LP-113-09-The Economics of Insurance - How Insurers Create Value For Shareholders PDF
LP-113-09-The Economics of Insurance - How Insurers Create Value For Shareholders PDF
LP-113-09-The Economics of Insurance - How Insurers Create Value For Shareholders PDF
OF THE
SOCIETY()F ACT∪ ARI巨 S
The Education Committee provides study notes to persons preparing for the
examinations of the Society of Actuaries. They are intended to acquaint candidates
with some of the theoretical and practical considerations involved in the various
subjects. While varying opinions are presented where appropriate, limits on the length
of the material and other considerations sometimes prevent the inclusion of all
possible opinions. These study notes do not, however, represent any official opinion,
interpretations or endorsement of the Society of Actuaries or its Education Committee.
The Society is grateful to the authors for their contributions in preparing the study
notes.
Foreword
1 lntroduction
l.t Why economic value?
1.2 Document structure
4 Performance measurement 22
4.1 A simple example revisited 22
4.2 Treasury function and transfer pricing 23
4.3 Performance attribution analysis
4.4 Target setting 26
t-q lncentive compensation 27
4.6 Section appendix: incorporating all frictional items 30
3
5 Managing risk and capital
3
5.1 Drivers of the cost of taking risk
3
5.2 Risk and capital management main issues 3
5.3 Amount of capital required
3
Appendix: Literature
コD Lフ
も _/亀 朴 。 亥″
Bruno Porro John H. FiEpatrick
Chief Risk Officer Chief Financial fficer
Swiss He Swiss Re
'1■ ■,1`● oぅ :● :● ●●
、 、 d)tヽ 、L'S
■● =●
The discussions that have resulted from this increased attention focus less on
iF●
=漱
■oS
p,1ヽ llaに },61● ウ aSI い■!● ぐ。 whether value should be measured at all than on how it should be measured.
by Fcc● :::、 ::ぅ o「 子OCticeヽ ′ 0(16d● ● ・`
1
"〔
While these shortcomings may not be critical in a high[ profitable and stable
industry. they have become more pressing as competition and volatility have
increased. These changes have reduced the tolerance for enor in financial
decision making. Moreover, more sophisticated maasures of value are now
required to pmperly assess.the more complex producB that insurers offer.
5 SGnEIh.r@ffioflne@.
These issues have not gone unnoticed by the accounting profession. ln
particular.the lntemational Accounting Standards Board is in the process of
developing a new standard fcr insurers based on economic valuation
PrinciPIes2.
Also from the actuarial side orfrom consulting firms drawing on standard
banking practice. there has been no lack of attempts to overcome these
deficiencies. ln the life insurancs industry. the embedded value method3
attempts to provide an economic view. However, though embedded values
address the greatest problem of uncovering hidden reserves, it is not based
on economic principles (see Section 4). On the non-life side RAROCa. or
variations thereof. have also been proposed as a posstble way out ofthe
accountjng trap. These methods are more or less straightforward extrapola-
tions from standard corporate finance. However, the standard corporate
finance toolkit, which was developed mainly to deal with industrial compa-
nies, does hot translate well to insurance companies. fu a consequence, these
altemative methods are equally unsuited for insurers,
The inadequacy of the standard corporate finance toolkit is due to the peculi-
arities of the insurance business, a topic that has been the subject of much
attention in recent yearss. The speclal role of capital as a cushion against
unexpected losses, as well as the many inefficiencies associated with holding
this capital within an insurance company - regulatory, fiscal and other iric-
tions - demand a more careful analysis. An important part of our considera-
tions will be devoted to elaborating this point.
A second distinctive feature of insurers is that they hold zsk capital. While
pooling redu.ces uncertainty, unexpected losses may still arise, potentially
jeopardising the insurer's abllityto meet its obligatons. This is a concern for
policyholders and regulators, especially sineo insurance is usually purchased
to transfer unwanted risk. Moreover, unlike bondholders who can readily
reduce their credit risk expolure by holding a welliiversified porrfolio of
bonds with difbrent issuers, policyholders generally cannot mitigate insurer
default risk in any cost-efficient way. For this reason. policyholders usually
accumulate their credit exposure with one or a fuw insureTs and are thus
particularly sensitive to the financial strengrfr of the insurer, where financial
strengr$ is determined by rating agencies and regulators. lnsurers recognise
this need forsecufi by holding risk capital. which provides a cushion against
unexpeeted losses.
l● ヽ饉rerS“aiSi r● こ゛t15,3i:1:An ξ● 1● r` らミ l■ :ヽ .
by shareholders. Thus. an insurance company resembles a leveraged invest-
Tい ,sコ in,li,:「 3,● ::、 :1条 │じ v9師 ent、 :,● :PS ment fund in which debt is raised through the sale of insuTance policies rather
t響 、
ル1と ,今 卜訳■h11準1,「 :tt,wh,:Frゃ 、い:、 than via'capital marketsG. However. two important features separate insurance
l,、:●。口,3:、 こo`re"::1,t● ●::● ド::、 ines,
::、
cti!嗜 ゛●、
メ 1)Iv o、 ′ v● :,oo議 、
:`′ 43● :」 . and their competitive advantage in raising funds.
いow sヽ 31o夕 lo:d● :,:o011ッ い lk● サ Is手 ‐
`ユ
.:lo今
:ャ │「
`1:Ohiv
On the investm ert side, insurance com panies compare unfavourably to an
l・ ぉ ぃ,“ i“ o● :ぃ ont tru瘍 ,´
investment fund. They are more opaque and operate in a much less beneficial
1-!1e icr)nori:si tax and regulatory environment than investment funds. For example, in con-
J場 Ⅲu`∼ 199, trast to investment funds, insurance company shareholders in most markets
are liable to pay tax twice on the investment return on their risk capital. These
returns are first taxed when they flow through the insurer's taxable earnings
and then again as part of shareholdeds taxable income when distributed as
divldends. This makes it difficult for insurers to create value through investing.
'h*urnrte l:t refjrrrl€d as a i.h--aF Leurlc Conversely, insurers have the.ability a create value by borrowing in the rnuch
t{;llgfng i1s1i-5 ior iivasirit nt. rl!6 less efficient insurance market, ratherthan in caphal markets. The insurance
uilrj€rHiiii(: Fr\rll r: sirnbr lrj paying u$
lQterEst (Eis ior ure u-.a ftl tl8 tunds,- market's inefficiency allows insurers to raise funds by selling policies for more
than their economic cost, ie what it costs to 'produce'them. ln so doing, they
M● nch
γ create value.
