David Parrott - The Business of War - Military Enterprise and Military Revolution in Early Modern Europe (2012, Cambridge University Press)
David Parrott - The Business of War - Military Enterprise and Military Revolution in Early Modern Europe (2012, Cambridge University Press)
David Parrott - The Business of War - Military Enterprise and Military Revolution in Early Modern Europe (2012, Cambridge University Press)
This is a major new approach to the military revolution and the relation-
ship between warfare and the power of the state in early modern Europe.
Whereas previous accounts have emphasized the growth of state-run
armies during this period, David Parrott argues instead that the delega-
tion of military responsibility to sophisticated and extensive networks of
private enterprise reached unprecedented levels. This included not only
the hiring of troops but the provision of equipment, the supply of food
and munitions, and the financing of their operations. The book reveals
the extraordinary prevalence and capability of private networks of
commanders, suppliers, merchants and financiers who managed the
conduct of war on land and at sea, challenging the traditional assumption
that reliance on mercenaries and the private sector results in corrupt and
inefficient military force. In so doing, the book provides essential histor-
ical context to contemporary debates about the role of the private sector
in warfare.
David Parrott
cambridge university press
Cambridge, New York, Melbourne, Madrid, Cape Town,
Singapore, São Paulo, Delhi, Mexico City
Cambridge University Press
The Edinburgh Building, Cambridge CB2 8RU, UK
www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9780521735582
A catalogue record for this publication is available from the British Library
Introduction 1
Notes 328
Bibliography 393
Index 419
vii
Figures
viii
List of figures ix
having supported a previous term of leave when I was giving the lectures
themselves.
A further and particular debt is owed to a benefactor of New College,
Eugene Ludwig, whose support for the Humanities within the College has
been marked both by extraordinary generosity and by his personal interest
and encouragement for our various research projects. I and all my col-
leagues in the Humanities disciplines are immensely grateful for his sup-
port. In the present case, I thank the Ludwig Fund for providing generous
coverage for the costs of researching images and acquiring reproduction
rights for the illustrations in the present volume.
In a project of this nature and scope, I have necessarily acquired many
intellectual debts to colleagues in the UK and abroad who have provided
vital advice, feedback and criticism. Amongst so many who have offered
their assistance in the course of this project, I should like to single out
Geoffrey Parker, who spent a term in Oxford as Distinguished Visiting
Professor in Trinity 2004, and whose enthusiasm and deft and knowl-
edgeable engagement with the project were invaluable at this early stage,
and have been no less valued in his later communications and discussions.
I would also single out Hamish Scott, to whom I am obliged beyond
measure for unstinting help and advice throughout the gestation and
completion of the project. Michael Howard, whose chapter ‘The Wars
of the Merchants’ in his War in European History first encouraged my
interest in military contracting, has been a source of encouragement and
inspiration throughout this project, as he has with all my previous writing
on military history.
Many others have contributed to my understanding of the parameters
and problems of the subject, and to the final shape of the present work,
and to all of them I owe my warmest thanks. In Oxford I am especially
grateful to Robin Briggs, Cliff Davies, Robert Evans, Steven Gunn, Clive
Holmes, Sarah Percy, Nicholas Rodger, Lyndal Roper, Hew Strachan,
Penry Williams amongst numerous other colleagues, while in the wider
academic world, especially Sydney Anglo, Rainer Babel, Joseph Bergin,
Jeremy Black, Tim Blanning, Olivier Chaline, Luc Duerloo, Jack Dunn,
Robert Frost, Lothar Höbelt, Bernhard Kroener, Jan Lindegren, Davide
Maffi, Simon Pepper, Guy Rowlands, Frank Tallett, Tony Thompson,
David Trim and Phillip Williams.
In the composition of the book I must thank particularly my picture
researcher, Julie Farguson, for all of her own suggestions and input in
assembling lists of images, for tireless reminders about obtaining permis-
sions, and for her willingness to go to extraordinary lengths to obtain some
of the illustrations in the volume. I am most grateful to my father, Fred
Parrott, for his time and expertise in reading through and removing many
Acknowledgements xv
xvi
Currencies
The principal currencies used in the book are Imperial talers and florins
(Rhenish), Swedish and Danish riksdalers, Dutch florins, Spanish
ducats and escudos, and French livres and écus.
Rough conversion rates in the first half of the seventeenth century:
1 Imperial taler = 1.5 German (Rhenish) florins
1 Rhenish florin = 1.7 Dutch florins
2.5 Dutch florins = 1 Imperial taler
1 Spanish escudo = 1.1 Spanish ducats
1.5 Rhenish florins = 1 Spanish escudo
3 French livres = 1 French écu
1 Rhenish florin = 2 French livres (from later 1630s)
3 French livres = 1 Spanish escudo
1 riksdaler (Swedish/Danish) = between 0.7 and 1 Imperial taler
xvii
Introduction
The aim of this book is to examine the rise, success and transformations of
military enterprise – warfare organized and waged by private contractors –
in early modern Europe (c.1500–1700). Military enterprise as it is dis-
cussed here amounts to a lot more than hiring mercenaries to serve in the
ranks of a state-run army or using privateers to supplement or stand in for
the state’s navy. Enterprise includes a more extensive delegation of
responsibility and authority to include the supply of food, clothes and
equipment to troops, and the manufacturing and distribution of muni-
tions and weapons. Warship and fortress building were outsourced, as
were entire naval operations. Garrisoning and siege-works were put out to
contract. A large part of this process did involve the hiring and mainte-
nance of soldiers or sailors, but the terms of many of the recruitment
contracts drawn up with the field and unit commanders reveal significant
differences from those before or after this period. Moreover the way in
which these commanders interpreted their authority and autonomy in
waging war on behalf of their employers was significantly changed. They
acted through their own creditors to raise the funds required for recruit-
ment and military operations, and they drew on networks of private
manufacturers, merchants and transport operatives to ensure that their
troops were fed and equipped. Some fundamental aspects of the financing
of war were placed in the hands of private military contractors or their
agents, who also ensured that their credit and costs were recovered, by
force if necessary, even when the army was on the territory of its notional
employer.
To anyone familiar with the historical debate about early modern
military change, it will be significant that the key decades of this ‘military
devolution’ lie between c.1560 and 1660, the same period identified by
Michael Roberts in his seminal article for the chronology of an early
modern European ‘military revolution’.1 From its inception in the mid-
1950s, this thesis that military change could be linked to wider processes
of political and social transformation has been the key organizing principle
for analysis and discussion of early modern war and society.2 Although
1
2 The Business of War
past few decades have called this seemingly inexorable process into ques-
tion. The relationship between military force and the demands and aspira-
tions of states and their governments no longer seems so one-directional.
Awareness that the outsourcing of military functions, and dependence on
private companies to fulfil vital ancillary and support services, is an increas-
ing part of most western military organizations has taken a while to grow
among non-specialists.10 More attention was focused on the resurgence of
private military companies and their operations on the fringes of the military
system, whether this was the comprehensive small armies fielded by com-
panies like Executive Outcomes and Sandline in south-central Africa in the
1980s and early 1990s, or the growth from the 1990s of private security
companies in zones of crisis, whose activities may well extend to proactive
behaviour replicating or replacing the work of state-run armed forces.11
The wars in Afghanistan and Iraq have provided further evidence of the
growing activities of private security companies whose remit to provide
military support services can on occasions shade into de facto combat
roles: during the past decade Blackwater has become a virtual household
name thanks to its massive presence in Iraq and the involvement of its
operatives in combat zones.12 The scale and the media profile of military
outsourcing in these last two wars has finally brought home to a wider
public how radical the transformation has been over the past few decades.
While in the West, what could be defined as the ‘core activities’ of the
armed forces have so far remained directly under state control, this is not
the case elsewhere in the world, and it is certainly arguable that in the West
the ability to perform these core activities has already become dependent
upon support services which are in large part put out to contract.13
So thinking about the organization of military force in the early twenty-
first century and beyond renders more controversial the notion that there
was a single historical path leading to the creation of a monopoly of
military force in the hands of the state (indeed, that the historical process
had reached that point by the late nineteenth century in even the most
backward of western nations). But it was never the case that this paradigm
for the understanding of European military history rested purely and
simply on an assumption of historical inevitability. Other no less problem-
atic assumptions play their part in shaping views of the development of
military force in early modern Europe.
If historians of early modern Europe have interpreted changing patterns
of warfare from the fifteenth to the eighteenth century in terms of the
growth and elaboration of state control, a significant element of this is
based on what is taken to be the axiomatic inferiority of private military
organization. Two sets of interlocking negative assumptions are at work
here. The first of these is a generalized, but well-established, moral and
Introduction 5
legal preoccupation with the use of soldiers whose activities seem to have
no justification other than the pursuit of personal gain. In some cases this
is made evident because the soldiers or sailors had taken service with a
foreign state, and had no obvious interest or engagement in the quarrels of
the contracting power. Against the obvious argument that many native
soldiers have a demonstrably limited commitment to the causes for which
they are fighting, the counter-argument is made that these native soldiers
were at least recruited within a societal context in which this cause was
considered an appropriate justification for war. Mercenaries, on the other
hand, choose their military service entirely freely and individually, and for
their own motives; they were neither conscripted by the state to service in a
cause judged appropriate, nor were they responding collectively to a wider
perception of that cause. Underlying these rather clumsy definitional
arguments is a widely shared assumption about the fundamental wrong-
ness of ‘killing for hire’: mercenaries have less plausible justifications for
their activities than a national army. Even where one side in a dispute
might reasonably assert that they possessed a just cause in defending their
interests through war, that cause would be demeaned by relying on hired
mercenaries to wage a struggle on their behalf since these would be unable
to provide a plausible justification for their own part in any consequent
violence. The free and inappropriate choice of soldiering for profit will
consistently trump any evidence that the mercenary, as individual, may
sympathize with the ideals, beliefs or cause of the party for whom he is
fighting and that this may in part have motivated the decision to offer his
services.14
In the West from the early nineteenth century this moral sense of the
wrongness of fighting for profit has combined on occasions with a political
interest in the containment of private force, to produce a legal framework
for restrictions on hiring ‘mercenaries’ and enforceable international
agreements to stamp out piracy or to restrict privateering.15 But such
attempted legal restraints, highly problematic in terms of definitions and
possibilities of enforcement, are a recent development. Sarah Percy in her
latest book points to the less substantial but more pervasive notion of a
shared, historical ‘norm’ against mercenary use. Starting with the reac-
tions to the unconstrained looting and violence of the private mercenary
companies of the fourteenth century, and enduring concern about vio-
lence outside the legitimate control of constituted authorities, she traces a
developing consensus, established well before an eighteenth-century
Enlightenment, that the hiring of military forces was inappropriate to a
civilized society.16 Whether seen through the eyes of theorists who wor-
ried about the moral impact of depriving the citizenry of the need to serve
in their own defence, or through the eyes of political and social elites,
6 The Business of War
concerned at the potential disorders that would result from allowing adult
males to seek their living by fighting for hire outside their own homeland, a
shared thread of hostility to and constraint in the use of mercenaries is a
persistent characteristic of western societies down to the present day. Both
humanist and Enlightenment discourses lay stress on the importance of
citizen participation in military service, and identify this as a mark of civility
and progress. Abandoning reliance on mercenaries (which, of course, can
easily encompass the whole structure of privatized warfare) is part of a
civilizing process; the state-controlled army reflects the achievement of
moral and political maturity.
Of course, the practical problem of who constitutes a mercenary
remains: the graveyard of most anti-mercenary legislation has been the
difficulty of finding any kind of workable definition; neither being non-
native in the country of employment nor offering military service exclu-
sively for financial reward proves very effective. Private forces standing
totally outside the control of the state identify only a minuscule subset of
activity which might broadly be considered mercenary. In this context, the
advantage of understanding the hostility to mercenary use as a ‘norm’
rather than an evolving body of international legislation is precisely that it
bypasses these issues and argues for a much longer-term, collective aver-
sion at a political and cultural level. Indeed Percy argues that it is the very
strength of the anti-mercenary norm which makes it virtually impossible
to legislate effectively against mercenarism.17 But this legislative failure
does not weaken a widely shared set of beliefs and assumptions, generat-
ing a consensus that in practice leads to restrictions on the hiring of
military force, or which reinforces moral hostility to its use.
The obvious point about the anti-mercenary norm is that it is enduring
and pervasive, but not susceptible to objective cost-benefit analysis: the
hiring of mercenaries is always wrong and undesirable, even when the
military alternatives will prove less effective in saving the state from
external defeat or internal fragmentation.18 States seeking to use the
services of external military forces betray their own organizational weak-
ness by such use, and by challenging the norm will reinforce an external
perception of their lack of civility, and the low level of their political and
social organization.
If this moral disapproval of the use of mercenaries forms one part of the
picture, it is reinforced by an equally powerful but pragmatic conviction
that the contracting-out of warfare is militarily self-defeating. The appli-
cation of military force should only be entrusted to those whose loyalty can
be ensured by shared national identity and allegiance. The ‘citizen army’
idealized by Machiavelli and cohorts of humanist and then nationalist
thinkers is contrasted with its apparent obverse, the mercenary soldier
Introduction 7
who serves only for money and outside territorial and ideological affili-
ations. The national soldier, fighting for country and family, has every-
thing to lose by showing limited military commitment; the mercenary has
only a service contract, on which he can renege with no more than
financial consequences. As such, it is assumed he must be unreliable in
his allegiance and half-hearted in his motivation. If a better financial offer
were to be made by the enemy, the logical behaviour for the mercenary
would be to accept it; the adoption of a decisive strategy involving hard-
fought battles with heavy casualties would be entirely contrary to the
interests of mercenary soldiers and their captains, whose own interests
would dictate drawn-out, expensive but indecisive conflict which would
keep them in employment for as long as possible. Both explicitly and
implicitly much writing about warfare picks up on these assumptions;
even if it is granted that mercenaries may, through length of service or
organizational expertise, have acquired particular military strengths and
skills, these will be counterbalanced by the deliberately limited nature of
their service and commitment. When mercenaries are hired en masse, it is
no less axiomatic that their captains, who have entered into military
activity for profit rather than for honour or duty, will seek to hire at the
lowest cost compatible with keeping the unit in being. In some medieval
and early modern cases of poor, resource-limited territories like
Switzerland or Scotland this pressure for cheapness may matter less: the
soldiers will still be raised on the basis of landed ties and other local
connections which may give them a high level of cohesion. But elsewhere
mercenary recruitment could easily mean acquiring soldiers or sailors
who were the social detritus of urban and rural life, lacking in resilience
as well as group identity, and unmotivated by any military objective except
plunder.
No amount of contrary evidence about the fighting commitment and
effectiveness of mercenaries in particular military circumstances will
change what seems, from one perspective, a set of logical assumptions
about their limitations as military operators. This in turn reinforces a view
of mercenaries as a worst option, to be adopted only by states for which no
better alternative exists, whether because of fiscal or administrative inca-
pacity, or through the weakness and corruption of a central regime. No
rational state or its ruler would choose such an ineffectual and unreliable
military system if other options were available.
The elision of these two negative arguments against private military
force makes a powerful rhetorical case. Indeed the combination of moral
repugnance with a ‘common-sense’ conviction that mercenaries make
bad and disloyal troops has been repeated so frequently that the counter-
productiveness of relying on private contractors can appear self-evident: a
8 The Business of War
school of nationalist German historians, for whom the history of the rise of
Brandenburg-Prussia was axiomatically the history of Germany, and,
from the 1860s, no less axiomatically the history of Europe. For a historian
like Johann Gustav Droysen, the Prussian experience demonstrated that
war was both the test and the catalyst of the growth of the state and the
achievement of nationhood: Brandenburg-Prussia had risen from being a
minor power and military victim during the Thirty Years War, to a state
which was to become the arbiter of German and European politics. It had
done so, although a small and under-resourced group of territories, by
systematically building up military force over a century from the 1640s to
1740s. Unwilling to submit to the political humiliations and economic
depredations that would stem from renewed military dependence on the
major powers, a sequence of Electors, then kings, in Prussia, focused their
attentions and the resources of their territories on creating a permanent
military force of a size and capability comparable with European powers
who possessed hugely superior resources. The story of the rise of Prussia
could be turned into the account of how, by eschewing the courtly and
cultural indulgence of other German rulers and by squeezing every fiscal
resource through unprecedented administrative efficiency, a permanent
army of 80,000 troops could be created by 1740, and could in turn be
expanded in a succession of mid-eighteenth-century wars which firmly
established Prussia as a great power in its own right.21 The centrality of the
army as the purpose and justification for every aspect of governmental
policy and every administrative initiative was undisputed: the very struc-
ture of society was organized around the militarization of the landowning
nobility and the organization of a large proportion of the male labouring
population in an annual cycle which alternated agricultural and military
service. In fact a permanent army on this scale was only viable on the basis
of hiring at least some of its troops from outside Prussian borders:
Frederick the Great sardonically referred to his grandfather, Frederick I,
as the ‘mercenary king’ for his willingness both to contract foreign troops
and then to hire them out to the Emperor. But for the historians of the
Prussian state, this was a necessary evil, justified, as it was at the time,
since it protected the economic capacity of the native population.22
Moreover such mercenary units were tamed and fully integrated by the
Prussian military model of drill, discipline and control, easily reduced to
component parts in the clockwork of a smoothly running military organ-
ization. They did nothing to detract from the military model which saw an
ideal synthesis of state, administration and army, so that even the desire to
spare some subjects from military service was, paradoxically, simply to
harness better the resources needed to sustain the army.
