Gas Emissions: Reducing Greenhouse
Gas Emissions: Reducing Greenhouse
Gas Emissions: Reducing Greenhouse
Gas Emissions
Carbon Cap and Trade and the Carbon Tax
By Glen Andersen and David Sullivan July 2009
finding that various greenhouse gas reduction sources policy is best suited to larger multi-state regions that include
must be addressed immediately and simultaneously. They multiple emissions sources with varying reduction costs.
can not wait until cap and trade policies take effect if they
A cap and trade system functions by placing a ceiling or The amount of allowances allocated influences their price
“cap” on the annual amount of greenhouse gas that can be and plays a critical role in the success of a cap and trade
released in a state or region. Emission allowances then are program. Thus, it is crucial that greenhouse gas emissions
distributed to emitting industries, which can sell or buy registries accurately assess how many allowances are needed.
them as needed. Each year, the amount of allowances given If the registry number is higher than actual emissions,
or auctioned to emitters is reduced to meet state or regional emitters will receive more allowances than they need and
reduction goals, requiring industries or power plants to can sell them for profit with no emissions reductions.
either reduce emissions or purchase allowances from other Inaccurate registries in the European Union’s European
emitters that have surpassed their requirements. Industries Trading System, along with free distribution of carbon
that can reduce emissions at low cost will reduce first, then allowances, resulted in such a scenario. Electric utilities
sell excess allowances; those for whom reductions are too were given more allowances than they needed, sold them
expensive will buy them. Trading allows emitters to reduce for windfall profits, and passed on higher energy prices to
emissions based on their cost of reductions, as opposed consumers. The mistake resulted in substantial analysis and
to requiring all industries to meet the same emissions revision of the European program.5
requirements, regardless of cost. The price of emitting
greenhouse gases then is passed to consumers, ensuring that As soon as a cap and trade system is established, emissions
energy costs reflect the added environmental damage that allowances have substantial value and can result in
may be associated with greenhouse gas emissions. significant transfer of wealth. Accordingly, equitable
and efficient distribution of allowances is paramount.
Each allowance is equal to 1 ton of carbon dioxide (CO2) In Europe, utilities passed on the cost of the value of
emissions. Other greenhouse gases, such as methane or allowances even though they received them for free. Many
nitrous oxide, are included in the cap. Allowances for economists argue that allowances are so valuable that the
these gases are calculated in CO2 equivalents. For example, most efficient method of distribution is auctioning, which
methane has 25 times the heat trapping potential of CO2, offers greater transparency and is more immune to lobbying
so 1/25 of a ton of methane emissions is equivalent to 1 than free allocation.6 Since energy prices increase regardless
ton of CO2. Accurate measurement and verification of of whether allowances are given away or auctioned,
emissions are essential to accurately setting the cap and auctioning provides for reinvestment of money in programs
assessing compliance. such as energy efficiency or clean energy development,
where both consumer and energy costs are reduced.
The First Cap and Trade Experience
The 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments required the U.S. Although economists tend to agree that auctioning is the
Environmental Protection Agency to establish a cap and most efficient distribution approach, there is pressure to
trade approach to reduce sulfur dioxide (SO2) emissions allow free allocation of allowances. Many policies propose
from coal-burning power plants. At the time, acid rain, a mix of auctioned and freely allocated credits to assuage
which is caused by the release of SO2, was damaging emitters’ cost concerns.
lake and forest ecosystems. By 2006, the program had
reduced power sector SO2 emissions to 40 percent below Price Volatility and Flexible Caps
1990 emission levels, at just one-fourth of projected Price stabilization is a key concern in implementation of
costs.2,3 In 2010, the annual health benefits from the
a cap and trade system because total CO2 emissions are
program are predicted to total more than $119 billion,
held constant while credit prices are allowed to fluctuate,
not including the value of reduced acid content in lakes
and streams.4 resulting in price volatility.7 The cost of emissions
allowances depends upon many factors, such as new
technology, weather, changes in demand and new buyers.
Distributing Emissions Allowances Price volatility can be problematic because it can inhibit
Assigning a cost to carbon emissions ensures that the cost long-term investment in measures to reduce emissions.
of activities that release greenhouse gases are reflected in Extreme price volatility has occurred in both the U.S. sulfur
the cost of energy production. A carbon pricing scheme dioxide program and the European Trading System.8
attempts to incorporate the potential environmental costs
related to burning fossil fuel—rising sea levels, agricultural Many economists suggest implementing different measures
and natural resource damage, increases in severe weather, to help stabilize prices and improve efficiency.9 These
drought and other damage. mechanisms create a more flexible cap that corresponds
© 2009 by the National Conference of State Legislatures. All rights reserved. www,ncsl.org