"::ヒ
Ju(1,2001,
So why are policyholders willing to pay more than what it costs to produce
the coverthey buy? ln principle, individuals could ent'or a pooling anangement
independent of an insumnce company. However, risk-pooling arrangements
are costly and insurance contracts have been found to provide an efficient
means of lowering these costs. As long as it is choaper to buy the cover from
an insurer, policyholders will be willing.to pay a premlum above the produc-
tion costs of a cover.
閂鯰ド
Marに o vaiue
an intangible component
of the
(fmnchlse wlue) which
repcsents the present
value of economic profits
from future business.
6 Alovenged i、 ′
emment"nd is an in′ est‐
-i ii:tys 5;:, y15l!i1 tffi krld$ oJ h{'rilless The return thatthey would have otherwise aehieved by investing in a lever-
e-irltF encl oi drcse dlsi*arr.q' losorhg aged fund is called the base cost of capital. lt represents the retum that
i:sks and itrsesting lhg Esir ,rroftt prt-
rilirilrF trnld clrnns or e i.'=id. lflsueertcr investors demand for the financial market risk that their capital is exposed to
cflllpaiics, h-"rr: tt-aditionnil!. not ssrralal'Jd and depends on.the inve$rment slrategy ofthe lnsurer. For example, for a UK
vaiue r)Eatiln iolo'ihesa i-& p6trs Y"1, insurerthat closely matched its insurance liabilities and used the FTSE 100
with !cr."nr sri pgrtful$ pgrFimerFa .'".Jr
index as a benchmark for excess capital, the base cost of capital would be
niq{e$ k ls lc6ible l, delem)ine }rhellsr
tfr" inw^\lm.f,r n)finag#eat Ei(18 o{ ih} equal to the retum on the FTSE 1 00 index This may be surprising at first.
b,:srnls:.rs cra&iing or dss!rBying v3!3€ " However, if a substantial part ofthe rctum on capital is obtained by investing
this capital in finaniial assets, why should this retum component differ from
T. Crpeland f. i{r:llcr, J lnunln
[i:Khreey & CstFpeo.r', lc- the return of a regular investrnent fund.2
l00c
Thus the base cost of capital is equal to the benchmark return on the invest-
ment portblio less the retum required to supportthe insurance liabilities,
known as the replicating portfolio return. This retum is comparable to the cost
of debt for i teveraged investment fund.
This would be the end of the sory were it not for the fact that investing capital
in fnancial markets through an insurance company gives rise to fristional
costs whlch do not arise when invesdng the same'capital more direcfly
through an investmentfund. These costs include compensation for lack of
transparenry and control, forthe additional costs related to potential financial
distress, for rqgulatory restrictions, and for any additlonal tax on investment
lncome. These costs are discussed in further detail below.
Therefore insurers can create value in only two ways: firsL b'y issuing insur-
ance contracts that more than cover the associated 'production' costs, includ-
lng frictional capital costs. Secondly, by achieving an investment resuh that
beats the benchmark implicit in the baSe cost of capital on a risk-adjusted
basis.
7 Economic net wortir denotss the market
value of assets less the the economic Elue ol
liabiltties (debt).
Beplicatjng Bepliaaling
portfolid . Fotiolirt
2,4 Replicatingportfolio
Having provided an overview of the value creation process, the following sub-
sections provide further ddtails on the key concepts. namely the replicating
portfolio and frictional capital costs.
ThE replicating, or hedge, port[olio is used to determine the cost of the liability
cash flows and the investment retum required to suppod the insurance liabili-
ties. lt.is simply defined as ths porlfolio that best matches8 the conesponding
liability cash flows. For example, in the case of pure insurance risks, the liabil-
ity cash flow can be replicated using risk-free fixed-income instruments with
appropriate maturities. The market value of the replicating portfolio is then
used to determine the value of the liability cash flows.
Beplicating portfolios hre routinely used in flnance to value cash flows that are
not actively traded. If non-traded assets were not valued relative to traded
ones. investors would arbitrage the difference by essentially purchasing the
cheaper cash flow and selling the more expensive one. This principle is known
as the no-arbitrage principle. lt ensures that clients are not able to arbitrage
the insurer and that value reflects the markel or shareholder, view,
Therefore, the replicating porlfolio provides the cash flows needed to meet
expected firture claims payments, to cove[ expenses. and to service capital
costs, thus'producing' the liability.
Investing in the replicating portfolio will not eliminate all risk, as it is not possi-
ble to match insurance risk by replication. ln principle, this risk component has
no economic cost because it is non-systematic. ie it can be diversified away
by shareholders. However. when insurance risk is held on the balance sheet of
an insurer, it gives rise.to fr"ictional costs, which are considered in Section 2.7.
'.t'
Option to detault and value of liquidity
For convenienci, the repliciting portfolio is constructed using defuult-free and liquid
marke-t insb'uments, In practlce, however, insurars could defauh on.thelr liabiliti*, and
it may be iossible in principle tb replicate the liability daymene usihg less liquid instru-
'
ments. ilrrise intanglble Factm reduce the Elue of the economic liabilities and the
retum required by shareholders. These technical aspects are considered in this section.
Readers not interested in technlcal details can skip this section.
.t}re
1 1 s*s" n* o[ h$mm.
"*rcm16
The insurer's optien to default
As with standard debt instruments, insurers have the option to default on their liabilities
in the event of insolvency. Foilowing bankruptcy, policyholders may not receive the
full payment entided to them. This option is an asset to the insurer and thus lowers the
value of liab.ility cash flows. As a result, the economic value ol liability cash flows corr*
sponds to their replication value less the value of fre deJault option.
The fact that the option to default is an asset to the insurer does not imply that the
insurer has any interest in defaulting. By defaulting, the insurer generally stands to lose
substantial franchise value.
llliquid assgts tend to sell at a d'rscciunt with respectto their liquid counterparts, ie there
is a premiurn for liquidity. Therefore, usinO illiquid instrurnents to replicate could in prin-
ciple lower the productlon costs of liabillties or, equivalently, the cost of bonowing
through lnsurance.
.------]
M.
d
︼
ヽ
t"11e Replcaung
■一
M載 ■●
︰
平=#一 一=一一〓
Feplicating
li。
, ,
■■●■ ﹁
+
︰
︰■
:■ キ
11‐ 、
十
■三
│・ : ::::1::
一
■二
・ ::= │ :11
■
●
茸暮::にR祓
一
There are essentially four sources of frictional capital costs: double taxation,
costs offinancial distress. agency cosfs and costs ofregulatory restictions.