10 The Business of War
Prussian historians who saw the rise of the state and the rise of the state-
controlled army as synonymous were especially strident: relating military
prowess and the mobilization of military resources to survival and national
success in war produced a crude – modernization or extinction – mantra
which fitted well with the triumphalist assumptions of a post-1870
Germany. Its emulators, amongst whom were historians of other
German states, and, for example, nineteenth-century French administra-
tive historians, were no less prepared to see in military force the rationale
for the growth of the state. If historians of seventeenth-century France did
not present Cardinal Richelieu or Louis XIV as single-mindedly obsessed
with the building of a powerful, effective army, this nonetheless figures
extensively in most accounts of the ‘rise of absolutism’ via which the
history of French state-building was cast.23 Moreover the Revolutionary
and Napoleonic wars saw the French citizen army not merely as the
product of a second stage of state-formation, but as a triumphant embodi-
ment of the nation in arms.24
Much of this celebration of armies and state-building might seem overly
specific, above all, shaped by the particular case of Brandenburg-Prussia,
and the circumstances of the creation of the Second Reich in 1871. But
crucially for its enduring success, this relationship between military power
and the rise of the state was analysed from early on through more com-
prehensive and nuanced studies, which crossed the borders between
history and the social sciences. Max Weber’s analysis of the rise of
bureaucracy as a stage in state-formation devoted much attention to the
Prussian experience of a militarized administration in which the bureau-
cratic model could be developed within a disciplined context of contig-
uous civil and military hierarchies. Military necessity – the requirements
of creating and sustaining military force – is the strongest factor in the
evolution of bureaucratic process and the development of state power
through rational administration.25 Even more than Weber, Otto Hintze’s
essays, again in many cases concerned with the history of Brandenburg-
Prussia, examine much wider conceptual questions relating to European
political and constitutional change from the seventeenth into the eight-
eenth century.26 For Hintze, the requirement to create and maintain a
permanent army was the key to determining the construction and char-
acter of the state, providing a detailed explanation of its structure and
functioning.27 The political identity of the state developed under external
military pressure, pressure which forced the hands of governments and
their administrators in ways which would challenge existing political
structures and consensus. Where Hintze moved the discussion beyond
the Prussian school was in refusing to see this process in terms of historical
specificities – the particular geopolitics of Brandenburg; the ambitions or
Introduction 11
All of this seems familiar, not least because it has been reiterated in so
many subsequent historical and social-science accounts of the construc-
tion of the modern state: warfare and its demands and burdens exercise
the direct pressure without which rulers and their administrations would
continue to acquiesce in systems of government which could provide a
barely adequate level of central control, a modest share of the resources of
their subjects, and a respectful relationship with socio-political elites with
whom rulers generally shared a world view.30 In practice, much of their
response to these new problems and challenges can better be character-
ized as desperate expedients to fund or organize a hand-to-mouth military
struggle, rather than as a carefully planned strategy to extend the power of
central government, but the long-term effect is no less considerable in
shifting political authority in favour of the ruler and his administration.
War is not seen as the only force at work in this process of concentrating
and institutionalizing power and administrative competence. Attention
has been given to the impact of religious reformations and the consequent
drive of rulers to impose norms of behaviour and belief on their popula-
tions. Another plausible factor in this drive towards early modern state-
building has been identified as the great economic shift in early modern
Europe – population rise, inflationary pressures, economic polarization –
generating intense social conflict and a strong preoccupation with social
discipline and authority amongst elites. Yet another would identify the
self-interest of an administration itself, passing a critical threshold of scale,
competence and professional identity, and linking its own collective and
individual goals to the extension of government and the elimination of
alternative focuses of power and authority.31
Yet the primacy of the ‘military’ explanation for the growth of the
European state, and indeed for a competition between states in which
survival, expansion and the remodelling of the international system
towards powerful, autonomous nation-states will be achieved by those
who best organize and deploy their military resources, remains integral to
most interpretations of the period.32 The empirical evidence for the
pressure of war seems persuasive. Tables showing the increase in the
size of armies and navies indicate that the scale of military activity
increases dramatically. If France could maintain armies of approximately
30,000 in 1515 which had risen to 340,000 troops by 1692, while
England’s naval tonnage increased from around 30,000–40,000 tonnes
in 1588 to 196,000 tonnes in 1700, it would seem logical that the admin-
istrative burdens of financing, administration, control and deployment of
these armed forces should have increased proportionately. The military
history of early modern Europe can be presented as a sustained arms-race
in which new military technology, geographical scale and numbers of
Introduction 13
had been popular throughout the sixteenth century, many of them seem-
ingly intended to provide practical guidance for officers in subjects like
ballistics, troop deployment and the military duties of different grades of
officer. Many such works, and notoriously Machiavelli’s Arte della guerra,
cast their discussion in terms of parallels between the ancient and modern
styles of warfare, frequently using an idealized conception of the military
customs and organization of Antiquity, and especially the armies of
Republican Rome, as a stick with which to beat the supposed failures
and deficiencies of modern armies, the most egregious of which, for
Machiavelli and many of his contemporaries, was of course the reliance
on morally objectionable and militarily deficient mercenaries.37
The case for a radical ‘transformation’ of modern warfare grew out of
this fertile soil of theoretical tracts and ancient–modern comparisons, and
represents its logical evolution. For instead of joining the general chorus
lamenting the extent to which modern warfare fell short of the standards
of organization, discipline and training of the Romans, the novelty of the
Orange-Nassau theorists of the later sixteenth and early seventeenth
century, notably Maurice (Stadholder from 1587/9 to 1625) and his
nephew Johann von Nassau-Dillemberg, was to argue that the successful
adoption of classical Roman discipline and tactical deployment was the
secret of their own armies’ military success.38 The recently established
United Provinces had every reason to wish to present its military capa-
bilities in the best possible light. A new republic, struggling for recognition
and legitimacy in a world of monarchies for which inheritance and dynas-
tic rights were the currency of international relations and territorial legiti-
macy, saved from extinction at the hands of Alexander Farnese’s Army of
Flanders only by a shift in Philip II’s international priorities in the 1580s:
all of this would make it an uphill struggle to persuade other European
states, even Protestant powers, that the fledgling republic was worth the
risk of recognizing and supporting. The ability to persuade other powers
that the United Provinces had both the will and the capability to defend
itself against Spanish reconquest and other potential aggressors would be
an important element in winning support. Hence the widely publicized,
and widely believed, assertions that the army of the States General had
been transformed by a rigorous and systematic adoption of the military
prescriptions of Aelian, Vegetius and various other classical military writ-
ers, so that it transcended the typical indiscipline, poorly articulated
command and control, and crude tactics of contemporary armies to
become ‘perhaps the most efficient and certainly the most widely imitated
force of its age’.39 Above all, typical, loosely focused fighting prowess had
been transformed through the development and imposition of formalized
drill into collective, mechanical order and obedience.40
16 The Business of War
and capital in raising and maintaining armies and navies was neither
synonymous with military ineffectiveness, nor an obscure historical cul-
de-sac, a system which had no future amongst the rulers and administra-
tors of early modern states. This is a short book on a very large subject, and
as such it focuses attention on western and central Europe. Military
enterprise and contracting are a significant presence in eastern and
south-eastern European states, but would require a considerably more
extensive range of linguistic expertise to treat with any sophistication, and
such elements play a less clear-cut role in an existing historiographical
debate about war, military organization and state-formation. Nor does the
book examine in more than cursory fashion what was perhaps the greatest
of all European military enterprises, the creation of joint-stock trading
companies and their colonial military activities. Once again, the excuse for
this omission is both space and the basic recognition that the activities of
the companies are shaped by military developments and possibilities
within Europe and not vice versa. The book is divided into two parts.
The first, ‘Foundations and Expansion’, examines the emergence and
elaboration of systems of military enterprise through the sixteenth century
down to the end of the Thirty Years War. The second part, ‘Operations
and Structures’, shows how contracting worked from military and organ-
izational perspectives, and examines changes in emphasis and role in the
century after 1660.
Within Part I, Chapter 1 looks at various types of private military force
and organization available to European states in the period before the mid-
sixteenth century. It focuses attention on the Swiss, and the German
Landsknecht infantry, not just as substantial contributors to the market in
hired soldiers, but because understanding the reasons for the effectiveness
of these two military systems has lasting implications for a wider grasp of the
qualities and strengths of early modern armies. The second chapter begins
with an account of the mid-sixteenth-century crisis faced by states which
had relied heavily for their military forces on a traditional market in interna-
tional mercenaries. It suggests that the primary reason for this crisis was the
unfolding of conflict over much longer periods of continuous campaigning,
a process which was to culminate in the Thirty Years War, but had begun in
the 1550s. This challenge of sustaining military force over long sequences
of campaigns pushed existing mechanisms of state-controlled war finance
to breaking point, but also offered the opportunity systematically to deploy
the credit of military contractors: the role and character of private military
organization was to be transformed by the rise of the enterpriser, offering his
credit as well as organization and military skills in raising troops for the
state. The high-point of this development was reached in the Thirty Years
War, but this conflict was characterized by the flourishing and development
20 The Business of War
deploying military force were retained in the second half of the seven-
teenth century and beyond. There was no dramatic break, no abandon-
ment of a discredited past associated with ‘medieval’ decentralization and
devolved power. The language of military authority changed to emphasize
the direct control of the ruler over his armed forces and to counteract any
implication of authority mediated through military proprietorship. In
many cases rulers used the experience of war taxes imposed during the
Thirty Years War as a bargaining counter to obtain permanent tax grants
from their subjects that would allow them to establish small permanent
armies. But the wartime enlargement of these armies, and often a signifi-
cant part of the running costs of maintaining even small numbers of
permanent troops, depended upon retaining or creating mechanisms to
co-opt the financial resources of the officers. Whether this came through
the marketing of officerships via official or unofficial venality, or through
the maintenance of regimental or company proprietorship, the aim was
entirely traditional: to maintain a strong financial interest amongst the
officers in the operational effectiveness of their units. Beyond the units
themselves, the entire structure of logistical support, equipping and arm-
ing of the troops was almost without exception put out to contract in the
hands of private enterprisers. Even the building of warships and the
establishment of dockyards, often seen as a preserve of state administra-
tion and direct funding after 1650, still depended in large part on out-
sourcing to private contractors.
Instead of assuming that the Thirty Years War tested to destruction a
fundamentally flawed mechanism for the raising and maintenance of
military force, and then treating the subsequent period as the decisive
move towards the achievement of a state-controlled ‘monopoly of vio-
lence’, there is much to be said for stressing the strong elements of
continuity in state/military relations, and the deliberate maintenance of
systems that drew heavily on private capital, expertise and organization.
Rulers now asserted explicitly and directly their claim to the command of
armed forces within their jurisdiction and to all decisions about their use.
One consequence of this was that the subtle means–ends balance that
had characterized the deployment of military force during the later
Thirty Years War was broken; armies and navies grew inexorably larger
and more expensive under the aegis of rulers who saw them as an exten-
sion of their dynastic self-perception and ambitions. Paradoxically, of
course, this made the role of private capital and private organizational
input into recruiting, equipping and mobilizing troops all the more vital.
Historical thinking about war and the state in the later seventeenth and
eighteenth century needs to accommodate itself to a different set of
assumptions where, writing of the eighteenth-century French army, Jean
22 The Business of War
Chagniot could assert that it was the War of the Spanish Succession
(1702–13) which saw the apogee of military enterprise in France.50
Nomenclature
Some of the terminology used in discussing early modern military organ-
ization and military enterprise can be confusing. Throughout the book I
employ the useful concept, derived from Fritz Redlich, of the ‘warlord’ as
the party contracting with the military enterpriser for the raising of troops.
Warlords will tend to be territorial rulers, but this would not exclude the
town council of a wealthy city raising troops for their own defence, or
potentially an aristocrat raising troops on his own account. Although
contemporary titles for the commander of a regiment-sized unit vary
from state to state – maestre de campo in Spain, maître de camp in France,
for example – I use ‘colonel’ consistently to designate the commander of
such units, the typical building-blocks of armies raised by enterprisers. In
the case of infantry this unit itself could vary from a theoretical strength of
1,200–1,500 men up to the 4,000 of a full Landsknecht regiment. Cavalry
regiments were smaller, largely because the costs of equipping them and
providing the horses were so considerable. In both cases theoretical full
strength could be substantially larger than the real, operational strength.
The earlier Swiss equivalent of a regiment, the Haufe, or Gevierthaufe,
could be of varying size, and was usually made up of a number of excep-
tionally large ‘companies’ whose main characteristic was that the men
would be drawn from a particular canton. But Swiss troops serving under
‘free’ commanders – troops provided for a warlord without cantonal
authority – would also be divided into companies under a captain-
proprietor (Hauptmann). By the seventeenth century the Swiss would be
hired out to warlords in more typical regiment-sized units. Where appro-
priate I use the Spanish term tercio rather than regiment, especially as the
Spanish army would include tercios of Castilian troops and also contracted
regiments of Landsknechte or Walloons. Regiments are in all cases sub-
divided into companies, and the commanders of these companies, the
captains, may be the clients or appointees of the colonel-proprietor, serv-
ing at his expense, or may be subcontractors, who have themselves com-
mitted funds to raising troops. Free companies are no less an important
part of this military world, in which the captain levies and maintains a free-
standing company, perhaps as the basis of a garrison.
I use the term ‘mercenary’ sparingly, and reserve it for a unit
commander who raised troops under a traditional contract in which the
costs of recruitment and a substantial advance of wages are paid up front,
and as a precondition of the contract taking effect. In contrast to the
Introduction 23
This battle of Anghiari (1440) lasted two hours, during which first
Niccolò [Piccinino] and then the Florentine troops were masters of the
bridge . . . Niccolò’s troops won the bridge many times, and always they
were repelled by the fresh troops of their adversaries. But when the bridge
was won by the Florentines, so that their troops gained the road, Niccolò
did not have time, because of the fury of those who came and the
inconvenience of the site, to relieve his men . . . the whole army was
compelled to turn round and everyone fled toward Borgo without any
hesitation. The Florentine soldiers attended to the spoil, which was very
great in prisoners, harnesses and horses . . .
Nor were there ever times when war waged in these countries or others
was less dangerous for whoever waged it than these. In such a defeat . . .
only one man died, and he not from wounds or any virtuous blow, but
falling off his horse, he was trampled on and expired.1
27
28 Military resources for hire, 1450–1560
from the eastern cantons argued that they were bound to honour their
contract with Sforza. The arrival of a further 10,000 Swiss helped to tip the
balance in favour of maintaining loyalty to the duke and upholding their
contract. On 13 September around 21,000 Swiss infantry moved out of
Milan in three great blocks, intent on a direct confrontation with the
French. The French superiority in numbers and firepower was over-
whelming, and the troops had used the opportunity to construct gun
emplacements and maximize the advantages of the terrain.3 The Swiss
had no illusions about the fact that they were fighting in almost impossible
conditions and would suffer terrible casualties. Signifying this awareness,
the captain of the Zug contingent enacted a short, moving ritual before the
assault commenced: picking up three clods of earth in front of the first
square of infantry, he threw them over the heads of the troops with the
words: ‘in the name of the Father, Son and Holy Ghost, this will be our
churchyard, my good, faithful compatriots’.4
The battle was fought over two days, brought the Swiss close to victory
at crucial moments, but was ultimately won by the endurance of the
French forces – some 23,000 of whom were German mercenary
Landsknechte – and the arrival of 9,000–10,000 Venetian troops on the
morning of the second day. The remaining Swiss troops withdrew in good
order, but the available sources suggest that some 8,000–9,000 were killed
on the battlefield or died subsequently of their wounds in Milan.5
These two accounts illustrate diametrically opposed views of private
enterprise warfare. Machiavelli’s account of Anghiari is fictitious: it was
far from being a bloodless struggle, and the battle and the campaign of
1440 were crucial to the survival of Florentine independence.6 Yet
Machiavelli’s animus was real even if his facts were not, and points to a
debate about the use of mercenary companies that has dominated dis-
cussion of the military history of Renaissance Italy. In Machiavelli’s eyes,
the real crime of mercenaries was not just that they were feeble combat
troops, but that they commercialized war: they turned it from a crucible
for forging republican virtù amongst citizen-soldiers into a cost–benefit
calculation in which service, fighting, flight and booty were simply nego-
tiable commodities.
