Mathematical Economics: Hasin Yousaf
Mathematical Economics: Hasin Yousaf
Mathematical Economics: Hasin Yousaf
Hasin Yousaf
Week 1
Course Staff:
Email: h.yousaf@unsw.edu.au
• Tutor:
References:
Assessments:
• Variables
– Quantity demanded of the commodity (Qd )
– Quantity supplied of the commodity (Qs )
– Price of the commodity (P )
• Equilibrium Condition
– Quantity demanded equals quantity supplied (Qd = Qs )
• Behavioural Equations
– Qd is a decreasing function of P Qd = a − bP (a, b > 0)
– Qs is an increasing function of P Qs = −c + dP (c, d > 0)
Partial Market Equilibrium - A Linear Model
Graphical Solution
Qs = −c + dP (Supply)
a Qd = a − bP (Demand)
Q∗ = Q∗d = Q∗s (P ∗ , Q∗ )
0 P
P∗
-c
Partial Market Equilibrium - A Linear Model
Analytical Solution
Now let the linear demand in the isolated market model be replaced by
a quadratic demand function. To construct the model, the following
elements are required:
• Variables
– Quantity demanded of the commodity (Qd )
– Quantity supplied of the commodity (Qs )
– Price of the commodity (P )
• Equilibrium Condition
– Quantity demanded equals quantity supplied (Qd = Qs )
• Behavioural Equations
– Qd is a decreasing function of P 2 Qd = 4 − P 2
– Qs is an increasing function of P Qs = 4P − 1
Partial Market Equilibrium - A Nonlinear Model
Graphical Solution
Q
Qs = 4P − 1 (Supply)
Qd = 4 − P 2 (Demand)
P
-2 0 P∗ 2
-1
Partial Market Equilibrium - A Nonlinear Model
Analytical Solution
• The solution will then consist of a set of prices Pi∗ and correspond-
ing quantities Q∗i such that all commodities’ markets will be in
equilibrium.
Two-Commodity Market Model
• Variables
– Quantity demanded of each commodity (Qd1 and Qd2 )
– Quantities supplied of each commodity (Qs1 and Qs2 )
– Price of each commodity (P1 and P2 )
• Equilibrium Condition
– Quantity demanded equals quantity supplied of each commodity
(Qd1 = Qs1 and Qd2 = Qs2 )
• Behavioural Equations
– Qd1 = a0 + a1 P1 + a2 P2 and Qd2 = α0 + α1 P1 + α2 P2
– Qs1 = b0 + b1 P1 + b2 P2 and Qs2 = β0 + β1 P1 + β2 P2
Two-Commodity Market Model
Analytical Solution
• Matrix algebra
– provides a compact way of writing an equation system;
– leads to a way of testing the existence of a solution;
– gives a method of finding the solution (if it exists).
Matrices as Arrays
Definition: Matrix
x1 + 2x2 − x3 =4
3x1 + 5x2 =5
−x1 − 3x2 + 6x3 =7
For example,
3 4 −1 0 3−1 4+0 2 4
6 7 + 6 5 = 6 + 6 7 + 5 = 12 12
−1 3 −1 3 −1 − 1 3 + 3 −2 6
Matrix Operations
For example,
19 3 6 8 19 − 6 3−8 13 −5
− = =
2 0 1 3 2−1 0−3 1 −3
Matrix Operations
For example,
3 2 2×3 2×2 6 4
1 6 2×1 2×6 2 12
2 = =
7 3 2×7 2 × 3 14 6
8 −2 2×8 2 × −2 16 −4
Matrix Operations
For example,
1 3 1(5) + 3(9) 32
2 8 × 5 = 2(5) + 8(9) = 82
9
4 0 4(5) + 0(9) 20
Matrix Operations
Exercise
Let
3 5 1 2 1
1
A= 2 1 ,B = 4 7 ,C = ,D = 0
3
6 0 0 3 0
(i) (A + D)C
(ii) (A − B)C
(iii) (A + B)D
• Associative Law (A + B) + C = A + (B + C)
Commutative, Associative and Distributive Laws
2 1 4
For example, the three vectors v1 = , v2 = , and v3 =
7 8 5
are linearly dependent because v3 is a linear combination of v1 and v2 .
6 2 4
3v1 − 2v2 = − = v1 = = v3
21 16 5
k1 v1 + k2 v2 + ... + kn vn = 0
Exercise
1 1 1
Show that v1 = −1 , v2 = 0 , v3 = −2 are linearly
0 1 −1
dependent.
a − bP = −c + dP
(b + d)P = a + c
Go Back
Theorem: Quadratic Equation
ax2 + bx + c = 0
there are two roots, which can be obtained from the quadratic
formula √
∗ ∗ −b ± b2 − 4ac
x1 , x2 =
2a
(
c1 P1 + c2 P2 = −c0
γ1 P1 + γ2 P2 = −γ0
Y = a + bY + I0 + G0
(1 − b)Y = a + I0 + G0
b(a + I0 + G0 ) a + b(I0 + G0 )
C ∗ = a + bY ∗ = a + =
1−b 1−b
Go Back
(i) Since A is a 3 × 2 matrix and D is a 3 × 1 matrix, (A + D)C is not
defined.
(ii)
3 5 1 2
1
(A − B)C = 2 1 − 4 7
3
6 0 0 3
2 3
1
= −2 −6
3
6 −3
(2)(1) + (3)(3)
= (−2)(1) + (−6)(3)
(6)(1) + (−3)(3)
11
= −20
−3
(iii) (A + B) is a 3 × 2 matrix and D is a 3 × 1 matrix. Since the number
of columns of (A + B) is not equal to the number of rows of D ,
(A + B)D is not defined.
Go Back
Consider the equation
k1 v1 + k2 v2 + k3 v3 = 0
1 1 1 0
k1 −1 + k2 0 + k3 −2 = 0
0 1 −1 0