Section 3 illustrates how to incorporate these costs into pricing, and Section 5
considers how these frictional costs can be managed,
Note that financial distress costs are related to the riskiness of the insurance
business. The resulting. additional return will thus be linked to company-
speciflc insurance risk or the risk of ruin. as opposed to systeFnatic risk, even
though this risk could in principle be diversified by shareholders. Financial
dlsfess costs.thus pmvide the link to actuarial techniques that have tradition-
ally focused on the probability of ruin.
Agency costs
'-ih€ iio*rnnac ln{uslry op3rsle,s a.rrl The third component is agency cost. When shareholders invest via an insur-
tglrortj rn ? tE6.r!3I whl*l Frel.J !t 3c.ir ance conpany, they entrust their capkal to managemenL who take investrnent
r&te tsyr{ueiicn cf sa!€s ! iru:rtt+$Fg iqsl
f!r. inyesics. r.tJo ruspeci tiral ihis hes krl
and underwriting decisions on.their behalf. Shareholders expect management
to tlte iidil',lrFnr)e show'l by iiv?strss to act in their best interests, but this is difficult to conuol due b an intrinsic lack
toerds {lre sscior.' oftransparency. As a result, shareholders require an addiiional return to com-
pensate them for the possibility frat management may not always act strictv in
L?hfiEr\ Sr"llDrs
Janucry l9g7 thelr best interests.
Agency cosb are compamble to mordl hazad in insumnce, which occurs when
the imerests of the poliryholder and the insurer are not in line with each other.
The policyholder is likely to have better information than the insurer conceming
the insured event and may seek to take advantage of this. ln addition. being
insured may encourage less prudent behaviour lnsurers manage this by way of
'.tい
●rw、 icヽ c9ri re、 颯 ・ me6t sharel“ :e:ヽ
「 Hミ 1“ 豫 d“ 113“ l.て `
V″ t● 11ヽ 01=ヽ ■,iヽ"【Stを X家 =1‐
mum levels of capital to support specific blocks of businessll. These restdc-
ilう :, A■ 負ミ:■ │:lah t:le Oゃ tiO:1ミ ●:::ヽ `=St tions may take the form of either conservative reserving standards or minimum
ュIc,P:ta:ヽ 'Xl'd●
し、 :輌 」■ヽ8in iコ V● urabl薔 :tal
caphdl requirements. They create additional potential costs for shareholders,
=ill、
`:、
because this capital is not readily available to support other lines o{ business.
Sclrroder:i It can only be physically accessed byselling the underlyiog business. which
Nr{emb€r 1393 generally gives rise to additional cosb that are heightened by the lack of a
liquid market in insurance llabilities.
An exclusivL focus on the total cost of capital can be even more misleading ifthe cost
of capital is measured using the CAPM, which was dsvBloPed wit'n industrial compa-
nies ln mind and focuses on the systematic risk a companytakes. lnsurance iompanies
take most of their syslematii risk on the investment side. \r'y'hatever systematic risk is
embedded in insurance liabilities can be hedged by offsetting positions on the asset
side, so systematic risk is not the.most important driver of the cost of taking insurance
risk. The rhore irirportant drivers, frictional capital costs, are not explicitly captured by
CAPIM. This will inevitably lead to wrong conclusions regardlng the cost of taking risk
for insursrs. ln additiori, CAPM provides no, or misleading, guidanceto insurers on how
to manage their cost 6ttafing rist '
thah on the total cost oi capital gives insurers a better measure of value creatlon and
also provides greatertransparency as to how risk and capital management decisions
can minimlse this cost
This is best illustrated by way of a simple example that will also be used in
Section 4 on performancei measurement The example focuses on the valua-
tion of a pure insurance risk contract with cash flows payable over two years
as shown in the table below.
'lime
Premiums 50
clalms o 70
Expenses 5 1
For simplicity, we start by considering frictional risk capital costs only. This is
suffcient to illustrate the principle. ln the appendix to this section, we
descrlbe how to integrate the other key components, namely the option to
defuuh and the liquidtty value, taxes on investment income, and regulatory
capital costs.
The figures in the above table represent expected values, and all firture cash
flows are assumed to be pald at the end of each yearl3. Hence at ioception this
'I2 Blsk €plrd ls defined as th€ amount of
contract generates a premium of 55 and incurs initial'expenses of 5. The risk
cpital necg$aryto supportfte riskto which
tte comparry is eposed. capital needed to support the confact amounts to 20 during the first and 1 5
1 3 The assumptions used Eiectthe specific during the second year. Risk capital costs are assumed to be paid at the end of
costs to the sntity. Ether than lndustry aveEge each year and amount to 2.5% of risk capital at the start of each year. The first
condttions. For *ample, they reflect the actual
sEp in determining the value added by this hypothe0cal contract is to deter-
axpeNe structuE of the ln$cr i$uing the
contEct Etherthan t}le e+ense stucture ot a mine the net cash flow payable, which is made up of clalms and expenses less
typiGl insurel Norentitfspecmc Numpdons premiums. This msh flow pattern is shown in the table below. Frictional capital
have been recommended where the ob]ectlve costs fren need to be added and the resulting cash flow discounted.
ls to detBrmine the 'alt' value of the cont?cL
Egardlss of who ffindy owns it This Is
analogous to the isue In accounting of
Since the contract covers pure insurance risk only. the cash flows can be
wheherto Elue prcpertyaccording to its replicated using.fixed-income instrumenB of appropriate maturities. Thus the
curent use, eg a bowllng allry. r;r its optimal value ofthe replicating portfolio can be derMed by discounting the expected
potEntial use,.say a pa*ing lol Howmr, our
liabiltty'cash floirvs at risk-free rates of appropriate maturitjes. ln this example,
objec{ve ls to detemlne the vatue of the
we use 5% per annum for the maturities of both one and two yearsl4.
. contEct to tle comparry that issued it re ask
Time 0 2
Net cash paymEf,ts 50_00 19_00 -71.00
Risk capital cost 0.oo -0.50 -0.38
Net cash flow after trictional costs 50.00 18.50 -71.38
lncome sffiement
Premiums 55.00 50.00 o.oo
inrestment Eturn 0.00 L.30 3.40
Claims 0.00 -30.00 -70.00
Expenses -5.00 -1.00 -1.00
Change in economic liabilities - 47.12 -20.86 6798
Result 2.88 0.50 o.38
1 6 sm n" ne ol lNutrcs.
"*node
As noted earliec for the more technically interested reader, the appendix to
this section extends this example by incorporating tre default option and liq-
uidity value, double tax, and regulatory capital costs.