On the other side, the account of Marignano illustrates the hybrid
character of the mercenary system and the perils either of romanticizing
the events, given the large number of contingents bought off before the
battle, or of dismissing such troops in general as motivated only by pay and
plunder – which cannot explain the behaviour of the rest in a situation
where the odds on victory were slight, the certainty of massive slaughter
overwhelming. Historians’ accounts of Marignano frequently betray an
exasperation with the Swiss troops: an already anachronistic system,
Military resources for hire, 1450–1560 29
or areas where control of the seas was under dispute. The ability of the
Cossack communities in Ukraine, for example, to provide defence in
depth against the Ottomans, albeit on their own terms, made recognition
and association with the Cossacks attractive at different times to both
Polish and the Muscovite rulers.12 But the problem posed by the security
of borders is perhaps epitomized by the extended frontier stretching from
the Adriatic and along the line which separated the Habsburg and
Ottoman parts of Hungary after the Ottoman victory at Mohacs in
1526. This was a long, sinuous and contested frontier, stretching through
open and underpopulated territory which even in settled circumstances
would have possessed limited agricultural potential to maintain large
garrisons, let alone field armies. For the Habsburgs, struggling with multi-
ple European commitments and continuous demands on their financial
resources, a solution needed to be found for the Ottoman frontier which
would provide some level of security at sustainable expense. The key
element of the defence system was based upon a few imposing fortresses
supplemented by lesser garrisons and local defence works, requiring a
permanent military force of around 15,000–20,000 men.13 Part of the
costs of the troops and the fortifications was covered by taxes levied within
the Holy Roman Empire, and part was funded from Habsburg resources.
But this was inadequate as a means to secure a frontier which stretched
from Croatia to Transylvania. Elsewhere, the solution was dependence on
local communities, either already in existence or established as colonies in
or just behind the frontier zone.14 These groups would supplement a basic
living from agriculture with banditry and raiding carried out across the
frontiers, and a willingness to defend their own territories against incur-
sions by equivalent cross-frontier communities, or against larger-scale
military activity. For the Habsburg central state and notional ruler of
such territories, they provided a vital buffer: they prevented enemy
forces or enemy communities encroaching into Habsburg territory and
potentially threatening more important bases and centres; they unsettled
civilian and garrison life on the other side of the frontiers by their raids
and attacks; they may have lacked regular military organization, but they
were able to harass and slow the advance of regular forces, giving the
Habsburg armies time to concentrate and confront the danger posed by
the invasion.
A classic case on this frontier of such an alliance by loose association
was the Hapsburg reliance on the Uskok communities in Croatia, based
round the strategic seaport of Senj.15 The Habsburgs guaranteed the local
political and commercial privileges of the Uskok communities in return
for their willingness to defend the city of Senj itself and to act as a military
force in the region.16 The garrison duties were shared with a small force of
Irregulars and privateers 33
The Uskoks raise a larger question about entirely private military activ-
ity. They were a refugee population drawn to this part of the Adriatic coast
by the possibility of taking part in profitable military operations, and
would seem to have been remarkably well placed to combine raiding
and piracy from their bases. The economy of Senj revolved round the
purchase and disposal of captured booty, but the beneficiaries of this were
in general prosperous middlemen, who advanced the funds to purchase
ships, hire crews or fund and provision land operations, and would expect
to reclaim a high proportion of all the profits of the expedition.21
Moreover, as in so many other centres of pirate activity, goods often
needed to be sold at knock-down prices if they were perishable, or in
less than perfect markets if they were rare and valuable. An obvious
question throughout the early modern period is whether freelance military
operations, even on the relatively small scale of Uskok raiding parties and
pirate sloops with crews of ten or twenty men, were financially and
organizationally viable?
defences at La Coruña, Vigo and San Sebastián, and the similarly well-
maintained fortifications at Dunkirk for the Flanders privateers, were
essential to the viability of their operations: the safe havens behind
which the ships could be repaired and provisioned, and prizes and booty
could be secured and ultimately auctioned.32 Given that the privateers
were dependent on state-maintained, fortified bases, they were obliged to
work within the framework of crown military policy or face expulsion and
a hazardous existence as truly independent pirates. In the case of the
Dunkirk privateers, the Spanish crown took the integration of private
and state-coordinated military activity a great deal further. The activities
of the sixty to seventy privateering ships operating out of Dunkirk in the
1620s and 1630s were supplemented by a squadron of directly controlled
and funded royal frigates. Larger, custom-built and better-armed than the
ordinary privateering ships, they could take the initiative in launching
privateering operations, attack far larger and better-armed ships or con-
voys, and facilitate policies that were both more profitable and served the
interests of the Spanish crown better than would have been possible via
forces of entirely independent privateers.33 The frigates provided the
cutting edge to naval operations in which the privateers were the numer-
ous auxiliaries, submitting to campaign plans and leadership from which
they would expect to make larger profits than their own smaller-scale
guerre de course could achieve.
Above the level of individual and collective privateering could be placed
more formal associations of ships, still privately owned and financed, but
more effectively and permanently coordinated within a formal hierarchy
of leadership. The line here can be difficult to establish, but the Barbary
corsairs, for at least the first half of the sixteenth century, were subordi-
nated and expected to participate in larger military projects directed by the
Ottoman government from Constantinople, albeit that these policies
involved capturing prizes, looting and plundering Christian coasts and
generating income for the individual shipowners.34 The Knights of
St John could be placed at the next level: a tighter structure and organ-
ization than the corsairs, and though the Order as an institution was self-
financing through landed endowments and through the capture and sale
of prizes, the role of the individual galley commander was much less
prominent.35 The Knights and their half-dozen galleys were outnum-
bered in Malta by privateers, many of whom were ex-members of the
Order who had taken up private operations after ‘retiring’.36 As Malta was
a fief of the Spanish monarchy, and Charles V had granted the Order the
right to establish themselves there when they were driven from Rhodes in
1522, the extent that they could escape becoming an adjunct to the
Spanish galley fleet was limited.37 They were expected to sail in support
38 Military resources for hire, 1450–1560
and subject to compulsory purchase, the ships were then seized at Port
Louis by the duc de Soubise at the beginning of the French Protestant
rebellion of 1625.44 Nevers’ crusading fleet became the core of a
Protestant naval squadron maintained at La Rochelle until the end of
the revolt.45
Early modern societies could sustain a considerable diversity of private
naval activity from individual privateering vessels, small-scale privateering
fleets, up to first-rank galley and galleon squadrons. If a ruler wished to
make direct use of these resources there were a variety of means at his
disposal from co-option based on legitimization of activities and control of
facilities, through to the outright hiring under contract of individual ships
or entire naval squadrons.
At the same time, the owners of such private naval force were aware of
their limitations: privateers’ remuneration depended upon the unpredict-
able capture of prizes or plunder; the financial risks of this made any
Emden
Waterford
Wexford Amsterdam
Middelberg
Ostende Flushing
Kinsale Bristol
Poole Nieuwpoort
Plymouth Dunkirk
Falmouth Calais
Channel Islands
St Malo
Nantes
Tripoli
their provisions, pay and, ideally, substantial booty.50 Until the largest
company, led by Fra Moriale, passed to Conrad of Landau in 1354, these
companies rarely enjoyed any permanent existence: having achieved the
purpose of enriching the participants, they would dissolve, to be created
anew a few years later when the ending of another war threw large
numbers of experienced veterans out of service.
Yet by the later 1350s the familiar patterns of extortion and localized
conquest were encountering stiffer resistance; the great company under
Landau was defeated in battle by Florence in both 1358 and 1359, and the
search for softer targets was also starting to yield more meagre results. A
loose association of self-seeking mercenaries was intensely vulnerable to
military setbacks: these would encourage wider resistance to their
demands, while the cohesion and logistical support of the company
depended on a regular supply of extorted money and goods. Despite
operating within some of the most sophisticated economies in Europe,
there was no easy access to credit for forces which were international,
transient and lacked leaders who could present themselves as a good
financial risk. Without this, an apparently terrifying force of thousands
of battle-hardened mercenaries could simply melt away in a few weeks.
The next generation of captains were more aware of this vulnerability,
and had a longer-term perspective on the raising and deployment of the
forces under their command.51 The best known of this new generation,
John Hawkwood, seems early on to have envisaged his primary role as a
contractor in the service of territorial powers. It certainly helped that the
force that Hawkwood took command over, the famous White Company
made up of soldiers who had fought in France down to the Peace of
Bretigny in 1360, could offer local rulers an attractive combination of
skilled military manpower and new technology/tactics. Drawing on
English fighting methods in France, the company made use of both the
dismounted man-at-arms and the longbow, and supplemented this new
style of fighting with powerful group cohesion and high levels of military
experience. Italian rulers were hiring not merely veteran soldiers, but a
proven and effective weapon system which still held the tactical edge over
any comparable-sized force serving in Italy.52 Over a thirty-year career,
Hawkwood and the White Company served Pisa, Milan and the Papacy,
finally settling into Florentine service from 1377 to 1394.53 The foreign
mercenary company was a particular phenomenon associated most obvi-
ously with a few decades in the mid-fourteenth century. The resumption
of conflict in France, the military demands of the transalpine powers for
experienced troops, and the readiness of Italian captains to offer a variety
of sizes and combinations of military forces under contract, all started to
change the pattern of military service in the Italian states.
42 Military resources for hire, 1450–1560
who had served well on the basis of past contracts could be hired again
when required.
Part of the relationship between warlords and condottieri was about
trying to come to terms with this issue of demand and supply, and indeed
goes to the heart of what in these circumstances is entailed by a condotta, or
contract. The starting point was that there was no single, generic condot-
tiere company. The highest-profile figures in the mid-fourteenth century
had been the foreign military veterans, who had initially simply sought to
establish short-term protection rackets, but had come to see the benefits of
offering longer-term military service to established rulers. But from the
outset and throughout this period, there had been far larger numbers of
Italian condottieri.57 By the later century the field had become dominated
by Italians: the Malatesta, Gattamelata, Attendoli/Sforza families proved a
far more prominent and lasting presence than Hawkwood, Albrecht Sterz,
Hannekin Bongarten and the other foreign captains. But in this field
dominated by Italian captains, there was an almost infinite variety of
military organization, from companies of several thousand armoured
cavalry, commanded by captains with a princely title in their own right,
down to the smallest independent contractors, offering the service of a few
dozen soldiers.58 The style and terms of contracts varied considerably in
relation to the status, scale and reputation of the condottiere.
Early on, however, the condotte were evolving to recognize the respective
strengths and weaknesses of the positions of the condottiere and the war-
lord. The key clauses concerned the length of service and the immediate
payment to the captain. The typical fifteenth-century condotta would be
for six months – in an earlier period they had been for two to three months
only – and usually included a clause for an optional additional period – di
rispetto – of the same length. This additional period would be at the
discretion of the warlord, but he would be obliged to provide notice
some weeks ahead of the expiry of the first half of the contract.59 If this
discretion seemed to serve the interests of the contracting warlord, the
financial arrangements emphatically reflected the ‘seller’s market’ in
which many troops would be hired. All condotte stipulated an advance,
the prestanza, which was to be paid immediately to the condottieri to allow
them to recruit their companies up to strength, provide equipment and
move the troops to the agreed rendezvous. The sum amounted to between
a third and a half of the total sum agreed for the contract. Payment of this
was in theory non-negotiable: receipt of the cash activated the condotta.60
The advance was the vital element in the financing of the military system,
and went some way to ensuring that the condottiere had the resources to
raise the specified numbers of troops, and to provide some safeguards
were the warlord to seek to dissolve the unit early on grounds of
44 Military resources for hire, 1450–1560
selection to achieve the agreed total of the levy. All those eligible for
service were obliged to provide their own weapons and appropriate
armour: breastplates and iron helms for the pikemen, in some cases partial
armour for the halberdiers. Those called for service, but unable to afford
weapons and armour, would be helped either from the town armoury or
by loans of equipment from neighbours who were not summoned for
military duty.85 Much of the support system for the troops – food supplies
to be purchased at least while the troops were passing through the
Confederation, transport for artillery, baggage and potentially for cap-
tured booty – was provided by the authorities.86 Though elements of the
local elites, especially wealthy merchants, could buy exemption from
military service via provision of arms, equipment and the hiring of sub-
stitutes, it would still be true that a higher proportion of the Swiss popu-
lation took an active part in military activity than in other contemporary
states.87 But if this appeared to some contemporaries and in subsequent
accounts as an apparently utopian model of collective, democratic civil
defence,88 the reality was rather different.
What made the Swiss military system work so effectively? Conscripting
and equipping the troops might be a collective exercise, but the tactical
effectiveness of the great Swiss infantry squares depended on military
professionalism and experience at two levels. The forces needed to be
led by men who knew how to deploy their troops effectively in very
different conditions and against different types of enemy – from French
and Burgundian heavy cavalry to Landsknechte who mirrored Swiss battle
tactics. This kind of tactical and operational skill had to be combined
with distinct leadership qualities. The cooperation of leaders of cantonal
contingents needed to be won by consultation and active involvement in
decision-making, while the ordinary soldiers had a strong sense of their
fighting identity and needed to be handled with respect and restraint.89
While such leaders were part of the cantonal elites and were involved in
decision-making in that context, they were also marked out by their
lengthy military service and experience.90 In general they came from a
tight-knit group of noble families with an extensive tradition of military
leadership, who looked on military command as a career rather than an
occasional act of patriotic duty.91 A noble family like the Stockalper from
Brig held a succession of military commands from the fifteenth to the
seventeenth century, with a representative figure like Peter von Stockalper
leading a large contingent of the Swiss troops in the French army at Pavia
in 1525.92 Another noble family, the Courten von Siders, dominated
recruitment and led troops from the Wallis through the sixteenth and
seventeenth centuries, combining this with a succession of influential
cantonal offices.93 Service abroad was the obvious means to acquire and
50 Military resources for hire, 1450–1560
Kriegsgurgeln – and the Mats who were still part of the community but were
under pressure as younger sons or unmarried relatives to draw their
subsistence from outside that local community. The numbers prepared
to volunteer for military service, either when authorized by the canton or
simply organized by officers for foreign service, were impressive: of the
30,000 men raised by the Confederation to attack Dijon in 1513, some
14,000 had come forward as simple volunteers, offering their military
experience in the hope of gain from pay and plunder.111
In a striking prefiguration of the activities of later military enterprisers, it
was thus possible for some of these ‘free’ commanders to raise large
numbers of troops, drawing simply on their ability to raise Swiss volun-
teers without recourse to any cantonal conscription or selection. The
precise number is not given, but in 1486–7 the eldest son of Count Jörg
von Werdenberg-Sargans was able to attract ‘around fifty companies’ of
volunteer soldiers for a war against Milan, against the explicit wishes of the
authorities in the Drei Bünde.112 The capacity of these private captains to
raise large numbers of troops was recognized by foreign warlords: in 1499
the French sought to recruit 12,000 Swiss soldiers on the basis that
they would negotiate with forty independent captains, prepared to raise
soldiers outside of cantonal organization.113
Moreover, as Swiss troops after 1515 again started to be hired less often
as a free-standing, battle-winning force, and more as a powerful addition
to a mixture of other units raised by a warlord, so the range of opportu-
nities for independent captains grew. There were large numbers of expe-
rienced captains who, in return for financial advances on their contract,
could raise one or several infantry companies of 100–300 men each, and
even a regiment at its later sixteenth-century strength of 1,000–3,000
men. The captains would receive funds from the warlord, and would
then use their reputation, local influence or social position to seek out
volunteers, who would arrive for service equipped and armed at their own
expense. Without the involvement of the cantonal officials, there was no
official mechanism to loan arms and armour to those selected for service
who lacked money to buy them. Instead there is some evidence of small-
scale financial investment in the individual soldier: money being lent him
for the purchase of halberd or breastplate against hopes of a good return
on a successful campaign.114 Some of this may have been more system-
atic: the captains who raised 6,000 troops for Ludovico Sforza’s service in
1500, Wilhelm von Diesbach, Jean Matter, Gutmann Zoller, George de
Riva and Antoine Wider, all contributed some of their own funds for
raising and equipping their companies.115
Where real differences opened up between captains offering ‘free’
military service to foreign warlords and those acting as the agents of a
54 Military resources for hire, 1450–1560
The Landsknechte
The other group of mercenaries whose contribution to the eventual
emergence and flourishing of military enterprise is of central importance
are the Landsknechte, to whom might be added the other substantial group
of German mercenaries hired by foreign warlords from the 1530s
onwards, the pistol-armed cavalry, or Reiter. The Landsknechte appear to
have been recruited from the time of Maximilian I, specifically as a
response to the Swiss Haufen, with the Germans employing the same
weapons, formations and tactics. Maximilian threw his own weight and
reputation behind the levying and organization of the Landsknechte, seek-
ing to overcome German noble disdain for infantry service by carrying a
pike himself and rewarding successful Landsknecht commanders with
honours and titles.119 Rather more rapidly than the Swiss, the
Landsknecht regiments started to substitute arquebuses and the heavier
muskets for halberds and other short-handled weapons. By 1570 each
company (Fähnlein) contained 200 infantry with firearms against the
remainder (somewhere between 100 and 200) armed with pikes.120 Like
The Landsknechte 55
the Swiss Haufen and the Spanish tercios, the size of the combat unit
gradually declined: a Landsknecht infantry regiment would be recruited
at 4,000 men in the 1560s, but the numbers of effectives would usually be
lower than that, with a company of 300 on paper being closer to 220 in
practice.121 As with most other European infantry the numbers within a
regiment or its equivalents were drifting down towards a typical 1,500–
3,000 troops by the end of the sixteenth century. The system of recruiting
and operating the Landsknechte differed from that of the Swiss in the
absence of any equivalent of the cantonal structure and authorities to
authorize, control, and in many cases administer the levy and deployment
of troops.
