Pari-Mutuel Algorithm
Pari-Mutuel Algorithm
Pari-Mutuel Algorithm
by
Guillermo Owen
Oct ober 1984
R. SHUMAKER
H. D. A. SCHRADY
.
NPS-53-85-0001
5. TYPE OF REPORT & PERIOD COVERED
4. TITLE (and Subtllte)
Pari-Mutuel as a System of Technical Report
Aggregation of Information March 1-Sept. 30, 1984
6. PERFORMING ORG. REPORT NUMBER
Guillermo Owen
PERFORMING ORGANIZATION NAME AND ADDRESS 10. PROGRAM ELEMENT. PROJECT. TASK
9.
AREA 4 WOHK UNIT NUMBERS
Naval Postgraduate School 6]]52N;RR000-0]-]0
Monterey, CA 93943 N000]484WR4]00]
II. CONTROLLING OFFICE NAME AND ADORESS 12. REPORT DATE
23
AGENCY NAME ADDRESSfff different from Controlling Ottice) 15. SECURITY CLASS. (o( thla report)
U. MONITORING ft
17. DISTRIBUTION STATEMENT (of the abatract entered In Block 20. If different from Report)
19. KEY WORDS (Continue on ravaraa aide If neceaeary and Identify by block number)
Group Decision
Group Probability
Pari-Mutuel
20. ABSTRACT (Continue on reveree aide If neceaeary and Identity by block number)
optimal
A bettor is faced with the problem of choosing
outcomes of an
bets given his (subjective) probabilities of Conversely,
experiment and the payoff odds on these outcomes
a bookie (pari-mutuel system), faced
by several bettors with
of choosing
different subjective probabilities, has the problem shown
It is
payoff odds so as to avoid the risk of loss.
under certain reasonably broad conditions on the several
that
S N 0102- LF-014-6601
Unclassified
SECURITY CLASSIFICATION OF THIS PAGE(TW»»n Dmtm Enffd)
DUDLEY KNO;
JWjVAL POSTG^:.
MONTEREY CA 93943-5101
Pari-Mutuel as a System of Aggregation
of Information
n
(1)
p .>
3=1
and
(2) £ q. = l ; g i
3=1
are consistent; condition (2) means the payoff odds are fair.
(Though, in fact, they seldom are, and most bookies will normally
(3) f(x
i v 2 p . U (
-3- - B + A \ .
where
n
(4) b =
^ x .
3=1
subject to
(5) b < A
(6) x . > .
conditions (2), the bettor might as well set B = A, i.e. bet all
x '. = x . + e q . j = 1 , . . . , n
3 3 3
In this case,
B'=>x.'=B
Iv + e
and, moreover,
F(x , ,
x _. + eq
F(x '
, . .
L r
so that f(x') = F(x), i.e. the bettor can do at least as well with
bets x .' such that b' = a as with any other bets with b < a.
(? ) ^(x x ) = yp u (1±
y
.
1 n 3 \q.
.
subject to
(8)
J,-
(9) x . > .
Pi
(10b) -^- w (0) < \ if x . =
of money.
In the simplest case, all x. are positive, so that (10a) holds for
(12) X - £
j
P, *' ^
j
More generally, of course, (12) does not hold for all j, and
. ^
value of u '
u'
/ x
—M=
. \
—
\q .
if x . >
(15)
x
i
-^-
q
>
x
—
qk
k
whenever
p
—i
q
<*- > —
pk
qk
j j
with the stronger result that, for strictly concave u, (15) holds
and the payoff odds leads the bettor to bet so that his conditional
winnings will be greater for horses for which the ratio P-/q.
is greater, and conversely.
(17) x . = if w I —
J
Xg
(is) , - ^ q . » (^i
J
where the prime on the summation svmbol means that it should con-
sider only those j such that (16) holds, i.e. such that
(19) \q . < p . W (0
The right side (18) can be seen to be a monotone non-increasing
problem.
2. The Equilibrium Odds
tion among bookies), the bookie could only eliminate the risk of
to the q . , i.e. if
(20) b . = q . c
J J
where b . is the total amount bet on horse j (by all bettors) and
b . = x . and c = A ) .
J J
If there are two or more bettors, the bookie must look for
effect, the players bet against each other, with the track as
payoff odds. Thus, a player might well feel he would have changed
his bets, had he known the true payoff odds in advance. Of course
equilibrium exists.
p . .
> , and
I >v - ' .
j=l
This same bettor has a sum of money, a., available for betting,
(<7
7
' <?-,/•••/? ), then each bettor will choose (x , x ,..., x. )
i=l
(22) C = 1 *i' 1 b .
J
i=l J=J
over that all the utility functions are strictly concave. Then
Q (the set of q with all components positive) and let 9£> be the
just (8) and (9), but also the condition x., = o whenever p., =
ik ik
Restricted to that set, bettor i's expected utility,
n
x
\.
i
(x.
i
f q) = )
t-d
p.
i
.
7
U .
i
(
\
—
a
J
x
i
*(q). Since f is continuous for all x. and all q e Q° , it
Let , now,
m
b*(q) = y x.*(q)
i=l
Then b* is a continuous mapping from q° into n
iR . Let, finally,
.
b
k *(q)
Z> .* (q)
J(q) = < j = ma x
continuous .