DoiJble taxation costs will depend on the tax jurisdiction and on how the assets are
managed. As a rule, tax rates on invesfnent income are readily available and rnay vaiy
dependlng on the type of asset held or dre type of lncome generated. As these rules
are usually explicit, this generally does not present any dtfficultles ln valuatlon. How-
ever. additional assumptions, such as the frequency with whlch capital galns are
reallsed, may well be necessary.
Financial.disfess costs will largely depend on tie rlsk profile of the company - le on
the likelihood offinancial dlstess - and on the value of lts infangible assets or fran-
chise value. Studies of industrial clmpanies have revealed that flnancial dlstress, as
opposed to barikruptcy. results ln cosb of.dround 1O-20% of marketvalue. *ese
costs are Ilkelyto be higher In the lnsumhce industry due to the credit-sensltive nature
...
of policyholdere. An upper range for these costs is the franchise value of the company,
Agency cbsts depend on factors that are hard tb measure. such as repfi;rlon and
transparenby, Nevedheless, they can be esumated by considering marketbompara-
bles. For instance, lpreads on cat bonds. wtich.ari unfamiliar and thus opaque to
invesGrs, can be considered di representing some type of agency charge, Also. the.
discounts typlcally applled by analylts to iompanles wlth.dcess_capital bn thelr
balance sheets can be interpreted as being largely an agency charge. Based on these
types of comparison, Bstlmates oftheir size range between 5 and 2OO basis points
of capftal held.
Begulatory restrictions are akin to liquidity restrictions, which have numemus market
comparables.,These include securities that are issued with tradlng restrlctions, spreads
on private placements, or the sprdad on off-th+.run treasuries, Depending on the
nature of the resffictlons and the composftion ofthe portfolio, estimates for these costs
range between 0 and 2OO baiis points.
Thb deliluh option and liquidity value cair bb quanttfied by considering the spread bn
the standard debt issued by the insurer, orlike insurers. This spread typically'represents
an upper bound because poliryhoiders usually rank above debt holders ln the event
of defuutl lf the underiying liabilities dre'considered to be liquid in the sense dbichbed
previously, then this spreaij shoi.rld be furtiier reduced by the liquidity premium implicit
ln corporaie deblThis liquidity premium can be qudntified using the samemarket
comparables as those used for the regulatory restrlctions.
17 swsn,T腱 g∞ mm csげ ぃ 帥
『 “
3.2 Section appendix: lncorporating all frictional items
For completeness, this appendix briefly describes how to include the value
of the option to default and liquldity value, taxes on investment income, and
regulatory capital costs.
Note that this does not imply that the replicating portfolio earns this additional
return. As discussed previously. the replicating porffolio best matches the
liability cash flows and is constructed using default-free and liquid instrurnents.
The additional return of 50 basis points reduces the frictional capital costs: the
replicating portfolio does not eam it.
Time 2
Net 6sh flow after
Hctlonal costs 5000 18_50 -71.38
Time
Regulatory and tax rseryes 100
Risk caphal
Total assets 120
lncluding this in the original net cash flow and discounting. allowing forthe
defuuh option and liquidity value, results in an initial economic liabilityvalue of
65.86 and a conesponding economic profit of 1.64. This is shown in the
table below.
Time 0
Net ash flow aiter
frlstional costs 50.00 18.50 -71_38
Tax 1■ 50 -19.25 -1.14
Nst 6h flow after tu 6■ 50 -0.75 -72.51
The future tax payment ls equal to the investment r8turn earned on the capital invested
muhjplied bythe appropriate tax rate. For example, lfthe capltal invested is 1O0, the
retum 1 O%, and the tax rate 3 5%, then the tax payment would be 3.5.
To replicate thls payment we can use the followlng strateg\4 First, invest an amount
equil to tire tax rate flmes the capital in the same assat category
as the underlying
capttal, ln this example this would mean investing 35. whlch would be worth 38.6 at
year-ind.
Second, borrow by'ss-uing a zbro coupori bond with a iace value equal to the tax Ete
times thg capital. ln ihis example. the bond rculd pay 35 at.ysar-end
Hente the year-end.total caih flow on thli portfolio would be 38.5 less 35, which
-eqrials
the t6x payment oJ 3.5. Note that the yaarcnd value of this portfolio is ahrr'ays.
equal to the tax piymenL no matter whqt return i! eamed on thi: underliing assets. As
a ieiulL it replicates the tax pdymBnt.
a'.
The i:resent value offiis reilib;ting portlolio is equal to the caphal invested of 35 less
the amount bonowdd. Ai the tax will be due with Virilal certalnty, the borrowlng. should
be discounted ai rlsk+ee rates. Hence the amount bonowed would cost 33.33. assum-
lng a 5% risk-free rate. Therefore the total cost of the rePlicaflng portfolio is 1.67.
The following income statements and balance sheets show the calculation
assuming regulatory costs of 1%. Fegulatory costs are.assumed tb be paid
at the end of the interval based on the restricted capital at the start of the
interval. This calculation assumes thatthe minimum regulatory capitai,require-
ments are 5 at inception and 3 at time one. The regulatory reserves were
given in the previous section.
Income statement o
Premiums 55.00 50.00 0.00
lnvestment return 0.o0 J.5 I 3.44
Claims 0.o0 -30.00 -70.00
Expenses -5.00 -1.00 -1.00
Change in economic liabilties -66.27 -2.51 68.77
B€forltu resuh -16.27 19.81 1-21
The balance sheet shows the fuil breakdown of the liability value. Note that
th'e above regulatory capital costs are simply equal to the restricted capital at
the start of the interval multiplied by the 1% Iiquidity charge.
Balance sheet 0 1 2
Assets
Investm ents 120.00 85.00 0.00
0_33 0.00
■て
ial a痰 :eヽ 120_63 85.33 0.00
ιね力′
Zたたs
66.67 0.00
9ii9g!!trg]E!I'tv-
Expense provlsions 1.86 0.95 0.00
Deferied tax liabilitv 18_21 0.81 0.00
Double tax liability 1.15 0.27 0.00
RIsk captal o)`■ l liability O.82 0_36 0.00
Regulatory cost liabi:ity O.41 0.04 0.00
Economic Iiability
1些鮭 豊 1生 璽 里 L__型 ____型 聖 ____型
Rest"cに ld shareh● :der capita1 38.73 r4.23 0.00
unres01cted shareholder capta1 15.00 12.00 0.00
昴olコ 1 liabH‖ es 120.63 85_33 0.00
The previous sections have illustrated the importance of economic value and
the way in which economic value is determined. This section shows, by way
of example, how to structure an insuTance company's financial statements to
faoilitato performance measurement on an economic basis.