The Landsknechte were raised throughout the constituent territories and
jurisdictions which formed the Holy Roman Empire. The initiative to
raise infantry on a scale and in formations large enough to match the
Swiss on the battlefield probably came from Emperor Maximilian. But
Imperial authority was not capable of coercing or demanding a military
contribution from the innumerable rulers over whom the Emperor pos-
sessed ultimate juridical authority but little practical power. Any equiv-
alent of the cantons’ universal military service was a pipe dream of
theorists like the writer, soldier and Imperial councillor Lazarus von
Schwendi.122 In the face of a generally perceived common threat, the
territories of the Empire might agree to provide financial contributions
to the Emperor as defender of the common interest through the regional
assemblies of the Reichskreise, the ‘Circles’ or regions of the Empire. The
one threat in the sixteenth century which was likely to command some
consensus was Ottoman pressure on the Habsburg lands and on south-
central Germany; for this a military tax, the Römermonate, was collected in
accordance with the agreement made with Charles V at Worms (Wormser
Matrikel) in 1521. A single Römermonat involved the collective levy of
15,371 infantry from the Empire, with a monthly pay and upkeep cost
added to this of 88,500 gulden. Depending on the nature of the military
emergency, the Diet could vote multiple tax grants which would maintain
an Imperial army for an agreed period.123 The Emperor could draw upon
the tax revenues to finance the campaign, and the territories within the
Circles would undertake or contract the levy of the specified numbers of
troops. Römermonate from the Circles might occasionally be available for
the pursuit of Habsburg dynastic interests in Italy, or directly against
France, but in general this would be funded by direct and indirect tax
resources, extraordinary lay and clerical subsidies from the Habsburg
lands.124
The actual levy of troops was a local matter, in which the smaller
German territorial princes and the subject nobility of medium and larger
Fig. 1.2 A contemporary visualization of Swiss and German pike-squares clashing outside the walls of a city
The Landsknechte 57
states might play a role as military contractors. But above all it was the
activity of the independent (Reichsunmittelbar) Imperial knights
(Reichsritter). These latter figure largely in the contracts for the hire of
Landsknechte, and include many of the names most closely associated with
the military history of the period: Berlichingen, Ems zu der Hohenems,
Sickingen, Schertlin von Burtenbach, Fürstenberg, Truchseß von
Waldburg. In most cases they were noble landowners for whom the addi-
tional financial attractions of successful military service were consider-
able, and who were unconstrained by the juridical complications of being
princely subjects. The extent that this became the knightly métier can be
seen from its continuation into the Thirty Years War, with no less reso-
nant military names like Pappenheim and Hatzfeld emerging from this
class. Though rather like the social rise of the condottiere in the fifteenth
century, the later, larger-scale and more complex military enterprise of the
seventeenth-century Empire became the province of the younger sons and
brothers of princely families. In contrast, sixteenth-century mercenary
activity in the Empire was dominated by the Reichsritter. There were a
few exceptions: the most famous of all Landsknecht commanders, Georg
von Frundsberg, was from a noble family who were subjects of the
Habsburg archdukes of the Tyrol.125 Martin Schwarz, notorious from
British history as the captain of 2,000 Landsknechte led against Henry VII
at the battle of Stoke in 1487, seems to have been a cobbler before he
progressed through the military ranks in the 1470s.126 At the other end of
the scale, some of the German princes, like their Italian counterparts, did
become directly involved in raising and hiring out bodies of soldiers:
Albrecht Alkibiades of Brandenburg provided a notorious example in
1552 when he hired out his army corps to the French for an invasion of
the Habsburg Netherlands.127 But the German soldier trade remained
dominated by the Imperial knights at least until the second half of the
sixteenth century, and their claim to make contracts with any warlord they
wished – the principle of Reislaufen – had direct consequences for the
capacity to satisfy external requests for the service of Landsknechte or
Reiter. The strongest opponent of this claim was the Emperor himself, to
whom all of these otherwise Reichsunmittelbar knightly captains owed
allegiance. Under Emperor Charles V, contracting to serve the French
king meant, more often than not, direct military opposition to the
Emperor, so the debate about ‘foreign’ service intensified. The one victim
of judicial proceedings to assert this principle was Colonel Sebastian
Vogelsberger. Brought to trial for having served François I in the 1530s
and having offered to recruit troops for Henri II at the time of the
Schmalkaldic War, he was executed in 1548. But Vogelsberger, though
enjoying wealth and office from his military service, had been born the son
58 Military resources for hire, 1450–1560
the 5,000 Landsknechte in French service at the battle of Pavia, but there
was little real sense of cultural identity that could be used to stimulate
cohesion.146 Appeals to Imperial service and common duty as the
Emperor’s vassals cut little ice when pay was in arrears, as Frundsberg
himself discovered in Verona in 1510 and again in 1527 at San Giovanni
near Bologna.147 And unlike the Swiss, the German soldiers, infantry and
cavalry, had few reservations about fighting each other as hired soldiers of
opposing powers, partly of course because recruitment across large and
diverse German territories outweighed any strong sense of a common
culture. The captain of the Zug contingent who told the soldiers of the
leading Swiss Haufe at Marignano that the battlefield would be their
churchyard, then appealed to them to ‘be courageous and think of their
home’. It is difficult to see that this shared concept of ‘home’ could have
an obvious collective German equivalent.148
Nor could religious identity be easily pressed into service by the military
authorities. Despite the distinctive piety and popular beliefs of the
Landsknechte – similar to those of the Swiss – on the eve of battle or after
military successes, soldiers and their officers were remarkably resistant to
the currents of evangelical reform unleashed from the 1530s and
1540s.149 Attempts to foster a strong, confessional identity amongst the
Landsknechte failed, as did most attempts to demonize enemies in terms of
their heterodox religious beliefs. Recent work continues to maintain the
judgement of Anton Schindling that armies in the Empire were confes-
sional ‘free states’ in the early modern period, in which religious piety and
practice was certainly evident, but strong confessional divisions and
antipathies much less so.150 That this was not necessarily the case with
all early modern soldiers can be seen through the example of the Spanish
soldiers of the tercios, whose behaviour and group indentity was strongly
shaped by a powerful, militant Catholicism.151
It is easy to depict the sixteenth-century mercenary as driven straight-
forwardly by greed or need; whether they were seeking to exploit their
military role to extort money from society, or whether they were victims
of that society, forced to become soldiers by a harshening economic
environment, their motivation was crudely material.152 When his own
Landsknechte surrounded Frundsberg at San Giovanni, threatening him
with violence over their arrears of pay, shouting ‘Money, Money’, and
then declaring that they would undertake no further military action until
their arrears were paid, it might seem perverse to question this bottom line
of their motivation for service.153 Like the Swiss, the Landsknechte
received decent wages: at four Rhenish gulden a month, this was typically
half a gulden less than the Swiss, but still double the pay of a farm labourer
and more than a skilled journeyman.154 With the appropriate, privately
The Landsknechte 61
could either act as a legitimizing force for the verdict and sentence, or
might register their disapproval or dissatisfaction with proceedings.168 In
some cases of crimes against fellow soldiers, the company would also act
as collective executioner, forcing the condemned to pass along two lines of
spear-armed soldiers who would beat and stab him to death.169 This again
was a recognition of the condemned soldier’s status; he would not be
humiliated by being handed over to the ‘dishonourable’ charge of a
regimental executioner.170
The obvious result of this popular participation in regimental justice
was to weaken the disciplinary sanctions of the senior officers over their
troops. It was difficult and sometimes dangerous to seek to prosecute
66 Military resources for hire, 1450–1560
extremely strong group bonding and the nature of military life gave them a
sense of assertive separateness, of being outside the norms of a settled,
‘respectable’ society.177 If a powerful motivation for enlistment and serv-
ice was a heightening of social status through the rights and freedoms
enjoyed as members of a prestigious corporation, an equally powerful
force was the cohesiveness gained from standing as a close-knit group
outside of, or hostile to, society. This latter tendency is characteristic of
many armies and navies, but it has rarely been carried to such conspicuous
extremes as by the Landsknechte, and certainly explains much of the
particular antagonism towards this style of mercenary warfare expressed
by many of the moralizing writers of the sixteenth century.
Much has been written on Swiss and Landsknecht dress and appearance,
and depictions of individuals and groups, whether from life or as carica-
tures, fascinated contemporary artists, supplying what was evidently a
large market for engravings.178 It is easy to imagine the impact of a
group of Landsknechte arriving in some small town or community in
central Germany, with their extraordinary, multi-coloured and extrava-
gant costumes, highly individualized, flamboyant in their use of slashing
(to reveal other, expensive fabrics beneath the top layer), elaborate stitch-
ing and ruffles, feathers, plumes and other decorations, in many cases
inspired by lively and colourful Italian styles of dress. Landsknecht cos-
tume was about conspicuous consumption: the soldiers had access to cash
paid as a monthly sum, intended to cover costs of food, lodging and
upkeep, but readily spent on gambling, drinking and the purchase of
provocatively expensive clothing. The dress was also unmistakeably
about assertive masculinity and sexuality: brightly coloured fabrics and
deliberately conspicuous codpieces, puffed and padded jackets which
emphasized shoulders and chest, tight leggings, fabric slashing to reveal
bare skin on legs, arms and chest. In a communal culture where the
disruptive effects of unconstrained sexuality were a strong source of
anxiety to religious and civil authorities, the dress and swaggering, aggres-
sively masculine behaviour of the Swiss or the Landsknecht were an open
provocation, an incitement to fornication, adultery, and illegitimate chil-
dren.179 That they would readily impress non-military young males and
encourage them to try to imitate clothing and behaviour, even if they did
not seek to enlist, was a further reason for concern.180 ‘I likewise require
modestie in apparell’, thundered the predictably puritanical Justus
Lipsius, in a comment that might otherwise appear a low priority in a
work on military discipline.181
Dress though was only one part of a more systematic rejection of the
norms of civil society in the social and cultural behaviour of the Landsknechte
and their Swiss counterparts. Their detachment from the settled life of town
Fig. 1.4 Landsknecht dress, an attractive subject for artists and engravers through the sixteenth century
.
The Landsknechte 69
and country was also embodied in the Troß, a great extended and mobile
camp of wagons, carts, porters, draught and pack animals, food and
merchandise vendors, servants, women, children and animals that
accompanied the regiments of troops to provide a combination of support
services, shops and social environment. The Troß was where the soldier
stored his possessions and might establish his wife, children or servants,
where he bought his food and drink, sold his booty, and could buy the
services of tailors, cobblers, barbers, surgeons, notaries and whores.182
This last service provided by the Troß was notorious amongst moralists
and critics of this military system. While they might grudgingly have
accepted the practical, physical necessity for the presence of whores with
the army – ‘no whores, no war’ was a popular saying from this period183 –
the openness with which the trade was plied and the lack of censoriousness
from the senior ranks of the unit presented a sharp contrast with the often
tortuous hypocrisy of settled civil society.
The open tolerance of the presence and role of whores within the army
camp was embodied in the office of the Hurenwaibel. Although this man
in fact had a wider responsibility for the general good order of all of the
services, marketing and other activities within the camp, he was specif-
ically identified for his role as the overseer and supervisor of the prosti-
tutes, a post which involved resolving disputes, preventing violence
and ensuring that the women were kept in the camp and were separated
from the troops when they were directly engaged in military activities.
Far from being a modest, low-key position, the Hurenwaibel in a large
army enjoyed a status equivalent to a company captain and had a team
of assistants.184 The frequent subject of engravings and descriptions of
the various ranks and duties of military officers, the Hurenwaibel was the
public face of an army organization which was increasingly at odds with
those urgent attempts at moral reformation and discipline that were
being launched by spiritual and civil authorities through the sixteenth
century.
If the enforcement of discipline amongst the Landsknechte may have
reflected collective consensus as much as top-down enforcement of
formal regulation, there is little doubt that the consensus was least
likely to support the punishment of soldiers who pillaged, stole or
perpetrated violence against civil populations, even those within the
territory of the warlord who had hired the soldiers. Though many of
the senior officers did recognize both a prudential and a moral duty to
try to protect civilians from their soldiers, the cultural and social
assumptions of the soldiers themselves did little to restrain lawless
behaviour against those who were outside the bounds of internal loyalty
and recognition.185
70 Military resources for hire, 1450–1560
The roles of both Swiss troops and Landsknechte illustrate the ambiguity
of a widespread acceptance of the military qualities of the professional
soldiers of the sixteenth century, and yet an unease about the extent to
which they were able to define their own relationship to surrounding
society. This ambiguity forms one of the most important contexts in
which the developing role of military enterprise in the later sixteenth and
seventeenth centuries should be seen.
2 The expansion of military enterprise,
1560–1620
As troops across western Europe dispersed into winter quarters, ports and
garrisons in late 1555, the fifth continuous campaign fought between the
Emperor Charles V and his rival, Henri II of France, came to an incon-
clusive end. Both rulers and their governments were well aware of the
fiscal stresses that this uninterrupted warfare was generating. In 1553
French military expenses, not including fortification works, were conser-
vatively estimated at 13.2 million livres, and with similar expenditure in
prospect for each successive year of war, it was impossible to meet military
expenses without a dramatic increase in borrowing.1 In 1555 the French
crown sought to reorganize its financial dealing through what became
known as the Grand Parti, based on a consortium of Lyon-based bankers
who raised the ever-larger sums required by the crown via the interna-
tional financial community which transacted business at the three-
monthly Lyon money fairs.2 Charles V and his son Philip were no less
aware of the fiscal pressures of warfare. In February 1555 it was estimated
that more than a million ducats would be required simply to maintain
Spain’s defensive positions on the frontiers of the Milanese, while a
serious offensive would cost vastly more.3 The situation in the
Netherlands was even worse, with a state debt of 7 million florins by the
end of 1555, and an annual deficit of 3 million ducats.4
The traditional instinct of rulers in this situation was to look for a peace
settlement that would preserve reputation but would allow for the drastic
curtailment of borrowing and some consolidation of existing debts. This
had been the case after the last round of the Habsburg–Valois struggle,
fought from 1542 down to the 1544 Peace of Crépy.5 The negotiation of
the truce of Vaucelles in February 1556 came as no great surprise there-
fore; but its collapse later in the year, as the new Carafa pope, Paul IV,
provoked a conflict with the Spanish over control of Naples and drew the
French back into Italy to provide military support, was an alarming new
development.6 War broke out again in northern France and was to reach
its climax in August 1557 with the crushing French defeat at St Quentin.
French attempts to redress the military balance led to a last series of
71
72 The expansion of military enterprise, 1560–1620
From a modern perspective, to suggest that waging war will become ever-
more costly is such a truism that it is easy to forget long periods of history
when either the scale of warfare and the levels of military technology
remained stable, or the costs of technological progress – improvements in
the quality of armour or the breeding of superior warhorses, for example –
were largely borne by individual warriors. But from the end of the fifteenth
century, European states moved into a period when both the scale and
expense of waging war increased exponentially, and, equally importantly,
when the possibility that this warfare would last for a series of continuous
campaigns also became far greater.