J(q) = | J q = o\ .
semi-continuous if restricted to dQ
with the case that q — -q, with all q and q e dQ, since we know
J, restricted to dQ , is semi-continuous.
* *
Thus x £ and x are both positive, and so we can apply (13) to
h
set
*
V ('M\ -iLlhl v (
x
-m
Now, since lg - g| < e, we will have q. > r/2, q. < z and
10
* 1
Also, p.. < 1. Finally, x,./g. > — , so by monotonicity
v (
x
Ai\ *
v <j>- Thus
7T 7T 7T
*
On the other hand, for any k 4 K, b < c and q > r/2. Thus
In this case,
j i X j t K
and so
. * 1
Thus there is some I a K with x, > =—
hin 2n .
Since |
q - q |
< e^ and q. = 0, we have q. < E and so
X
'Z ^ h/ > i = 2C
11
Once again b.*/q. < 2c/r for all j 4 K, and so b*/q. < b»*/q.
for s c n,
q e Q
$(S) = q
I
q . = if j £ S > .
J
)
q e $ (q ) .
w =
-X
. ( x , t ) u . (x ) - t
12
"
X
w .
'
(x , t) = U .
'
(x) + t e
X
w .
(x ,t) = U ." (x) - t e
all q*(t) c Q ,
q** could conceivably belong to dQ. Theorem 2
e = e /2 . Let S < U .
'
(j).
5
13
.
2C
v (*M -v (*f) *• r
>v (*)
v (H - v (i)
*<* 4 <v (i) «<«* (i)
and so
£
4
!i ££ • v (ff) » v (fM
The proof then proceeds as in that of Theorem 1, leading to the
conclusion that
J (?) c K * n
t
functions u .
Assumption i
y. For all i and j, p. •>
. > 0.
i j
equilibrium q* * e Q .
14
.
U[ (Aj +)
r =
U (A ~ }
'l 1
^ ij < r ik
j k
X X
-^
. . . .
(24) ~ -J*
qk q
j
mean x_
±j = A j = 1 , . . . , n
Then, for k c K, j i k,
P lj < r P ±k
q 2 qk
j .
15
,
and, by (11)
V
w '
(A
(A
i
+!
-;
t}
t)
< r
2
i 2
or
Al
U ' (A. + ) + t e
1 I < r
U ' (A}-) + t e~ 1
V ' (A 1+ )
<
U '
(Al-) 2
2
desired equilibrium.
3. Examples
some "reasonable" utility functions; the last shows that the con-
U . (x) = log (K . + x)
l l
form
ij =A.^ if x . . >
K .q . + x . .
1J
i J 13
or, equivalently
P
25 13
( ) *
i7 - = ~y~ - K.q if positive
(26)
X = if p . . < K q X
i.7 ij .
*
.
3
.
1G
.
A
1
2
- z
*—>
3=1
*.
XJ
- -i
A
. — .
*.
2
and so
1
X .
2 A . + K .
2 2
1J 1 2 2 J
i=l
Thus
C
Zj (A
i
.
'
+ K
"l
.
"^
)p . - q
^
* Zj K x
7
. = q .*
J
so _
(27) (A + K )p ij
_ j j _ i
*j* = C + £K.
2
babilities p . . .
U (x) = -e i
17
In this case, the optimality conditions (10)-(11) take the
form
- — \ = X .q . if x . . >
which reduces to
P ij
(28) a . x . . = q . (log a . - log X . ) + q . log
i xj j l i l q
if this (right
° side) is positive, and x . .
= otherwise
2J
to j gives us
p
a
11
. A . = log a.
i
- log X . + y
/. q" . lo< n
7 J
P
^
,-'
Ik i
q.
k
=
a
1
.
i
1 og
qk
- 1 q. log + A
j
obtaining ~
P ik
c - I i
JL
a .
i
1 og
k
+ C
j
or
p ik
y~ a i
.
i og
* k
q
y y *
111
l i k i j l
k, and so
V
^ a. -
i
log p - log^ q, /. = y
ii
.
* ik ^ k
ii
. a '
log qk * =
Z r
i
log p. - Y
I-
18
.
or
(29) V - r
i=l
ik i
r .
1
+ +r
where r.
l
= —
a .
, and r is constant. Thus in this case g,
k
* is
l
the probabilities p
ik
art icle
(d) A counter-example .
p ll = Z p 12 - o
21 22
A = A = 1
2 2
3q
= -
3q l
1
21 22 —-=-
19
3q 3q
*21 ' ' ~ — 22
b *(g)
2
= 1 + —
J
*l
if q2 <
1
-
V<*> - 2 - —
3q 2
=
1
2
+
3q
-J-
i
lf
*1 >
1
J
I s
V*' -
1 if
^i = i •
20
. ,
APPENDIX
Xx + (l-X)y e S.
• s = |
x | f(x) > q
q |
unique
f has both right and left derivatives, f'(x+) and f'(x-). The
1,t
Upper Semi-Continuity
then <J>
is an upper semi-continuous set-valued mapping from x to Y
x* e 4> ( x* ) .
BIBLIOGRAPHY
^
DISTRIBUTION LIST
iA
DUDLEY KNOX LIBRARY
3 2768 00347544 3