The expected cash flows at inception are shown in the table below:
■me 0 2
PBmiums 55;-_ _ q_0_._
Cialms 0
q
Expenses 1
li"irsEIsl- 20 15
Again, starting with the simplest case of zero tax and regulatory capital.costs,
providing that everything develops as expected and under'the assumption
that interest rates do not change. the value ofthe contract atthe end ofthe
first interval is as Jollows:
■mel
ffi
Expense provisions
Risk €pital coat liability 0.36
Economic llability 67.98
■rne l
Discounted llability 66.04
Expense provisions __
oqL
Bisk capital cost Iiability 0.35
Economic liability 67_33
ln addhion to the change in interest rates, assume that the actual claims and
expenses paid at the end of the first yeai are 25 and 2. reipectively, rather
than 30 and 1 as expected. The corresponding economic income statement
is shown below.
■mel
Premiums 50.00
lryestment rqturn
{replicating portfolio) 1.71
Claim● -25.00
Expenses -2.00
Change in economlc liabllities - 20.21
Result 4.50
Note thatthe investment return has reduced from 2,36 in the projected
income statement calculated at inception to 1.71. This.reflects the value
reduction ofthe repllcating portfolio due to the increase in interest rdres. Note.
howeveLthatthe change in economic liabilities is now - 20.21, comparedto
the expected value of - 20.86 at time zero. The replicating portfolio therefore
immunises the result from changes in interest rates.
Economic B-S
lnvestments B-S
/ Treasury B-S UndeMriting B-S
躙
TAA and stock seleqtion
+
Oveall risk tolerance
+
lnsumnce,
repliction risk
The treasury function determines the level of financlal risk that the company
should take for stategic reasons by specifying the SAA benchmark for the
invesfnent function. As a result the treasury balance sheet is comprlsed of
assets represented by a loan to the investment funstion of the SAA i:ortfolio
and liabilities represented by bonowing from the underwflting function of the
rcplicating portfo.lio. Therefore. the treasury function isolates the impact of the
strategic asset-liability mismatching decision. The shareholder capital. or
equity. in the company resides in the treasury balance sheet Note that by
specifying the SA,A, tre tredsury function tacitly determines the base cost of
capital.
‐
lncome statement :iotal lnsuEnce lnvestment Treasury
Irsrrqri-- 50.00 50.00
Investment retum 12.00 1.71 12.00 -1.71
Claims -25.00 -25.00
Expenses -2.00 -2.00
Change in liabilities - 20-21 -20.21
Fesult 14.79 4.50 12.00 -1.71
The insurance functjon receives the retum on the replicating portfolio from the
teasury function. The lnvestment function receives the total investment retum
and is charged with the return on the SAA benchmark. The treasury function
is.not a profit centre; it is merely used to iransfur payments between the
investrnerfi and insurance.functions. h pays out the return on the replicating
portfolio to the insurance function. subsequently receives the return on the
SAA benchmark 1 0.80, and is charged with the overall base cost of caphal
Note that, in this example. the expenses of the investment function have been
included in the insurance function's. expenses. This is becauso the insurance
function. is assumed to pay a fee to the investment function that precisely
matches their expenses. ln practice, these fues and expenses may be explic-
itly reported to assess whetherthe additional expenses associated with active
management are justified by additional retums.
The appendix to this sBstion shows howto include the option to default and
the value of liquidity;double taxation costs and regulatory capital costs.
25 smng.Ihemoomansrrc
4,3 Performanceattributionanalysis
While the economic income statement records the overall result it is generally
insufficientto fully explain it. This difficulty is exacerbated if multiple business
lines; with contracts having different inception dates, are consolidated together
in a single statement. To address this, a performance attribution analysis is
required.
The franchise value of an insurer provides an overall yardstick for value cre.
ation, but h says nothing about when this economic profit is expected to arise
or which units are expected to dellver it. lt is possible to estimate the annual
profit expectations by multiplying the frhnchise value by a suitable discount
rate, which reflects cunent long-term interest rates and a systematic risk pre-
mium associated with realising firture new business sales. This approach
assumes that the franchise value reflects a constant profit stream paid in
perpetuity. However, there is no mechanistic way of seffing proft targets for
individual business units.
The targets for individual business units should be based on a range of con-
siderations relating to the cunent and likely future competitive state of the
local insurance market. This is. and always has been, one o-f the key tasks of
manaQement to Judge the level of profit that maximlses long-term value.
These targets should be benchmarked against other companies operatinj in
similar circumstances, if possible. They should also be added up and com-
4,5 lncentivecompensation
Having an incentive compqnsation system linked to economic profit is not only
an essential part of encouraging value cfeation. but is also vhal for risk man-
agement. The primary cause of financial fiascos is usually a misalignment of
incentives.
For employees below the line management level, incentives based upon tie
economic profit produced bytheir business units are less effective. This is
because the impact of an individual bn the performance of the group is dituted.
A more effective incentive system at this level would identily the drivers of
profit that an individual can impact and then link compensation to those drivers
only. For example, in companies where the underwriting function is separate
from the marketing function, it is advisable to implement a two-stage incentive
system. Underwriters calculate the economic value of insurance contracts.
This economic value is used as a benchmark to measure the performance of
the markoting unit Marketing staff are rewarded for selling insurance above
this economic value. Underwriters are rewa[ded lor producing ex artg risk
prices that are in line whh their ex posr costs. ln this incentive system, it is
important that the incentives for underwriters be symmetric - ie they are
penalised when the expost cost is either hlgher or lower than their ex arte
price. ln irractice, this implies a high baseline bonus that is subsequently
reduced to the extent that the pdce was higher or lower than cost
Embedded Value
The.embedded_value method is most popularwith British life insurance companies. lt
calculates the value of exis'ting business, termed in-force value, as the discounted
tuture statutory profrts that are expected to emerge on thls business. The risk dlscount
rate usbd in this calculatioh is intended to represent the insuier's overall cost of capital
and is typically around 3% above risk-free rates. The embedded value ls then given by
the sum of the in-force value and the market value of the i;tatutory shdreholder capital.
The reason given for basing fie embedded value calculation on statutory accounB is
that they determine when the capltal is avallable for distribution.
The embedded value method is a special case oithe economic iramework described
in this publication. lt can be derived by using expected earned rates on the backing
assets rathei than spot forward yields, by setting the rlsk capital costs to zero, and by
setting the i'egulatory capital cost to the difference between the risk discount rate and'
the exp,ected earned, rate. This indicates that the embedded value method is noi based
on ec6nomic principies for the following realohs: . .