The decades from 1500 to 1550 saw the largest percentage increase in
the military establishments of European states before the second half of
the seventeenth century.13 It is tempting to offer a structural explanation
for this military expansion, pointing to the widespread and rapid
European population growth from the later fifteenth century as the
means by which larger numbers of troops could be recruited at lower
cost. However, if surplus population might facilitate the raising of larger
armies or navies, the second stage of this determinist argument, that the
greater economic activity that accompanied population growth provided
states and their rulers with larger revenues to pay for these additional
troops, looks less convincing. Seemingly substantial increases in state
revenues need to be offset against the underlying rates of sixteenth-
century price inflation.14 The absolute increase in revenues was in most
cases modest; at best, what rulers gained was greater access to forms of
credit which they lacked the fiscal organization or the solid and assured
revenues and other resources to consolidate into stable, long-term debt.15
The ability to realize substantial, permanent increases in taxation reve-
nues was generally limited by a combination of constitutional and pru-
dential restraints on rulers.16
In fact the key precipitant of military growth in these decades was a series
of contingent political developments. From the 1520s the Ottoman Empire
brought unprecedented armies and navies to bear on central Europe and
the Mediterranean. The major role in resisting Ottoman expansion fell to
the Habsburg ruler Charles V, whose stupendous dynastic inheritance and
elective title of Holy Roman Emperor provided a resource base not seen in
the West since the fall of the Roman Empire. This unanticipated windfall of
inheritances gave him the ability to call upon resources and troops from well
over half the states of western and central Europe, mobilizing military forces
both to confront Ottoman expansion and, more immediately, to rebuff
France, whose Valois monarchs deployed the resources of the most pop-
ulous state in Christendom to wage a series of wars with the aim of
fragmenting and undermining the Habsburg monarchia. The result of
74 The expansion of military enterprise, 1560–1620
Table 2.1 Growth in army size in the first half of the sixteenth century: France,
the Habsburg lands and England
Sources: Figures from Lot, Recherches; J. R. Hale, War and Society, pp. 62–3; J. J. Scarisbrick,
Henry VIII (London, 1968); C. S. L. Davies, ‘England and the French War, 1557–9’, in
J. Loach and R. Tittler (eds.), The Mid-Tudor Polity, c.1450–1560 (London, 1980), pp. 159–85.
open land and outworks. The walls were themselves defended against
direct assault or mining by large, projecting bastions, able to provide
stable platforms for the defenders’ artillery and allowing them to rake
the exposed approaches to the fortifications with gunshot. This develop-
ment, the so-called trace italienne, was gradually to transform the military
landscape of whole areas of west-central Europe, and in the cases of
powers with colonial interests and territories, their overseas holdings as
well.20 Building such fortifications was expensive, and a relatively slow
and labour-intensive process; it was not possible to wait for an imminent
threat before embarking on such defensive programmes. Between 1529
and 1572 some 43 kilometres of trace italienne were constructed in the
Southern Netherlands at a cost of around 10 million florins.21
While European navies and naval warfare did not reach a similar crisis-
point in the 1550s, a sixteenth-century pattern of substantial growth in
numbers of ships, their size and cost is also evident. Shipboard artillery
was developed along a number of divergent lines as designers and builders
of high-sided sailing ships sought to come to terms with the new threat
posed by extremely heavy guns mounted in the prows of galleys.22 The
problems of matching the low-mounted, forward-firing guns of the galleys
ultimately produced the solution of a new generation of ships, the ‘race-
built’ galleon design, with lower forecastles into which heavy forward-
firing artillery could be set. In this context broadside guns mounted more
deeply in the ships were initially a secondary development, but became
increasingly important as it was recognized that a broadside battery could
follow on from the fire of the ‘ship-smashing’ heavy guns in bow and stern.
This overall concern to maximize the heavy firepower of sailing ships was
itself a catalyst for subsequent changes in shipbuilding and tactics, and the
tonnage of newly built warships steadily increased in the last decades of
the sixteenth century, matched by a growing complement of heavy artil-
lery.23 Until cast-iron cannon became more widespread and available, this
hugely increased the costs of fitting out a warship, or an armed merchant-
man, with an appropriate armament. Moreover, sailing ships were built to
progressively higher specifications in order to survive direct hits from
cannon shot, to absorb the recoil shock of their own cannon fire, and to
stand up to sea and weather conditions.24 Although it was not until the
1650s and the development of the line of battle that the purpose-built
warship all but eliminated the traditional use of armed merchantmen as a
major element of battle fleets, there had been a steady increase in the
numbers of ships built and crewed primarily as naval vessels during the
preceding century. A bigger proportion of navies was being made up of
large, specialized warships which were unsuited to playing a dual role as
merchantmen, and the costs of which, even if maintained under contract,
76 The expansion of military enterprise, 1560–1620
fell heavily on the resources of the state.25 This, for the Mediterranean
powers, would be coupled with the continued need to maintain fleets of
heavier, better-armed and larger-crewed galleys, further increasing the
costs of the state’s seaborne strategies.26
So to an unprecedented, politically driven increase in the size of armed
forces could be added the implications of some new military technology,
notably the trace italienne and the heavy-gunned warship. All contributed
to making military growth harder to reverse, and to ensuring that the
financial costs of such expansion, measured in terms not just of soldiers
hired, but of cubic metres of earth shifted and bronze cannon expensively
purchased, consistently outpaced states’ revenues. When, from the mid-
dle decades of the sixteenth century, one final factor was added, the entire
edifice became unsustainable.
Though the costs of war were steadily increasing through the earlier part
of the century, the worst fiscal and organizational effects of this pressure
were mitigated by the shortness – one or two continuous campaigns, for
the most part – of the periods of large-scale conflict. The significance of
the war that in the 1550s finally broke the bounds of this characteristic
stop-start rhythm of European warfare is central to our understanding of
both the particular crisis of the mid-century and later military develop-
ments – above all, the shift towards a privatization of war.
There is no reason to think that either Charles V and Philip II or Henri
II of France consciously planned to extend the war of the 1550s beyond
any previous period of large-scale continuous conflict. Both parties had
been anxious to secure the Peace of Vaucelles in early 1556 before another
year of campaigning had to be funded from their already dangerously
overextended credit networks. But the failure to bring the various inter-
locking conflicts of the 1550s to an end had the potential to change the
terms of warfare. A readiness to keep on fighting could be adopted as a
deliberate act of military policy. Much more than technological or tactical
developments, it is arguable that the lengthening of periods of continuous
warfare – a process which started in the 1550s, progressed through the
later sixteenth century and culminated in the Thirty Years War – was the
key early modern ‘revolution in military affairs’, the single transformative
factor which had a major impact on the entire conduct of warfare.
For it was now clear that one way of achieving direct strategic and
military advantage became simply to wage war over multiple, continuous
campaigns to the point of exhausting an enemy whose resources were
smaller or less well organized. The bankruptcy of an enemy state, or the
desertion of its unpaid and unfed soldiers and sailors, was as effective a
way of forcing that state to terms as winning battles or conquering cities.
The ‘revolution in military affairs’ was essentially about the rise of
Towards military enterprise 77
fitting out the squadron and ensuring that it was ready for service.40
Political success and failure in controlling the Italian peninsula during
the struggles of the 1520s in fact hinged on one such contract, that with
the private galley squadron of the Genoese patrician and entrepreneur,
82 The expansion of military enterprise, 1560–1620
A merchant ship would carry considerably fewer guns, but it could easily
be adapted to carry more if intended to serve, permanently or for a single
campaign, as a warship.48
It was thus possible for a ship’s master, using a ship constructed on a
single template, to pursue activity as an ocean-going merchant, a privateer
at own risk, or a contracted naval warship; only the temporary balance of
artillery to cargo, crew numbers and the provisioning of the ship would
vary. Ships operating out of the Adriatic free port of Ragusa (Dubrovnik)
exemplify this development. With a long tradition of large-scale mercan-
tile activity based on a concentration of skilled sailors in the city, com-
bined with an equally robust piratical and privateering background, the
Ragusans were well placed to sell their services as additional naval ships to
the Spanish crown.49 The numbers of Ragusan ships in Spanish service
have been exaggerated in some accounts, but contracts with Ragusan
shipowners were one of the key components in a sixteenth-century
Spanish naval policy which drew the largest part of its capability from
armed merchant ships contracted into service.50 At least three ships were
contracted to serve in the 1588 Spanish Armada, including one of the
largest ships in the fleet, the San Niccolo, of 834 tonnes, armed with
26 guns and carrying 68 sailors and 226 soldiers.51 The Armada itself
made explicit the central role of the armed merchantman in early modern
Hiring naval capacity 85
interested in buying private naval capacity ‘off the shelf’, and Elias Trip’s
shipping company alone also dealt with the Portuguese government dur-
ing the twelve-year truce, and then with Cardinal Richelieu of France who
wanted to negotiate a contract for six fully crewed Dutch ships to be
brought into French service in the 1620s.56 The Trips’ position as the
leading armaments family in seventeenth-century Europe was cemented
by their links to the De Geer family.57 The latter’s activities as arms
dealers had been closely linked to Sweden from the 1620s, above all as
developers of copper and iron works, and the manufacture of cannon.
Their ties to the Trip family expanded the range of their armaments
activities to include the contracting of warships. In 1644 in the midst of
the Thirty Years War, the Swedish field marshal Lennart Torstensson
decided on a pre-emptive strike against an apparently resurgent Denmark.
Torstensson and his troops would look after the land war, but Jacob de
Geer was approached to raise a fleet of thirty-two fully crewed and armed
Dutch ships, mostly converted merchantmen, which would supplement
Sweden’s navy and ensure an overwhelming naval superiority for the
period of the lightning campaign.58 The total cost of hiring these ships
for the forthcoming campaign was calculated by de Geer in December
1644 at 460,550 talers.59
These naval examples provide evidence that members of the military
and political elites had been prepared to involve themselves as creditors in
contracting to meet some of the military needs of the crown. Similar
initiatives can be seen in the upkeep of frontier and other strategically
important garrisons, where again military commanders or entrepreneurs
had been prepared to contract with the government for the payment and
maintenance of troops.60 The critical factor in all these developments had
been the perception that they were areas of longer-term military activity
and demand, where advancing credit brought a lower risk of default, or
other political or social benefits from longer-term involvement in the
military system could become a significant, compensatory inducement.
But this of itself would not necessarily have led to a widespread shift in
existing military organization on land to one also based on devolved power
and private credit. More was needed to tip a political and military balance
towards private enterprise, a balance which at a rhetorical level was still
influenced by hostility to the use of mercenaries, added to which at a
practical level there was no reason to assume that the move to longer wars
was a permanent feature of European military development. In the event,
this transformation from hired mercenaries to military enterprise was
driven by a number of evolutionary initiatives, development of which
was largely a result of contingency: the character of a series of major
European wars in the later sixteenth century. Yet the cumulative effect
The French Wars of Religion 87
from amongst the Walloon population and the lands just across the
borders – the German principalities and the bishopric of Liège.78
Though these troops could be raised under what looked like ‘typical’
Landsknecht contracts – cash advances payable by the warlord for a con-
tract that was assumed to last only for a short period of service – it soon
became clear that these were no longer short-term, single-campaign
agreements. The German examples here are telling. Some 25,000
German infantry were recruited under contract to serve in the crisis of
1572, and the great majority of these regiments remained in service with-
out interruption until the general demobilization of 1576/7. Most of those
officially dismissed were contracted back into service in the next few years,
and some much sooner: Jakob Hannibal von Hohenems had seen the
original 1574 contract for his infantry regiment abrogated in the crisis of
1576, yet renewed again as early as December 1577.79 In 1580 the
governor of the Netherlands, Alexander Farnese, duke of Parma, pro-
ceeded to disband a number of German regiments which, despite the
hiatus following the sack of Antwerp, were considered to have been in
continual service for the eight years since 1572.80 What is clear as the
struggle continued was that contracts were being either explicitly drawn
up, or implicitly understood, as open-ended agreements, in which the
regiments would continue in service for as long as they could remain
militarily effective, or until the crown finally reached a political settlement
with its enemies. In this case the settlement was the Twelve Years’ Truce
of 1609, though even this by no means led to total demobilization of the
army.
German regimental contractors who now recognized that they were
raising troops for longer periods of paid service were prepared to absorb
some of the costs of recruiting, equipping and moving troops to the
Netherlands. Hohenems, who had contracted in 1574 to raise a regiment
of 4,500 infantry in Tyrol and Upper Germany, had spent 46,844 florins
on the costs of recruitment by November 1574, money raised via family
funds and his own credit.81 His own subsequent stipend of 400 florins
per month was sufficiently high to indicate his position as a creditor of his
warlord, the king of Spain. In comparison the maestre de campo (colonel) of
a royal tercio received 40 escudos (approximately 60 florins) per month,
together with a further 40 from the captaincy of the leading company.82 It
was equally clear that Count Florens von Berlaymont had committed his
own funds to the recruitment of his regiment of eleven companies of
German infantry, and that he and his captains had continued to meet
some of the costs of the wages of these troops throughout the period of
military service. The total sum owed to Berlaymont in 1580 when the
regiment was disbanded was 717,329 florins, while we know that one of
The Army of Flanders and the Dutch revolt 91
his captains, Ruprecht von Eggenberg, had a share in this overall debt
acknowledged at 23,715 florins.83 A similar process is notable for the Irish
troops serving in Flanders, where captains raised troops in Ireland at their
own expense and regarded their companies, once in service in the army, as
an investment that would provide for their subsequent livelihood.84
Seen at face value, financial commitments at this level by the colonels-
proprietor seem extraordinarily ill-judged. The Spanish crown was both
reluctant, and in many cases unable, to pay its debts to military contrac-
tors in full, and in the case of Berlaymont’s regiment the immediate pay-
off in 1580, albeit accompanied by promises of further instalments in
future, was a mere 55,000 florins in cash.85 Yet not merely did the
colonels apparently tolerate these funding shortfalls, remaining in service
despite apparently mounting arrears, but like the Genoese owners of the
galley squadrons, they seem to have been positively enthusiastic to draw
up new contracts with the crown. In December 1577, Hohenems accep-
ted a contract to raise another infantry regiment, this time of twenty
companies, to be recruited in the Tyrol and also to be armed and equip-
ped at his own expense.86
As with the management of the galley squadrons, it is necessary to keep
the bigger picture in mind when looking at the attraction of these con-
tracts. The major factor in the Netherlands is the development of what was
to become the key fiscal feature of the Thirty Years War, the contributions
system. From 1574 the military administration in the Low Countries
bypassed the existing regular tax system in the majority of provinces,
and allocated a fixed monthly sum to each community within the prov-
inces to pay directly for the upkeep of the troops garrisoned or stationed in
the area. The contributions were administered by special commissioners,
but the money was paid directly to the regiments, and the system was
gradually refined over the next decade. In 1591 it became possible to
adopt a variation that would become familiar enough throughout the
seventeenth century: provincial authorities in Flanders and Brabant
proved willing to agree a lump sum which they would collect themselves
on behalf of the troops, rather than submitting to the exactions of com-
missioners with their explicit threat of military enforcement.87
As the war settled into its character as one of territorial occupation and
garrisoning, the officers of the contracted regiments were able to claim
these local contributions on behalf of their units. Much of this payment
would be in kind, and food and quartering would be distributed to the
troops in lieu of pay, ensuring that immediate concerns about breakdown
or mutiny could be contained. Later official calculations take the provi-
sion of food and quartering for the soldiers as the equivalent of at least 50
per cent of their wages. Officers were given the opportunity to meet part of
92 The expansion of military enterprise, 1560–1620
the needs of their soldiers from a local tax which was not to be offset
against their final receipt of monies intended to pay their soldiers in
full.88 The contributions were in effect a form of interest against the initial
capital invested by the colonel, and the running costs of the regiment and
its companies forced upon him and his captains by the delays and short-
falls in payment from the central treasury. The military contractors by the
later sixteenth century had achieved a sufficiently strong position with
major sources of credit that these would not merely make loans to the
enterprisers themselves, but guarantee loans that the enterprisers had
negotiated with third parties to provide supplies or provisions.89
Typically in 1575 the banking house of Fugger agreed to guarantee a
payment of 4,000 florins which Colonel Hohenems owed on account for
the purchase of weapons and armour for his unit.90
This in turn linked the enterprisers into a world in which ultimate
access to financial resources was more than a simple question of what
the crown’s administrators might or might not pay of monies outstanding
at a particular moment. Ruprecht von Eggenberg, a captain in Florens von
Berlaymont’s regiment, was owed an outstanding sum of 23,000 florins in
1580, and in that year received a modest instalment of 5,500 florins
towards this from the Spanish crown. Yet instead of being ruined by the
tardy repayment, he managed to sell the remainder of the acknowledged
debt to the House of Fugger for the discounted price of 15,000 florins.91
Eggenberg went on to become an enterpriser-colonel in his own right, in
May 1587 receiving a patent from the Duke of Parma to recruit and
command a new regiment of twelve companies of German infantry.92
Such individual experiences may simply be exceptions to the general
experience of the military enterprisers, but it seems more likely that, in
the same way that the advantages of running a galley squadron need to be
seen in a broader financial context, the ability to collect local contribu-
tions as a form of ‘bottom line’ guarantee of subsistence, and the more
complex financial arrangements brought into play by longer-running
contracts, may have transformed the financial realities of this activity.
