Intra Port Competition
Intra Port Competition
Intra Port Competition
1. Intra-Port Competition
Intra-port competition is beneficial for the competitiveness of ports, local and
national economies, and consumers and exporting industries. Its presence is
conditional and might be facilitated by specific initiatives. This is most
commonly observed in terminal operations, where a terminal operator has
jurisdiction over an entire terminal area, from the berth to the gate, and
competes with other terminal operators responsible for other terminals.
Intra-port competition might also be observed in providing other services,
either at landside (warehousing, logistics, value-added services) or maritime
side (pilotage, towage, mooring) of the port.
If parts of the hinterland are captive and markets are not contestable,
opportunities for rent extraction by the port service provider exist when any
of the following three conditions are met:
The share of the port services in total port costs is not substantial.
The overall port product consists of various services, such as terminal
handling, towage, pilotage, and ship handling. Port services providers
that are of relatively minor importance for the overall costs will hardly
lose business when they raise prices, as port users are sensitive to total
port costs, rather than their individual components. Thus, such service
providers have market power.
The captive hinterland is large compared to the contestable
hinterland. In this case, monopoly pricing is possible since many port
users cannot shift to an alternative port without facing substantial
additional costs. Monopoly prices increase revenues for service
providers, even if a part of the port’s users in the contestable
hinterland shifts to another port.
Opportunities to differentiate prices in the captive hinterland exist.
Even when the captive hinterland is not sufficiently large to maximize
profits via monopoly pricing, it may be possible to charge port users in
the captive hinterland higher prices, since they can hardly shift to other
ports. Three different types of port users purchase port services:
shippers (cargo owners), shipping lines, and forwarders (or other
transport intermediaries). Unless they are located in a perfectly
contestable hinterland, shippers have the worst bargaining position
since switching to a second-best port leads to higher transport costs.
Port service providers have market power versus captive shippers
located in the captive hinterland as they can charge higher prices than
those applicable for contestable shippers. This explains why large
shippers in captive hinterlands frequently invest in user-owned port
facilities. However, most shippers do not have direct contracts with
port service providers. Instead, they have contracts with either shipping
lines or forwarders. The bargaining position of port service providers
vis-à-vis shipping lines or forwarders is substantially weaker because
these users might consolidate cargo with different origins and
destinations. Consolidation and the development of transshipment
hubs and the increasing efficiency of inland transportation limit
geographical powers and increase the cross-elasticity of demand for
ports. Price differentiation related to the origin/destination of the
cargo is not viable when shipping lines or forwarders purchase
services. In short, port service providers do not have market power vis-
à-vis shipping lines and forwarders in ports where the contestable
hinterland is so large that the loss of volume (volume effect) offsets the
additional revenues from the price increase (price effect), and the port
service is an important component of total port costs.
The experience from the privatization of terminal operation suggests that due
to the lack of intra-port competition, port users rarely face high tariffs and
request regulatory institutions to limit the monopolistic position of terminal
operators. Such regulation (whether created and monitored by a government
agency or by a port authority) incurs costs, such as monitoring costs,
including productivity and tariff controls. Furthermore, due to information
asymmetry between the regulator and the port industry, regulation is
unlikely to be ideal for the purpose of preventing all efforts to extract
monopoly rents. Intra-port competition is potentially a more effective way to
ensure competitive port tariffs.
Minimum Efficient Scale and Long Run Average Costs in Container
Terminals
Source: Porteconomicsmanagement
Author: Dr. Thanos Pallis