Firstly, usiog the embddded value method, value is based on the ccimposrtion ofthe
.backing assets rather than on the ilsk characteristics of t'ne cash flows being valued,
This is because the projected statutory proftts are calculated iricoiporating expected
investment retums. Forexample, the proJected investment c'ash flows on corporate
bonds are assumed to be the future coupons multiplied by the irrobability that the
'
bond ls nor in default. As spreads on corporate bondS are typlcally greater than thelr
conesponding defuult probabiltties; the embedded value method generally places a
hlgher in-force value on business backed by corporate mther than govemment bonds.
Secondly, the embodded value method lavies frlctional capital costs solely on the
basis of regulatory restrictions. lt does not expllcitly allow for fllctional rjsk capital costs,
Thus, in the extreme, if two lines of business were wTitten in different territories, the
one line belng virtually risk-free but requlrlng high regulatory reseryes, the other bding
risky but only requlring low levels of regulatory reserves. Then the embedded value
method would penalise the former line regardleSs of the level of risk lnherent in the
other Iine-
Thirdly, under the'embedded value method, the level of the regulatory capital charge is
highest for business backed by the lowest yielding assets. This would tyPically mean
thatthe least risky business would be allocated the highest frictional capital co!-ts.
Lastly, as the embediedvalue method is based on expected cash flows it does not
eaiily accommodate optioni and guaranti:es. The economic method properiy allows
for these by valuing thern based on a coireiponding replicating porffolio. Valuing these
options based on expected cash flows is likely.to understate their vali:e..
HAFOC
BAROC, or risk-adjusted return on capital, is a performance measure that is typlcally
defined as discounted economic profrt divided by risk capital, There are many different
variatlons to the name and calculation of this measore. h ls not inconsistent with the
economic framework outlined in this publication and cbn bi a useful steering measure
tf caphal rere a scarce resource.
lf capltal were plentitut. then the only criteria for accepting business should be whather
economic piofit ls positive. Converse[, ff capital were scarce, then it should be allo-
cated. to the projects that 6re expected to €arn the griiatest econofric Profit relative to
the capftal invested, Thls relationship is quantified bythe HAHOC measure and is
equivaleQt to piEfit targets based.on fisk capital.
1l*rtino
The diff'rculties with RAHOC measures tend tb d.ise bscause of the measures of profit
or capiial that are sometinies used. ln many cases, capital costs are not included in the
eco-nomlc proflt measure.,lnstead, they are lncorporated in a BABOC hurdle mte, This is
problematic.because th'rs approach impligitv assumes that all.capital.costs aB prcpor-
tjonate to economlc cafiital. Hbwever. t]ris is generally not the case foi regulalory and
tai iosts.
AnotherprobLm ;th the application of RAROC. hurdle rates lles in the way tlre hurdle
rate ii
calculated. ln mafi caies. the hurdle rate is measured using the CAPM modei.
As stressed preiziously;the baptal costs incurred is a resultofwiiting insurance risks
are primirily frictional ;apital costs. CapiEl cost measures based upon CAPM largely
lgnore these costs, stressing lnstead the base cost of capital that is primarily incurred
on the investment side ofthe business.
16 This is a consequ8nce of the Modigliani
and Miller prcposttions.
Some RAROC measures also discount expected retums at the expected eamed
investment rate, This approadh has similar problems to the embeijded value method.
h does not prdperly value systematic risk and it is biased towards higher yielding
backing assets, h is important that the rcplicating portfolio replicates the systematic
risk in the coriesponding cash flows. Note that risk capltal generally does not properly
accolnt for systematic risk because it ls measured rolative to the insurer's insolvency,
ratherthan market risk
If misinterpreted, FIAI]OC can also create incentives to talg excessive investrnent risL
When a company takes more investment risk the amount of economic capital allo-
cated to investment dsk rises and the amount allocated to insurance risks genemlly
falls. As a resuh. BAROC results for insurance units v/ill tend to iise ds.insurers increase
.their investrnent risk. However, this does not necessarily imply that the proftablltty of
the company has.increased.
A tax rate of 35% has been used. where tax is payable on the statutory result
and is initially due at inception.
The allowance for the insurer's defauh option and liquidity valLie is assumed
to be an additional spread of 50 basis points. The impagt ofthis spread has
been included in the base cost of capital for the instrancd opemtions in the
income statement and under the assets in the balance sheet. As mentioned
previously, this enables the impact of a change in credit rating to be isolated
and excluded if necessary.
The income statement shows that the insurance operations achieved an eco-
nomic profit of 2.60 after tax, which is simply the pre-tdx profit of 4 less tax
at 35%. The investment operation achieved an economic proft of 0.78. which
is the pr+.tax outperformance of 1.20 less tax at 35%. The overall economic
profit is equal to 3.38.
ln addition, the llne 'rtem double taxation does not add any additional costs to
the insurer overall because tax on investment income is already included in
the tax line 'rtem. The double taxation line item is used to re-allocate the tax
incurred on the SAA benchmark to the lnsuranca and treasury functions.
The balance sheet shows that the total economic shareholder capital is 1 6.5 9.
Of this total, 4.59 cannot be realised r,n;,ithout infringing the regulatory restric-
tions and 12 can be reallsed without restriction. lt also shows the full breakdovrn
of the economic liabllities, including the default optlon and liquidity lalue,
Balance sheet
,4ssets
Investments 85_00
Default option and Iiquidity Elue 0.32
Total assets 85.32
UADilfuES
Discounted Iiability 66.04
Egense provisiore 0.94
Detered tax liability 1.O3
Double tax liability 0,33
Risk capital cost liability 9.35
Regulatory cost liability 0.04
Economic tiability (before detuult dption) 68.73
lg1lged sharcholder Gpha
Unrestricted ihareholder 12.00
liotal liabilrties
However, the base cost of cdpital does not directly impact value creaion or
operating efficiency. This is because shareholders do not benefrtfrorn a strat-
egythat only changes the base cost of capital. ln principle. they could unwind
changes to the base cost of capital by making corresponding changes to their
own portfolios. For example, if an insurer switched from equities to bonds,
then shareholders could in principle nullify the impact of this by selling equiv-
alent bonds and purchasing equivalent equities in their own pbrtfolios. Share.
holders would only benefrt indirectly to the extent that the investment strategy
reduces operating and frictional costs. Though it obviously has an important
impact on the eamings ofthe company, the base cost of capital perse is not'
a driver of value creation. h just represents thi appropriate reward for the level
of f nancial market risks to which shareholders' capital is expoied and there-
fore merely provides a minimum benchmark for asset management
lnsurers can manage their double tax costs by their fnancing and investment
decisions. For instance, insurers can finance therlselves with hybrid equity,
which has the tax characteristics of debl blrt the risk characterlstics of equity.