Without taking such factors into account the behaviour of German colo-
nels is, by any historical standards, incomprehensible. In other cases of
local Spanish commanders it led to accusations of substantial private
profiteering: Colonel Francesco Verdugo, appointed governor of
Friesland, produced an account of the campaigns of the early 1590s
which is an indignant denial of the accusation that he was siphoning off
for his personal gain 40,000–50,000 talers per month from the province’s
contributions.93 Verdugo is at pains to point out that the exaction of local
contributions represented the one means of maintaining the remaining
troops in Friesland, otherwise completely ignored by the central financing
The ‘Long Turkish War’, 1593–1606 93
machinery, and that far from profiteering from these, they were the one
factor keeping the troops operational.94
All of this was further transformed in the early seventeenth century by
the transfer of the Army of Flanders into the Genoese financial system. In
1603, the archducal government gave control of the army to the Genoese
noble and financier Ambrogio Spinola; Spinola possessed no previous
military experience but had organizational ability and massive personal
credit through his family banking connections.95 He controlled the com-
mand, pay and supply of the entire Army of Flanders, including those
Walloon and German colonels who were automatically thereby his sub-
contractors, as well as the tercios, for whose pay and supplies he was now
directly responsible.96
Spinola’s own financial resources and networks gave him the opportu-
nity, not seen again until Albrecht Wallenstein, to run a large army on the
basis of government receipts, but mediated through his own access to
credit: henceforth the payment of the army, the establishment of provi-
sioning and munitions contracts, the running costs of campaigns, could
draw upon his own and his family’s credit rather than that of the Spanish
crown.97 This certainly meant that he was able to defuse crises by borrow-
ing on his own credit to meet military costs; but in return, he either
assumed direct control of the collection of local revenues through the
army, or ensured the assignation of customs and other revenues to his
creditors. The system did not prevent the Spanish crown declaring a
further bankruptcy in 1607, which blocked the external funds required
for any attempt to take the offensive against the United Provinces. But the
ability to tie the funding of the army into the Genoese financial system by
means other than the loans contracted to the Spanish crown did create a
new element in the financial management of the army in the Netherlands,
which had not been achieved in an earlier period of direct state
administration.
borderlands could not even support the ordinary garrisons from local
revenues. Fighting a major war in this theatre required that the vast bulk
of military expenditure be assigned against incoming subsidy and external
tax revenue. Systems by which subsidies collected in Spain, Portugal, the
Papal Lands and elsewhere were realized as cash payments in Hungary
involved tiers of international financiers and bankers operating largely
outside the direct control of the Habsburg administration but in conjunc-
tion with the commanders in the field. Above all, thanks to a forthright
interpretation of the terms of the 1570 Speyer Reichsabschied which stipu-
lated that the Imperial German territories in case of war were to provide
quarters and subsistence for an army engaged in common defence, the
Long Turkish War saw the imposition of agreed military contributions
across the Empire.99
Imperial taxes and international subsidies on this scale transformed the
management of the war. The Hungarian conflict was not just the ‘military
school’ of Europe – though it could claim that title more readily than could
the Netherlands in the first years of the seventeenth century; it was also the
‘military market’ of Europe. A cosmopolitan army, made up of regiments
from almost every nation, including many Protestants, was drawn in by
the opportunism or ambitions of existing or potential unit commanders.
The practical problem for military organization was straightforward: very
little of this money was raised in or near the Hungarian campaign theatre,
and not much of it could be matched to precise areas or locations where
troops were being enlisted. Raising troops for the Army of Flanders had
already demonstrated to German would-be colonels that a willingness to
deploy some of their own credit in raising troops many hundreds of miles
away from the Flanders’ military treasury would expedite, or in many
cases simply make possible, a recruitment process. This was even more
evident when raising regiments for service in Hungary.100
But no less important was the working assumption that these regiments
were, like their Flanders counterparts, being raised not for a single cam-
paign but on a more open-ended contract. Within the unit, this allowed an
early version of the business of the regiment/company to develop. From
their own funds or credit, colonels or captains provided weapons, cloth-
ing, food and munitions to take the troops to the campaign theatre, and
might continue to issue these on campaign.101 All of these would be
provided against regular deductions from the soldiers’ wages when these
were paid to the unit commanders from the contributions and subsidies
sent to the army. Credit advanced in this way became a large-scale
financial element in the funding of the armies, and the commanding
officers were increasingly expected to fall in with this new pattern of
funding on credit. A period in which large numbers of the Landsknechte
An alternative to military enterprise? 95
had been under-equipped, lacking armour and full weapons, had ended
by the second half of the century.102
Another distinctive factor in the conflict was that the agrarian and
population base of Hungary, and even the immediately adjoining lands,
was wholly inadequate to support the provisioning needs of Habsburg and
allied field armies whose numbers had climbed to around 30,000 in the
later 1590s.103 From the outset it proved impossible to sustain operations
using solely the local economy. Initially this meant the negotiation of
contracts with suppliers in Bohemia and Upper Germany, but competi-
tion for grain surpluses from these regions was already stiff and the burden
of sustaining armies in Hungary overwhelmed their capacity to provide
sufficient foodstuffs.104 Food had to be acquired and shipped from much
further afield, as did munitions and additional arms and equipment. The
food and munitions supply of the military operations was handled under
contract by a wide range of contractors from Genoa to Amsterdam.105 This
system could successfully mobilize the credit of a mass of unit officers,
suppliers and munitions contractors who were all confident that the war
would continue long enough to see the repayment of their financial com-
mitments. A figure like Maximilian von Liechtenstein invested not merely
as proprietor of a cavalry regiment but in acquiring and managing artillery
on behalf of the Habsburg war effort.106
the brink of fragmentation by the 1580s. In other states rulers were aware
that they were making a choice, and no less aware of why they were doing
so. In at least one case where the government’s discussion of the merits of
state control versus military contracting was explicit, Habsburg Spain,
Philip III could go on record to his Council of State in 1607 that ‘no one
would be more eager than I to dispense with [military] contracts if that
were possible’.107 Clearly neither the king nor his councillors considered
that this was a possibility.
One plausible-sounding solution to reducing the costs of recruiting and
maintaining armies was the creation of local and national militias of
conscripted soldiers. This had been warmly espoused by theorists since
at least the fifteenth century, and very explicitly as a classicizing counter-
point to a reliance on mercenaries. The rhetoric was typically humanist:
Machiavelli’s critique of the unreliable, self-interested and venal merce-
nary was followed by the equally formulaic espousal of the virtues of a
citizen militia, as a means both to inculcate civic virtù into populations and
to produce effective combat troops, whose fierceness and resilience would
reflect their commitment to the defence of patria and identification with a
glorious common cause.108 Though Machiavelli’s own experiment with
the raising of a militia for the Florentine Republic, the conscription of the
reluctant contadini of the Tuscan countryside, had come to an inglorious
end in 1512 with the rout of his hastily assembled militia by Spanish
regulars, followed by the sack of Prato and the Spanish restoration of the
Medici in Florence, such projects merely went into abeyance.
By the later sixteenth century, under the rigorous and persuasive
spokesmanship of Justus Lipsius and numerous contemporaries, the proj-
ect for creating citizen – or subject – militias gathered new momentum.
Lipsius’ Politics had run through more than eighty editions and trans-
lations by 1650; his writings had a large impact on an international
political and administrative elite.109 The traditional, negative assessment
of the military qualities and reliability of mercenaries was supplemented
by a shrill note of complaint against the contemporary version of the
phenomenon. The extravagant, self-constructed identity of the sixteenth-
century mercenary, or of professional soldiers like those in the Spanish
tercios, was seen more and more as standing in provocative opposition to
the moral and social norms of wider society, itself the target of broader
attempts to enforce tighter social and religious discipline on the masses.
The individualism and self-assertiveness of the Landsknecht, Swiss, even
Spanish or Italian soldiers was measured in clothing, behaviour and
their double-edged position in relation to society – both claiming status
and self-consciously standing outside its norms.110 In a moral and
confessional climate that was increasingly intolerant of any kind of
An alternative to military enterprise? 97
option, even when demand meant that the best mercenary troops had
already been acquired by other warlords.116 In the eyes of both the militia
theorists and some military practitioners, this situation might be transformed
by subjecting conscripted troops to rigorous, externally imposed training
and drill, until they could master tactical and weapons manoeuvres with
such precision that they could rival any traditional, cohesive and organically
developed unit. Though Lipsius was an eloquent spokesman for the whole-
sale adoption of citizen militias by European princes, in fact his central
contribution to a debate about military organization and society was a set
of precepts about order, obedience and discipline. His neostoic doctrine of
‘true discipline’ imposed his moral and philosophical concerns upon military
life; his recipe for a disciplined and effective army was to demand ‘a severe
conforming of the souldier to value and virtue’.117 It was with the ‘exercises’,
or drill, of his military disciples like Maurice of Nassau, Stadholder or
military commander of the Dutch armies, and of Johann, prince of
Nassau-Dillemberg, that this discipline assumed a more concrete form.
The Nassau reformers took the Lipsian precepts of restraint and self-
discipline, and connected them to a specific set of classical tactical and
organizational prescriptions, based on the legionary drills demonstrated in
Aelian and Vegetius. As was claimed at the time by Maurice of Nassau, and
has been echoed ever since, not least by those historians who identify a
military revolution in this period, it was this new discipline and drill which
made possible a transformation of armies and of the seventeenth-century
battlefield.118 More prosaically, it was argued that the new system of collec-
tive, regularized drill, by the repeated practice of precise routines for using
weapons and deploying units, could match that slow accumulation of col-
lective identity and martial values within the traditional elite military unit.119
Regardless of whether they were to be applied to citizen militias com-
posed of part-time ‘souldiers of ayde’ or to conscript troops like the
Swedish levies, these systems of externally imposed drill promised to
turn inexperienced troops with little corporate identity or military tradi-
tion into disciplined, professional soldiers, responsive to the commands
and direction of their NCOs and officers.120 As an apparently quick and
cheap means to raise forces that would be militarily effective, it had great
appeal, and its dissemination came at a critical moment. Late sixteenth-
century rulers throughout the Holy Roman Empire and beyond its fron-
tiers noted with concern the destabilizing political effects of confessional
tensions; an established territorial defence seemed an essential safeguard
against this more threatening environment.121 Thus in a spasm of admin-
istrative activity, militias were introduced in a short period across a
remarkable number of states, the administrations of which set about
establishing liability of subjects for military service, selecting suitable
An alternative to military enterprise? 99
complained that the militia, assembled in 1605 to face the threat of invasion
by Stefan Bocskai, were no better than disorderly peasants.131 The German
states that deployed their territorial militias, mostly in last-ditch defence
against invading armies such as the German Catholic Liga in the 1620s or
the Swedes in 1631–2, saw these forces systematically, and usually brutally,
annihilated by the invaders.132 If there were some serious possibility of
producing group cohesion and collective identity through the rigorous
inculcation of drill, it would require more than a few initiatives with reluc-
tant, part-time militiamen. Speaking admittedly of the later seventeenth
century, when the ‘science of drill’ had reached altogether new heights of
rigour and relentless day-on-day practice, Jacques-Louis Bolé, marquis de
Chamlay, commented that whereas it was possible to have good cavalry
troopers within a year of their enlistment, it took a minimum of five to
six years to produce infantry who grasped the rudiments of disciplined fire
and cohesiveness.133 Not surprisingly the militia experiments of the later
sixteenth century fell dramatically short of such a demanding preparation.134
Theories of drill and related ideas of tactical and organizational rede-
ployment were not irrelevant to military success in the seventeenth cen-
tury, though it is necessary to maintain a sense of proportion about just
how important they were, even when, as was the case with Gustavus
Adolphus, they were applied to military professionals in a well-conceived
tactical system. But it was simple delusion to believe that they could
transform a part-time, reluctantly recruited militia, and could offer mili-
tary effectiveness on a par with motivated, long-serving troops raised
under contract. The crushing defeats and collapse of the German militias
at the beginning of the Thirty Years War, and the incorporation of most of
the willing soldiers from the Catholic Landesdefension units into the
contractor-forces later in the war, put paid to this as a serious and viable
solution to the problem of raising troops.135
In the context of the early seventeenth century, this left little option for
states seeking to raise military force: a state-recruited, permanent army
was a financial and organizational impossibility, and the apparent panacea
of conscripted militias drilled up supposedly to professional standards had
been an embarrassing and tragic failure. To adapt slightly the final sen-
tence of Michael Roberts’ essay on the ‘Military Revolution’: the way lay
open, wide and straight, to the triumph of military contracting. The next
great war would see its fullest and most extensive evolution.
3 Diversity and adaptation: military enterprise
during the Thirty Years War
The previous chapter illustrated how the shift by European states towards
reliance on mechanisms of military enterprise was an evolutionary pro-
cess, shaped by a variety of pressures and problem-solving needs from
the early sixteenth century onwards. Whether military enterprise would
subsequently have expanded and flourished so extensively without the
particular factor of the Thirty Years War is a matter for speculation; hard-
pressed governments had certainly discovered before 1619 that the
contracting-out of military functions and the mobilizing of subjects’
resources which it permitted offered a practical solution to some of the
constraints on mobilizing military force. Yet the Thirty Years War,
through its unprecedented length, geographical scale and number of
belligerents, offered a vital forcing-house for the development of military
enterprise. At one level this has been noted by historians: the war is
strongly identified with the hiring and use of mercenaries, whose self-
serving and strategically sterile military activities are considered in part
responsible for the brutality, destructiveness and length of the struggle.
The career of the Imperial Generalissimo Albrecht Wallenstein, the great-
est of all condottiere, whose absolute authority over an army of more than
100,000 men raised and maintained through his own networks and
resources, is offered as the epitome of an age of military enterprise.
Whether seen as an extraordinary project launched by an organizer and
administrator of precocious talent, or the last gasp of a system of warfare
dominated by over-powerful and unreliable aristocratic power-broking,
Wallenstein’s army is placed at the apex of a process by which a long-
running form of military enterprise finally reaches its high-water mark in
the context of Imperial politics in the 1620s. After Wallenstein the military
world changes: fighting wars through private enterprise is everywhere
acknowledged as dangerous and unviable, even if many states were unable
to act upon that recognition until after the end of the Thirty Years War.
The present chapter seeks to take issue with this interpretation on two
levels. The Thirty Years War made military demands upon the belliger-
ents that were met through a range of different forms of military
101
102 Military enterprise during the Thirty Years War
K. OF SWEDEN
BALTIC SEA
K. O F
NORTH DENMA RK
SEA
Danzig
Hamburg
Elb Stettin O F
K .
e
Bremen L A N D
K. OF Berlin P O
Od
ENGLAND Osnabrück Braunschweig
er
Poznan
Amsterdam
Jüterbog
Magdeburg
Münster
Rh
Halle Kottbus
ine
Y
Nuremberg Brünn
Brunn
Verdun Metz Ansbach
R
Paris
Eichstätt MORAVIA
ine
A
Regensburg
Rh
Stuttgart Danube
G
Offenburg
N
K . Ulm Munich Vienna
O F
U
Salzburg
Montbeliard
H
F R A Ravensburg Buda
N C E Constance Ofen
L
Berne Graz
A
SWISS
I
CONFEDERATION
R
D.
O
E
F K. O
OFF
SA
P
Lyons R E Trieste
VO HU NG A RY
HUNGA
M
Y Milan P.
I
Turin O Venice
F
V
õne
Rhon
E
N
I
C DA
E LM
AT
IA
Burgundian Circle Franconian Circle Swabian Circle Lower Rhine Westphalian Circle Lower Saxon Circle
more closely with French military policies and armies, caused tensions
and resentments that were unresolved at Saxe-Weimar’s death in 1639.18
Saxe-Weimar recognized that the subsidy treaty with France, however
inadequately maintained, offered some stability and the possibility of
maintaining lines of credit, even if it narrowed his overall freedom of
military action.19 Many of his colonels remained unconvinced, unhappy
to have abandoned close cooperation with the Swedes and dissatisfied
with a zone of military operations so far to the west of the Empire, where
subsistence from a ravaged countryside was difficult. But Saxe-Weimar’s
army itself had evolved a great deal since Mansfeld’s time; it was smaller,
and better adapted to the fast-moving war of surprise, manoeuvre and
rapidly seized opportunities which was typical of Saxe-Weimar’s opera-
tional style. Even when his army was reduced to 11,000–12,000, the
troops were of high quality, serving in regiments that had already been
some of the best in the Swedish army back in 1634.20 Speed and compact-
ness greatly assisted occasions when the army had to rely on foraging and
local requisitioning of supplies, and in general facilitated the logistical
underpinning of Saxe-Weimar’s operations. The army was a flagship of
the new face of military enterprise as it was evolving through the 1630s
and 1640s.
