisation séquentielle de la VaR,» Septembre 2009
251.
A. Monfort, “Optimal Portfolio Allocation under Asset and Surplus VaR Constraints,” September
2009
252.
G. Cette and J. Lopez, “ICT Demand Behavior: An International Comparison,” September 2009
253.
H. Pagès, “Bank Incentives and Optimal CDOs,” September 2009
254.
S. Dubecq, B. Mojon and X. Ragot, “Fuzzy Capital Requirements, Risk-Shifting and the Risk Taking
Channel of Monetary Policy,” October 2009
255.
S. Frappa and J-S. Mésonnier, “The Housing Price Boom of the Late ’90s: Did Inflation Targeting
Matter?” October 2009
256.
H. Fraisse, F. Kramarz and C. Prost, “Labor Court Inputs, Judicial Cases Outcomes and Labor Flows:
Identifying Real EPL,” November 2009
257.
H. Dixon, “A unified framework for understanding and comparing dynamic wage and price-setting
models,” November 2009
258.
J. Barthélemy, M. Marx and A. Poisssonnier, “Trends and Cycles: an Historical Review of the Euro
Area,” November 2009
259.
C. Bellégo and L. Ferrara, “Forecasting Euro-area recessions using time-varying binary response
models for financial variables,” November 2009
260.
G. Horny and M. Picchio, “Identification of lagged duration dependence in multiple-spell competing
risks models,” December 2009
261.
J-P. Renne, “Frequency-domain analysis of debt service in a macro-finance model for the euro area,”
December 2009
262.
C. Célérier, “Forecasting inflation in France,” December 2009
263.
V. Borgy, L. Clerc and J-P. Renne, “Asset-price boom-bust cycles and credit: what is the scope of
macro-prudential regulation?,” December 2009
264.
S. Dubecq and I. Ghattassi, “Consumption-Wealth Ratio and Housing Returns,” December 2009
265.
J.-C. Bricongne, L. Fontagné, G. Gaulier, D. Taglioni and V. Vicard, “Firms and the Global Crisis:
French Exports in the Turmoil,” December 2009
266.
L. Arrondel and F. Savignac, “Stockholding: Does housing wealth matter?,” December 2009
267.
P. Antipa and R. Lecat, “The “housing bubble”and financial factors: Insights from a structural model
of the French and Spanish residential markets,” December 2009
268.
L. Ferrara and O. Vigna, “Cyclical relationships between GDP and housing market in France: Facts
and factors at play,” December 2009
269.
L.J. Álvarez, G. Bulligan, A. Cabrero, L. Ferrara and H. Stahl, “Housing cycles in the major euro
area countries,” December 2009
270.
P. Antipa and C. Schalck, “Impact of Fiscal Policy on Residential Investment in France,” December
2009
271.
G. Cette, Y. Kocoglu, and J. Mairesse, “Productivity Growth and Levels in France, Japan, the United
Kingdom and the United States in the Twentieth Century,” January 2010
272.
E. Lavallée and V. Vicard, “National borders matter...where one draws the lines too,” January 2010
273.
C. Loupias and P. Sevestre, “Costs, demand, and producer price changes,” January 2010
274.
O. de Bandt, K. Barhoumi and C. Bruneau, “The International Transmission of House Price
Shocks,” January 2010
275.
L. Ferrara and S. J. Koopmany , “Common business and housing market cycles in theEuro area from
a multivariate decomposition,” January 2010
276.
V. Chauvin and O. Damette, “Wealth effects: the French case,” January 2010
Pour accéder à la liste complète des Documents de Travail publiés par la Banque de France
veuillez consulter le site :
http://www.banque-france.fr/fr/publications/documents_de_travail/documents_de_travail_10.htm
For a complete list of Working Papers published by the Banque de France, please visit the website:
http://www.banque-france.fr/fr/publications/documents_de_travail/documents_de_travail_10.htm
Pour tous commentaires ou demandes sur les Documents de Travail, contacter la bibliothèque de la
Direction Générale des Études et des Relations Internationales à l'adresse suivante :
For any comment or enquiries on the Working Papers, contact the library of the Directorate
General Economics and International Relations at the following address :
BANQUE DE FRANCE
49- 1404 Labolog
75049 Paris Cedex 01
tél : 0033 (0)1 42 92 49 55 ou 62 65 ou 48 90 ou 69 81
email : thierry.demoulin@banque-france.fr
jeannine.agoutin@banque-france.fr
veronique.jan-antuoro@banque-france.fr
nathalie.bataille-salle@banque-france.f