They can also hold their investments in low-tax environments and invest in
assets that are taxed favourably. Even the choica of active or passive manage-
.ment styles influences the tax burden on capital income. These issues will be
discussed in more depth later.
Agency costs
lnvestors are naturally reluctant to allow someone else to manage their money
forthem.simply because there is always a possibilitythatthey may not man-
age the money in their best interest This is true for any investmenl but is
particularly important for an insurer because the insurance industry is not
transparent to outsiders. This makes it difficult for investoc to monitor the
decislon making of insurers. As a resuh investors demand a higher retum on
their caphal.
,Agency costs can be further reduced if these internal measures are linked to
incentive compensation: this obViously assumes that the measures are valid
and accepted by shaieholders. This better aligns tile interests of managers
with the interes.ts of shareholders.
The scale of a company also impacts the transparency it can achieve because
large companies aTe more likely to get press coverage and be {ollowed by
financial analysts. Financial analysts spend a great deal of time sorting
through accounting statements trying to get a better. picture of shareholder
value creation that they then pass on to shareholders.
The primary driver of this cost is the regulatory environment the business is
written in. To a limited extent, insurers can exercise control over this cost by
effi cient risk transfer.
How lnuch capital to hold? How much capital does the company need to operate
efflciently? What can be done b manage regulatory and rating agency require-
m-ents? How can the company be steered to improve diversification? Can tle com-
pany opeErE more efficiently by transfening riskto financial or reinsumnce markets?
What type of capital? ls equity the only option? How to invest.capttaP Should
the company mismatch asseb and liabilities? How much market risk should it take?
As shown in the graph below this depends critically on the size of the insurer's
franchise value. If an insurer has little franchise value. then it can o:tract value
for shareholders by minimising the amount of capital held. This increases the .
value of the shareholders'optlon to default on the existing insurance liabiiities.
HoweVer, this relationship is well understood by reguiators who generally pre-
vent this itrategy from being pursued.
In the more normal situatjon where an insuier has a substantal franchise value,
the level at which poliryholders are prepared to pay the highest margins largely
deGrmines the optimal level of capital. This is a complex decision and requires a
thorough understanding ofthe preferences ofthe target client market. This deci-
sion is frequently driven by mting agency requirements, which creates $e need
to efficiently manage the level of capital required to secure a particular rating.
Optimal
Caphal costs
●ョ一
too high
”> ●り一
Put option
〓OC●﹄﹂
I
Franchise
1 1 1←
at risk
Capital
lnsurers have two tools at their disposal for managing their overall level of risk
and consequentlythe amount of capltal they need to hold: diversification and
isk tansfer
Diversification
By pooling independent risk, insurers can reduce the riskiness oftheir balance
sheet Eifectively managing diversification, however, can be a challenge.
When market units price and write business, they need to know ahead of time
how the risk they are underwriting diversifies with the other risks on the
company's books. Risks that diversify well are less costly for the company to
underwrite than risks that do not. lf risks werc written one at a time, this
would not be ditficult to measure. However, market units within an insurer all
write business simultaneously, so that a capital and capacity planning cycle is
necessary.
Atthe beginning of this cycle; risk and capital managers, togetherwith market
units, must decide how much of a particular risk will be undervwitten in the
course of the planning cycle. A capital plan must also be developed to support
those risks, whether the risk will be kept on the books of the insurer and
backed with caphal ortransfened via financial or reinsurance ma*ets. Based
upan this plan, the expected cost of taking various risks may be determined
and these costs may be included in actuar,ial pricing.
The time horizon of the capltal and capacity planning process should be long
enough to allow market units to implement a business plan. and short enough
to keep the company sufficiently flexible to react to changing market condi-
tions and opportunities.
Bisk transfer
Risk transfer can be used effectively as a capital substitute whenever the cost
of fansferring risk is lower than the cost of keeping that risk on the company's
books. Risk can be transferred elther to financial markets or to TeinsuTance
markets.
allowing insurers to manage lnsurance dsk for them and avoiding moral
hazard problems. Despite the clear advantages of securitization, this market
lnsurers can also reduce their cost of taking risk through the use 6f reinsur-
ance. The value proposition for reinsurance is well developed. Professional
reinsurers are specialised in obtaining a low cost of taking risk. They generally
are well'diversified and have large capital bases, good access to capital
ma.rkets, and expertise in carrier management to minimise tax and regulatory
bu rdens.
Signalling capital
Signalling caphal refers to capital in excess of economic capital that insurers
must hold in cjrder to satisfy external requirements. such as regulatory or rating
agency requirements.
Hegulators and rating agencles musi apply simple and universally applicable
capital requirements. ln addition. they preferto er on the conservative side.
As a result, lt is somdtimes the case that regulators and rating agencies
require more capital than is economically justified. Insurers can manage the
amount oJ signallirig capital by choosing to transfer risks where extemal
requirements are onerous. Beinsurance and accounting structures also exist
that reshape risks into a more regulatory and rating agency-friendly forrn.
38 sws na The
"onomls
oflnsuEncr
5.4 Type of capital required
lnsurers hold capital to increase their ability to pay their insurance Iiabilities
even under adverse circumstances. Insurers have an increasing number of
choices for how they finance.that capital. All of these choices vary In terms of
both the cost of holding that capital and the security thoy provide. As a result
the optimal-capital structure will be a trade-off between the amount of capital
the company must hold and the frjctional costs of holding that capital.
Equity
Equity is the saiest {orm o{ capital since shareholders cannot demand divldend
payments, nor can they demand repayment of their capital. However, because
of disadvantaQed tax treatment. it is also the mbst expensive form of capital.
Corporate profhs, which accrue to share investors, aro taxed whereas interest
payments. Which accrue to bond investors, are treated as expenses and are tax
deductible.
Debt
Senior debt iinance cannot be used to support insurElnce risks since in the case
.of defuult senior debt is repaid firsl Debt that is subordinated to insurance
liabilities could in theory be used to suppon risk taking. However, in practice,
it is seldom used. {or a numbdr of reasons. To support risk taking, the subordF
nated debt must be longer in durdtion than insurance liabilities. ln practical
terms, this means that subordinated debt must be continually recalled and
new longerduration debt issued. ln general. regulaton and rating agencies
also do not treat this debt as risk-bearing caphal.
Contingent capital
lnsurers also have the.option of ananging for contingent capital - contractu-
alV obligated investments that trigger under pre.defined condhions. The
advantage of this sort of financing is that the capital is kept off balance sheet
and so is'not subJect to taxation. By using contingent capital, however, the
insurer exposes itself to credit risk of the contingent capital provider. Regula-
tois therefore often lirnit the amount of contingent capital an insurer may use
to support risk taking.