Many of Saxe-Weimar’s shareholder-colonels were dissatisfied with the
French alliance and the cooperation with French forces in the Rhineland
that this required, and after his death in 1639 the colonels who inherited
the army and became its directors were well aware of their bargaining
power.21 Though the French government saw the death of Saxe-Weimar
as a timely opportunity to place the leaderless army under a French
commander and more directly within French service, the four colonel-
directors who became the spokesmen for the army’s own interests thought
differently. A number were now of the opinion that they should return to
Swedish service, and were able to use this as a lever in hard bargaining
with the French authorities and the acting French commander, Jean-
Baptiste Budes, comte de Guébriant. A deal was finally hammered out
between October 1639 and August 1640, by which the army agreed to stay
in French service on terms which respected their proprietary status and
virtual independence.22 The agreement held together, despite consider-
able tensions in the early 1640s, largely through the tactful and respectful
generalship of Guébriant and then Turenne, and was only finally broken
in 1647 when Cardinal Mazarin misguidedly ordered that the army of
Germany, largely made up of these regiments or their successors, should
move into Flanders in support of the French war effort against the
Spanish. The subsequent mutiny saw the departure of all but three of
the regiments into Swedish service for what remained of the war.23
110 Military enterprise during the Thirty Years War
deployed to raise his army. Able to borrow 430,000 talers on the Kiel
money market at a comfortable interest rate of 5 per cent, and not
anticipating problems with obtaining further loans against tolls and rev-
enues, Christian saw no reason to deal with mercenary colonels on any-
thing other than the traditional basis of the payment of full advances, with
the corresponding subordination of the mercenaries to the king and his
military commanders.28 In addition the administrators acting directly in
the name of the king took on a significantly larger share of the supply
arrangements, whether this was to meet demands – via the sea – when the
troops were on the Jutland peninsula, or to try to ensure that they were
adequately supplied in Germany. In the summer of 1626 the royal com-
missioner for war, Aksel Arenfeld, was making extensive contracts to
obtain supplies from merchants in Hamburg and Bremen who would
ship them along the Elbe to supply the king’s army.29 The decisive military
failure of Christian’s German expedition can conceal the equally dismal
impact on the royal finances, brought to the point of breakdown from
where, grudgingly and temporarily, they were salvaged by the tax grants of
the Estates.30 The belief that large-scale war could be sustained by tradi-
tional hired mercenaries and supported exclusively from royal revenues
and loans was as impractical for Denmark in the 1620s as it had been for
France and Spain in the 1550s. Had Christian managed to establish a
permanent military presence in Germany, some form of military enter-
prise might have evolved in negotiations with German colonels. His fail-
ure to move in this direction earlier in the campaign was a lesson learnt by
Gustavus Adolphus four years later. It was only with the attack on
Denmark by Swedish forces in 1643–4 that Christian’s policy towards
mercenaries started to change. Simply because of the crown’s lack of
financial resources, some effort was now made to recruit military enter-
prisers, prepared to absorb the initial costs of recruitment and opera-
tions.31 This trend towards military enterprisers, principally drawn from
the German market, was even more evident as Denmark prepared for war
with Sweden in 1657–8.32
use of the credit of the colonels they hired, they saw clear political advan-
tages in keeping them dependent on the provinces as paymasters.38
territories 400 florins per month.50 Most of this was intended to assist
with the recruitment and reconstruction of the regiments, but doubtless
allowed the colonels some element of reimbursement for previous
expenditure.
This financial structure based on moderate but regular pay was subject
to slippage, above all as the Bavarian and other Liga territories suffered the
blows of invasion, devastation and occupation by the Swedes in 1631–4
and again later in the war. But the major army reforms following on the
Peace of Prague (1635), which abolished the Catholic Liga army but
permitted the Bavarians to retain an independent army under the overall
authority of the Emperor, reiterated the principles of restricted investment
and a strong administrative-supervisory presence with the army.51 The
advantages of this may have been less apparent in the campaigns of the late
1620s and early 1630s when the armies of Wallenstein, the combined
forces of Christian of Denmark and the armies of Gustavus Adolphus
were briefly pushing totals of troops under arms into the hundreds of
thousands, but in the longer run the Liga/Bavarian model of a small and
high-quality army was to prove the optimal solution to the challenges of
waging the Thirty Years War, with its logistical constraints and the need to
promote sustainability of financial commitments both at the level of
exactions from territory and populations and from the military enter-
prisers themselves.52
Over the period 1635 to 1648 by far the largest proportion of the
financing of the army came from agreed military contributions levied by
local authorities on the Bavarian and Swabian Circles.53 This was not a
system that depended on conquest, occupation and near-confiscatory
contribution demands to meet its own military costs. Between 1635 and
1648 the contributions and other local taxes levied across the two Kreise
amounted to 11.7 million florins, a huge amount by the standards of pre-
war taxation, but spread out across relatively prosperous territories and
imposed over fifteen years, it was a sustainable burden.54 State-sanctioned
financial support, coupled with an administrative presence within the
armies, permitted the maintenance of the Bavarian system of ‘restricted
enterprise’, encouraging the colonels to invest in their units, but at a
sustainable level compared with the central sources of funding.55 This
had a particularly significant consequence in maintaining the long-term
existence of a significant number of Bavarian regiments.56 While the
Bavarian army was not unique in its capacity to maintain a strong core
of experienced career soldiers under arms, it was certainly one of the most
successful of the armies of the Thirty Years War in this respect (see below,
pp. 171–2). Contemporaries largely agreed that the numbers and quality
116 Military enterprise during the Thirty Years War
Swabia, and the heavy, and to a large extent arbitrary, burdens of the
Imperial contributions was summed up by the Abbess Katharina von
Spaur, when in June 1628 she wished heartily for Tilly’s Liga army to
move back into Swabia in order to drive out ‘Wallenstein’s grasping
rabble’.79
The only way in which the long-term sustainability of Wallenstein’s
army could have been secured would have been – as the generalissimo
himself recognized – through a wholesale reshaping of the political map
of Germany. Just as the reconquest of Bohemia had created vast oppor-
tunities in an atmosphere of feverish financial speculation, so a settlement
in the Empire which carried through substantial territorial confiscations
and adjustments, and permanently alienated resources into the hands of
officer-proprietors, might offer a solution. Wallenstein set himself on the
road to such a territorial reconstruction with his Imperial investiture as
duke of Mecklenburg in 1628. This was halted by the disintegration of his
political position in 1629 and the political and military crisis of 1630
which led to Wallenstein’s dismissal.
The dismissal brought down the entire edifice of Imperial war finance,
crippling the contributions system and freezing access to further credit.
The impact was felt directly by the Imperial colonels and other proprie-
tors. From having been better funded and possessing better-maintained
troops than any other force in the Empire, supplies of food and munitions
dried up, wages could no longer be paid and the officers’ burden of
unsecured debt hamstrung their ability to meet further financial demands
for the support of their troops, who grew increasingly mutinous and
insubordinate.80 The operational efficiency of the Imperial army col-
lapsed; troops billeted in Pomerania and Mecklenburg surrendered
towns and fortresses without resistance to the Swedish army in early
1631.81 Against the odds, Gustavus Adolphus was able to sustain his
position on the Baltic, recruit substantial numbers of German units on
his own account, and conduct a campaign which strengthened his pres-
tige, brought his forces deep into central Germany and ultimately, in
September 1631, to Breitenfeld, just outside Leipzig, where he won his
greatest victory.
A major reason why Wallenstein could make good his promise to the
Emperor in October 1631, that he would be able in only three months to
reconstruct a still larger army than the one he had commanded in the
1620s, was the proprietary interests of the existing Imperial colonels.82
The period from Wallenstein’s dismissal through to Breitenfeld had been
ruinous for many of those colonels who had continued to serve in the joint
Imperial-Liga army. Wallenstein’s reputation for managerial and financial
skills could work its previous magic, but still more important was the
The Imperial armies from Wallenstein to Hatzfeld 121
the Imperial troops had been concentrated under the direct authority of
Wallenstein.91 After Prague, the Emperor was able both to require the
disbandment of all pre-existing leagues and other associations in the
Empire, including the Catholic Liga, and to draw the forces of
Brandenburg, Saxony, the Rhineland electorates and Bavaria into a direct
military alliance. But recognizing the impossibility of creating a genuinely
joint army, the Bavarian, Saxon and Brandenburg armies were permitted
to retain their own structures and organization, as ‘mediate’ forces under
the authority of the Emperor.92 Military victory followed by a German
peace on Habsburg terms was to have paradoxical consequences for
the maintenance of Imperial armies over the ensuing decade. The great
majority of Protestant rulers in the Empire had now submitted to Imperial
authority and had joined a general military alliance. Those rulers who
were now fielding their own ‘mediate’ armies could legitimately claim that
they were making their military contribution directly and that they and
neighbouring states within the central and north German Circles should
be exempted from additional pressures to sustain the troops of the primary
Imperial army. Even if there were not already good reasons for rethinking
Wallenstein’s approach to raising and funding an Imperial army, the
dramatic shrinkage of the areas over which Imperial troops could
now be billeted and contributions exacted would in any case have forced
the issue.93
The directly controlled Imperial forces were divided into two: the main
Imperial field army, largely sustained from regular contributions exacted
from the Habsburg lands and on the basis of Spanish and other subsidies
to the Emperor, and an army based in the Westphalian Circle, or that part
of it which was free of remaining Swedish garrisons.94 The Westphalian
Circle was to become the financial mainstay, after Bohemia and Silesia, of
the Imperial military system. It supported an army that was directly under
Imperial authority (unmediated), provided local protection within the
Circle against Swedish and Hessian incursions, but was also expected to
participate in wider military operations. Westphalian troops were used to
reinforce the main Imperial army time and again in the 1640s, whether
to make good the effects of defeats such as Breitenfeld II and Jankow, or to
provide additional troops for campaigns such as Gallas’ ill-fated advance
into Holstein in 1644. At the same time the basic lesson had been learnt
that the apparent availability of resources should not encourage military
inflation: the number of troops retained within the Circle remained
limited and multiple recruitment contracts were not drawn up on the
basis of the colonels’ credit, necessitating an ever-higher burden of con-
tributions to meet start-up costs and the maintenance of large numbers of
these new regiments. The army was kept relatively small – fewer than
124 Military enterprise during the Thirty Years War
talent, but it did make it more difficult for any of the Imperial lieutenant
generals to lay outright claim to supreme command. The new generation
of commanders anyway lacked willingness or ability to engage in
Wallenstein’s vast speculative enterprises, mobilizing military and finan-
cial resources that had seemed to give the army a high degree of inde-
pendence, but had actually proved an illusion. Long gone was the
situation in 1626 when Wallenstein’s father-in-law, Karl von Harrach,
could coolly inform the Emperor that His Majesty would only be able to
dictate the policy of Wallenstein’s army if he himself paid for its running
costs.99 By the 1640s, Imperial authorization to collect contributions, and
even the provision of direct funding from the Habsburgs’ own lands, was
the essential financial anchor of the armies. Wallenstein’s drive to domi-
nate and control a vast and expansionary military system was abandoned,
and command was divided; cooperation was still possible and desirable
on occasions, but the logic of sustaining troops and military operations
on a day-by-day basis dictated much smaller forces able to operate
independently.100
Hatzfeld worked within these constraints, as did his equally competent
successor from 1645, Peter Melander, Reichsgraf von Holzapfel. This
meant acting on military orders from the Imperial court which might be
misguided, partisan or based on an inadequate operational picture, and
accommodating at least some of those demands for military appointments
and exemptions from contributions and quartering based on courtly
petitions which Wallenstein had been so effective at refusing.101 Yet
their overall success in pursuing the war effort in a more sustained,
regulated and strategically coherent manner, thanks to more manageably
sized forces and known, if not always adequate, sources of funding, offers
a striking contrast with the earlier period. It is equally the case that the
regimental proprietors, now much closer to their Bavarian counterparts,
could still accumulate profits from the business of war and remained very
clearly shareholders in military enterprise, but with neither the huge
capital risks nor the short-term windfall profits of the Wallenstein epoch.
As with the Bavarian armies, it is striking that the Imperial forces in the
later 1630s and 1640s consisted of a smaller number of longer-serving
regiments, with similar effects of accumulating long-serving, experienced
officers and men.102
than 3,000.112 The largest proportion of the Swedes who were raised and
deployed were not in the campaign armies, but were garrisoned across
fortifications in the Baltic territories. Wallenstein had pioneered the prin-
ciple of exacting massive contributions, not just from enemy but from
allied and home territory, in order to reimburse colonels and other senior
officers who had engaged in substantial financial speculation; Gustavus
quickly adopted the same policy in recruiting his army from amongst
willing German enterprisers. Paul Khevenhüller, in religious exile from
his native Carinthia, joined Gustavus’ army as a cavalry colonel at the head
of a unit which he had recruited at his own expense, while in addition he
and his brother Hans also lent the king a further 70,000 talers at 6 per cent
interest per annum.113 After 1631 it seemed that enthusiasm to invest in
the Swedish king’s military activities was even greater than it had been for
Wallenstein.114
Underpinning this enthusiasm for massive capital investment in the
Swedish army, even after the death of Gustavus Adolphus, was the
Swedes’ ability to occupy great swathes of western and southern
Germany, mostly Catholic lands subjected to contributions in the form
of direct confiscations or war indemnities which were massive even by the
standards of Wallenstein’s system.115 As with Wallenstein, however, the
aim of imposing these extremely heavy burdens was not simply to provide
a one-off levy which could meet some of the outstanding debts of his
numerous subcontractors and investors; despite near-confiscatory exac-
tions, it was still conceived as means to a regular, substantial income flow.
This could finance a stream of new borrowing and financial investment,
one part of which was to pay for the expansion of an army that was
required to occupy the territories from which the burden of contributions
was to be extracted. After opening its gates to the Swedes in April 1632,
Augsburg was subjected to a regular and crushing burden of taxation and
requisitioning until the final collapse of Sweden’s position in the south in
early 1635. The Catholic bishop and the Fugger family alone were
assessed for an initial payment of 700,000 gulden, and as both had fled
the burden was laid upon the city, which received in return highly dubious
rights to the property of both parties. The inhabitants of the city were
assessed for contributions, both in cash and in kind, intended to support
the immediate costs of five regiments of Swedish troops, to indemnify
the officers for earlier costs, and to make a further payment to the overall
costs of the army.116 Resistance, backsliding and evasion were as much a
part of Augsburg’s relationship with the Swedish military as they had been
against the rather lower demands of Wallenstein’s army.117 Contributions
extracted at this level, even from a city as wealthy and well-placed as
Augsburg, proved unsustainable.118 The result can be seen in the rapid
The Swedish army 129
collapse of the population of the city under this pressure, from 80,000 in
1632 down to 18,000 in 1635.119
If the burden on what was perceived as a major hostile city was massive,
the contributions burden even on territories that were nominally allied
with the Swedes from 1631 represented a dramatic break with any pre-
vious taxation regime. The extraordinary Protokoll drawn up in late 1634
after the departure of the Swedes from the Ober-Barnim Circle of the
Margraviat of Brandenburg provides a striking picture of the detailed
contributions imposed over the preceding four years of Swedish occupa-
tion, and the costs of this in terms of depopulation, ruined villages and
destitute peasant communities. The modest community of Neustadt-
Eberswalde, with 216 hearths in 1630, claimed to have paid the total
sum of 43,987 talers over the four-year period, but at the cost of a
50 per cent fall in population and 106 houses abandoned.120
Thus, in the heady days of Gustavus’ victories it looked as though the
Swedes were plunging straight into the same trap of unsustainability on
the back of massive self-financed recruitment as the Imperialists under
Wallenstein had done. And even after Lützen and the king’s death, the
appetite for further and heavier investment by enterprisers within the
Swedish army seemed undimininished. In 1633 an unprecedented agree-
ment was made by which the Swedish enterpriser-colonels formally took
over the debts owed by the crown to the subalterns, non-commissioned
officers and men of their regiments. Added to their own advances and
other payments, this produced individual claims by some of the colonels
against the Swedish government of 200,000–300,000 talers.121 In the
same year and in the face of mounting protests and non-compliance by
the territories subjected to contributions, a series of negotiations took
place at Heilbronn between the Swedish government of Oxenstierna,
the army commanders and the states allied with the Swedes, to try to
establish a formal and agreed level of support.122 These Heilbronn nego-
tiations established that the Swedish campaign army, taken at a minimum
of 45,000 men, would require regular financial support of 8.5–9.5 million
florins per year.123 This simply could not be paid through further regular,
heavy war taxes on the back of the already unprecedented exactions on
occupied territory.