Market risk
Due to an historical focus on reporting accounting profrts, insurers have often
invested in high-yield products. The value proposition for yield. however, is
unclear since to get a higher yield, the insurer must normally take additional
risk and will incur additional frictional costs as a result
The market risk that an insurer takes is passed directly on to shareholders who
could have invested in these instruments directly..lnsurers can therefore only
create value bytaking market risk if investors preferto have an insurer manage
these investments for them despite the fact that they w,ll be surrendering
control of these investments which, in addhion. will be held in a regulated and
'taxed vehicle. As this is not likely to be the. case, this suggests that insurers
should focus on thelr core competency of originating and managing insurance
risk by hedging market risk as iar as possible. However, another consideration
to be taken into account is that other frictional costs may create incentives for
insurers to take investment risks.
Tax codes can differ greafly from jurisdiction to jurisdiction. However, in most
countries capital gains are taxed preferentially to ihvestment income. The
nominal tax rate on capital gains is often .lower ln some countries capital
gains are not taxed at all. Caphal gains also carry the benefit of defenal since
they are only taxed at realisation. By postponing the realisation of capital
gains, insurers can gain the time value of money on their defarred taxes.
The amount gained by deferml ofcaphal gains depends on how long capital
gains are defered and on the pre\railing interest rate. The graph below shows
the effective tax rite on capital gains as a percentage ofthe nominal tax rate
for varying realisation rates and interest rates. lf an insurer is very aggressive
about postponing the realisation of gains. the tax rate can be reduced suF
sfantially. For inshance. if the insurer realises just I 0% of unrealised gains each
year - an average investment horizon of just under 1 O years - the effective
tax rate drops to two thirds of the nominal tax rate. Reducing the realisation
rate to 5% - average investment horizon of 1 5 years - cuts the effuctive tax
rate to about half the nominal tax rate.
0
0
%
-4%
8
0
__
%
-5% 6%
■■ 主 ●E・
6
0
%
●“cL Xc” oいつop〓ロ
EOrい
4
。
%
oメ ︸
2
0
% i
0
I I I I I I I 1 1
1O0% 80% 500/6 40% 2O'/" Ooh
Favourable tax treatment of capital gains does create an incentive for insurers
to invest in equities. Howevet investing in equities generallY m6ans taking
more market risk and this creates additional frictional capital costs which will
offset some, if not all. of the gains from lower tax rates.
Uquldity
Anotherfrictional consideration in determining an insurer:s optimal investment
strategy is liquidity. Insurance is a cash-rich industry. The cash flow in from
premiums and investrnent income is often signmcantly greater than the cash
flow outfrom claims and expenses. ln addition, insurers usually keep large
amounts of liquid assets on their balance shaet. As a result, many insurers
have more liquidity than they need to suppoit their.business.
Amihud, Y. and H. Mendelson, 199'1, Liquidtty, 6set pdcs and finah Jensetr, M. c., 1 986. Agency cosb of fEe cash fow corpoBte nnance,
cial poliq. Financial Aoalyss Joumal, Nwember/December: 56-66. atd ldkewe$. Ameri@n E@nomic Revlew 76: 323-329.
Andmde, G., and S. N. Kaplan, 1 9 98: l.low costly is flnancial (not eco- Merton, R. C., 1993, OpeEtions and Egulation ln financial intemedia-
nomic) distrss? Evidance from hlghly leyemged tEnsactions that tlon: a funcuonal peEpective, in Englund, P., ed.-, Opeation aod regula-
became distressed. Joumal of Finance, 53: I443-1493, tlon offfnancial markts (Stockholm: The Economlc Council):1 7-67.
Babbel, D. F., and K B. Staking, 1 I I g. The mdrket rcmrd for insurere Merton, R.C., anc A.F. Perold, I 999, Theory of risk cpital in tnancial
that pEctice asset/llablllty managsment Financial lns{rtutions Besearch, flrms. in: Chew D.H. ed.. \he neil
cotpoate finance: where the6ry mees
Goldman Sachc pGcarce, Second Editon. (Boston: IMin McGcFHill): 505-521.
BabbeL D.F.,and C.Meri‖ ,1998′ ECOnOmic valua● on modelslo「 Miller, M.H., i999, the Modlgliani-MillerprcpGitioN afterthirtyyea6,
inSuに ヽ.′ `
′0“ │ス θ ′7aa′ スOtta"′ ノ Oυ 初証 2(3):1-15. ln Chew. D.H.. ed-, The new corpone finance:where theory meea
“ pacdce, Second Edition {Boston: lrwin McGmrHill)
Babbel, D. F.. 1 999, Components ot lmuEne flm value, and the pES-
ert value of liabilttis. in: Babbel. 0.F., and F). Fatud,,lnvefiment Perold′ A.R,1998.Capital a‖ o`認 t onin i`■ tncね 1 lrrnsfヽVo「 噸ng Pape「
mnagnatfoilnsum, (New Hope, PII FEnk J. Fabozl Assoclates): 98-072.Hanに lrd Business School.
51 -60.
PEtt, S. P., 1 g 9 8, Co$ of capital: estimation and apblicatlons" lNew
Babbel,D.F・ ′R.S,ic:c,and I.■ Vanderhoof′ 1999,A perfo「 rnance York John Wley & Sons)
measurerlent sy● em forinsurec in:Babbel.D二 ′and F」 .Fabozzl,
力蔭 r"″agmear″ 麻 υた_(N"Hope′ PA Frank J.hbo」 Senbet, LW:. and J.lC Se@rd, 19 9 5, Financlal dlstEss. bankruptcy
"″
Assodats):61‐ 76. and reorganisation, ln JarrM, B et a[. eds-, Handbooks in OR & MS,
Volume g. Elsevier Science.
Babbel, D.F.. and c. Merill, 1999. Tourard a unified valuation model for
insucm, in: Chargs ln the llfe lnsuance lndntry: efriciency, Edlnology
and rkk managment, (NoMell, MA Klwer)
64(4:673-694.
Swiss Re publishing
Swiss Re's Technical Publishlng seris
compal€es the subcategoris of Property,
casuahy, Engineering and lhdu*ry, Avia-
tion and Marine, and Genml. The General
cfiegory includes a wide Eoge of reln-
surancFrelaEd &plcs, for mmplei
o 2001_
Swiss Reinsurance Company, Zurich
Tide
The 6conomics of insunnce
How insureE create v6lue foa shaEholdErs
(2d edhionl
A!tho6:
John Hancock Pa{l Huber, Pablo Koch
GEphic design:
PhmgEptu
CoEE lmage Banlg Zurich