The proposed resolution to this impasse had similarities with
Wallenstein’s plans in the late 1620s, involving a massive transfer of
confiscated lands into the hands of the officers as a ‘once-and-for-all’
means to cover their debts and allow them to meet their own obligations
to junior officers and men.124 But not only did this raise serious constitu-
tional concerns about the extent of Sweden’s rights of conquest within the
Empire, it also created a mass of practical problems. Passed into the hands
130 Military enterprise during the Thirty Years War
of colonels who wanted to sell the property to realize capital to meet their
own debts, the market was rapidly flooded. Colonel Claus Dietrich
Sperreuth received as his payment for debts incurred the town of
Wembdingen, valued at 100,000 talers, and the monastic lands of
Kirchheim. He would have been prepared to sell them for cash for a
fraction of this value, but the one potential buyer, the count of
Hohenlohe, would only purchase these lands via long-term annual instal-
ments, rejected by Sperreuth.125
With the battle of Nördlingen in September 1634 the matter of the
colonels’ debts was settled more dramatically, with the complete collapse
of the Swedish position in southern and central Germany. The areas that
could support the Swedish army were reduced to the Baltic coastal terri-
tories of Pomerania and Mecklenburg. This was itself problematic, since
these were territories envisaged by the Swedes as part of a lasting territorial
satisfactio in a forthcoming peace settlement, and not therefore to be
ravaged by punitive contributions. Nördlingen and the ensuing Prague
settlement between the Emperor and the German princes forced Sweden
to carry through the same kind of radical reconstruction of army organ-
ization and support that the Imperial war council and the army
commanders undertook after the assassination of Wallenstein.126 In part
this task was simplified for the Swedes both by the heavy losses and
subsequent desertion of troops following Nördlingen, and by Bernhard
von Saxe-Weimar’s decision to lead off a substantial group of German
regiments as an independent corps, which from 1635 would receive a
subsidy from France and operate in the west of the Empire.
All of this reduced the Swedes from a vast military presence to a single
campaign army and the garrison forces on the Baltic coast. Virtually
overnight, the army had been transformed from a large, cantankerous
coalition of enterpriser-colonels to a relatively compact force, no longer
able to draw support from large-scale contributions except by a laborious
process of re-establishing a permanent military presence deeper in the
Empire. In the meantime it would be forced to subsist on a minimal
contributions base in Mecklenburg and Pomerania, on subsidies from
allied powers and on a willingness to put up with limited resources and to
rely on hand-to-mouth credit.127 As with the thinking behind the support
structure for the Imperial army in the aftermath of Prague, the key issue
now facing the Swedish high command was to establish a system that
could ensure military sustainability through balancing secure occupation
of territory and realistic contributions with providing enough additional
resources to support the operations of a campaign army – albeit one that
would be much more modest than hitherto. When the Swedish military
position improved from the late 1630s a larger area could be brought
The Swedish army 131
Conclusion
These examples of armies with a substantial component of private finan-
cial and organizational involvement by no means represent a comprehen-
sive list of enterprise-based armies in the Thirty Years War. Numerous
smaller Protestant forces subsisted largely through an element of private
enterprise. At least one, the army established by Wilhelm von Hessen-
Kassel, had a lengthy and successful history throughout the war, and
achieved something of the permanence and professionalism of the
Bavarian army, while never enjoying a comparable resource base.145
Another force made up of long-serving regimental proprietors, initially
raised as the army of a ruling prince and funded in part from his own ducal
resources, were the Lorraine troops of Duke Charles IV. The French
Conclusion 135
occupation of his duchy from the 1630s turned Charles into a general
contractor in the style of Mansfeld or Saxe-Weimar, except that his own
dynastic imperative of ultimately recovering his duchy constrained his
ability to negotiate contracts and pursue military activity with the potential
freedom of a Saxe-Weimar.146
This chapter has given little attention to the huge Spanish military
establishment of this period. This is in part because the lineaments of
the system were set out in the previous chapter: the Spanish crown
brought together a core of troops – the tercios viejos – which were directly
organized and funded by the state, surrounded by a much larger military
establishment made up of military contractors – whether these were
German colonels serving in the Netherlands, or Genoese nobles running
the Mediterranean galley squadrons. The demands of warfare for the
Spanish in the later sixteenth century had been uniquely intense and
large scale, and the development of the military system had already
taken on a settled form by the beginning of the Thirty Years War, one in
which a massive presence of military contracting played its role in keeping
the organizational and fiscal pressures of the military machine just in
check.147 There was no evolution comparable with that seen in the
Austrian Habsburg forces or the Swedish army, and the Spanish military
system occupies its own important niche in the spectrum of private–public
military partnerships as they evolved in this period. The French mon-
archy’s unique experience in establishing an initially highly problematic
public–private military partnership will be considered in more detail in
Chapter 6. Nor has the diversity of naval organization been fully exam-
ined. This is again partly because many of the developments in combining
state-owned and state-built warships with privately contracted elements of
navies, and in outsourcing aspects of naval activity to private contractors,
had already occurred during the sixteenth century, and there was less
distinctive evolution in the period of the Thirty Years War.
What this chapter has sought to show is that there was no single model
for the organization of military force in this period; still less was there any
inexorable process towards a state-run, state-controlled army. No state
had the resources or the organization to create a significant army directly
under its own funding and control, and the only issue was what level of
private enterprise would be encouraged or allowed. Equally though,
Mansfeld’s and a number of other armies raised by so-called general
contractors demonstrate that the independent contract army raised
entirely at the risk of the colonel-proprietors lacked even medium-term
durability during the Thirty Years War. What is evident from the given
examples is that different political and military pressures can lead to very
different emphases in the relationship between central authority – most
136 Military enterprise during the Thirty Years War
about the strength of his own troops, Pappenheim drew him off and
entered Magdeburg on 14 January 1632.4 Notoriously, of course,
Magdeburg had been sacked and virtually destroyed by the Imperial
army eight months previously; but it remained a prestigious and strategi-
cally important centre, and the military assumption was that such strong-
points should be held. Pappenheim simply incorporated the garrison into
his army, destroyed the artillery which he could not take with him, and
abandoned the city. Between February and October he conducted a
remarkable, extended campaign across enemy-held territory in Lower
Saxony and the borders of the Westphalian Circle, reliant on food and
provisions that he could organize through his own resources, and obtain
or seize locally. Plundering territory in a ruthless campaign of manoeuvre
and surprise, he wrong-footed Swedish and Hessian forces which totalled
almost four times his own 8,000 men, blocked a Swedish operation
against the major Westphalian city of Paderborn, in turn captured smaller
places such as Höxter and Einbeck, while defeating Swedish and Hessian
forces in detail. The campaign was a masterpiece of surprise, disinforma-
tion and rapid responses to evolving circumstances. While tying down
throughout the summer of 1632 substantial Swedish forces which might
otherwise have given Gustavus more flexibility in dealing with
Wallenstein, Pappenheim was able to use interior lines to defend
Westphalian territories against any Swedish counter-incursion.
Moreover in the midst of a campaign that covered hundreds of miles of
rapid troop movements and involved more than a dozen engagements
with enemy forces, he managed to ensure adequate food supplies for his
troops and even organized the purchase of new equipment and clothing
from merchants in Cologne, having them shipped to Paderborn for dis-
tribution.5 As a matter of operational priorities, Pappenheim had avoided
sieges of major places which might draw him into an unsought battle with
larger Swedish forces. However, he rounded off the campaign with the
remarkable capture of Hildesheim on 9 October, again by a combination
of bluff, surprise and intimidation. Most immediately important for
Pappenheim was the huge contribution of 200,000 talers imposed on
the city, a vital means to provide his officers with the wherewithal to pay
arrears of wages to their troops and reimburse themselves for their
expenses in the campaign. A few days after this, Pappenheim responded
to the ever-more insistent orders from Wallenstein that he move east to
reinforce the main Imperial army, and was to meet his own death at
Lützen a few weeks later.6
Three years later, in August 1635, a mixed force of ships set out from
Dunkirk on a raiding expedition of the type that had been characteristic of
the previous decade. The fleet comprised six frigates from the royal
Interpreting early modern warfare 141
squadron, built and manned under the direction of the Spanish crown,
and fourteen other privateering ships independently owned by Dunkirk
armateurs, who paid their captains and crews but hoped to cover costs and
make profits from successful prize-taking and booty. Some of these pri-
vateering vessels, like those constructed for the Van der Walle family of
armateurs, were built to the same specifications as the royal frigates: fast,
well-armed, low-lying vessels of 150–200 tonnes, designed to catch and
Stade
26 April – 7 May Hamburg
Elb
e
17 April
Verden
United
Provinces
Brunswick
10–16 Oct.
Hildesheim
Magdeburg
(3) 31 May. 1632
14–17 Jan. 1632
Hameln
(1) 29 Dec. 1631 4–12 April
Rh 18 July
ine (2) 28 Jan.–17
Jan. – 17Feb. ’32 Einbeck
Feb.’32 Saxony
27 Sept. 21 Oct
26 July Paderborn (4) 6–8 July
7–9 Sept. 18–20 Sept. 1 July
Rohrort Dortmund 15 Nov.
Warburg
Halle
Völksmarsen Höxter Munden 28 Oct.
27 June ’32 (16 Mar.) 9–16 June Mühlhausen
Westphalia Leipzig
Höxter II
19/20 Aug. 16 Nov.
29 Sept.
Vicinity
Vicinity Of
of Maastricht
Maastricht Battle of Lützen
Hesse
Cologne
22 Dec. 1631
Spanism
Netherlands
Thuringia
Frankfuat am Main
overwhelm the typical merchant ships, the fluyts, operated by the Dutch,
but potentially a match for heavier, slower warships.7 Others, drawn from
the pool of sixty or seventy privateering ships operating out of Dunkirk on a
year-on-year basis, were lighter, but still well armed and crewed. The fleet
was under the experienced leadership of the admiral of the Dunkirk royal
squadron, Jacques Colaert, who began his career as a privateering captain
employed by an armateur consortium of magistrates from Bergues.8 Setting
out into the North Sea, Colaert’s ships encountered the Dutch fishing fleet
operating out of the port of Enkhuizen: the fleet sank more than half of the
140 fishing ships, capturing more stragglers the following day. A few days
later they intercepted the Maas fishing fleet, overwhelmed their naval guard
and destroyed another twenty vessels. En route back to Dunkirk, laden with
prisoners and booty, the fleet ran into a Dutch battle squadron of twenty-
two ships and worsted them in the engagement, reaching security without
the loss of a single ship.9 The quantity of plunder was overwhelming,
together with 800 prisoners and the prize of a major Dutch warship. They
had managed to sink in the region of 8,000 tonnes of enemy shipping in just
over two weeks of operations.10 Earlier in the year, and following the
French declaration of war in April, another Dunkirk-based combination
of royal frigates and privateers had intercepted the French Dieppe fishing
fleet, capturing forty-two vessels from a fleet of fifty-two, together with one
of the largest French warships, the La Rochelle, captained by the father of the
later French admiral Abraham Duquesne, who was mortally wounded in
the combat.11 A month after his return to Dunkirk, Colaert and his fleet set
out again, and this time managed to intercept a large convoy of the Dutch
West India Company, capturing amongst other vessels the flagship of the
escorting warships.12 The impact of these losses on the Dutch economy was
severe and demoralizing: it was felt in the herring fisheries and in trade with
the Baltic and the Mediterranean, and had a significant impact on levels of
maritime insurance. Taken over the successive campaigns and losses across
the 1620s and 1630s it did a great deal more to disillusion the Dutch with
the conduct of the war than conventional military means ever achieved.13
These accounts of two very different military operations during the
Thirty Years War highlight the involvement of military enterprisers pre-
pared to finance and organize warfare on their own account, and give an
indication of the extent to which this involvement might determine the
methods and focus of the campaigning. Pappenheim himself articulated a
theory of aggressive, destabilizing and fast-moving operations as a deliber-
ate approach to war which, rather than relying on a single major encounter,
sought to make best use of limited resources and to exploit enemy weak-
nesses in detail.14 Colaert was invited to the court at Madrid, where he
proposed a coherent theory of intensified economic warfare based on a fleet
144 The military contractor at war
that included heavier galleons as well as the frigates, and further fortification
and harbour work on Dunkirk.15 Yet neither of these operations occupies a
significant role in most traditional accounts of the Thirty Years War.
Overviews of the century of European warfare from 1560 to 1660 have
been sharply divided. On one side, the period has been presented as an age
of dramatic tactical, organizational and strategic progress both on land
and at sea. It has been linked on land with the birth – or rebirth – of the
‘decisive battle’, and at sea with the triumph of firepower and line-of-
battle tactics. The period has been identified with great commanders,
Interpreting early modern warfare 145
whose military genius shaped and directed their armed forces in new
directions, and whose leadership and military achievements personify
the transformation of warfare: Maurice of Nassau, Gustavus Adolphus,
Maarten Tromp, Turenne, Blake, all occupy an assured place in accounts
of the changing character of early modern warfare and in the history of
military and strategic thinking. Perceptions of the period as one of pro-
gress and transformation were reinforced by widespread acceptance of the
‘military revolution’ thesis, first advanced as an integrated theory of
military change by Michael Roberts in 1955 (see above, pp. 14–17).
Though Roberts himself was measured in his assessments, subsequent
accounts of early modern warfare seized on the thesis, casting Gustavus
Adolphus of Sweden as the creator of modern warfare following a Dutch
prologue in which the basic foundations are laid by the military reforms of
Maurice of Nassau. Gustavus’ victories, most notably at Breitenfeld in
1631, signalled the birth of a ‘strategy of annihilation’, aimed via over-
whelming victories on the battlefield at ending wars quickly by the
destruction of the enemy’s will to resist.16
A very different view of this century of warfare, and above all of land
warfare, is not hard to find. Starting from accounts written at or just after
the time of the Thirty Years War, hugely reinforced by later eighteenth-
and nineteenth-century German romantic writers and in particular by
Schiller’s great trilogy of Wallenstein plays and his own history of the
Thirty Years War, the period was presented as one of all-destructive,
indecisive struggle, in which political aims and ambitions were totally at
odds with the military resources and strategy needed to achieve these. The
Thirty Years War shares with the first World War the dubious accolade of
being regarded as the pre-eminent example of a futile and meaningless
conflict.17
If the argument for an early modern ‘military revolution’ might seem to
have revived an interpretation of the period as one of tactical and strategic
progress, paradoxically much of the subsequent discussion and criticism
of the thesis has reinforced the trend towards a thoroughly negative
picture of wasteful, destructive and strategically sterile warfare. The argu-
ment for a transformation of the battlefield through tactical and organiza-
tional innovations had always owed more to the a priori claims of
reformers than to empirical validation through events on the battlefield.
There was nothing especially distinctive, let alone revolutionary, about
the redeployment of troops in shallower, linear formations which would
allow more infantry the opportunity to fire their muskets or arquebuses.
A wide range of tactical manuals published in the second half of the
sixteenth and in the early seventeenth century in Spain, Italy and France
indicate that there was a general evolution towards shallower, therefore
146 The military contractor at war
additional troops required to make good wastage from disease and deser-
tion in the siege camp, to convoy supplies to the encampment and to
provide one or more additional army corps to repel relief attempts. Sieges
could come to dictate the character of entire military campaigns. If some
commanders regarded a fortified city as a prize and bargaining counter
worth consuming an entire campaign to capture, other commanders who
might have sought a field engagement recognized that to leave heavily
garrisoned and well-defended fortified places in the rear of their army
would pose obvious dangers for the maintenance of lines of communication
and supply. And as Parker points out, the development of siege warfare was
more or less shadowed by a similar technological shift in the nature of naval
warfare, with its emphasis on more and heavier shipboard artillery and the
tactical shift to a style of combat based on firepower that was akin to the use
of batteries of artillery in sieges. The result was the same: more expense,
greater technological sophistication and higher demands for manpower.33
Historically convincing though the argument for the dominance of the
siege remains, it has a major consequence for the perception of warfare in
this period. If Michael Roberts argued that adopting new organization and
tactics on the battlefield restored military decisiveness, the great majority
of sieges, and the process of siege warfare itself, reinforce exactly the
opposite conclusion. Sieges were expensive, resource intensive in both
materials and the lives of military personnel and civilians, and achieving
the final surrender or conquest of a place stood a good chance of domi-
nating any given campaign to the exclusion of other operational objec-
tives. The French armies on the Flanders frontier between 1638 and 1646
poured resources into military campaigns that averaged just less than one
successful major siege per year, and in some cases that gain was offset by a
corresponding failure to hold a place elsewhere on the frontier.34
The same could be said about naval warfare in the Thirty Years War.
Both large-scale attacks on fortified coastal positions and set-piece sea
battles were costly, resource-consuming operations, which would con-
sume an entire campaign and offered only a small chance of decisive
results. The English failures at Cadiz (1626) and the Isle de Ré (1627)
were matched by the Spanish attempt to dislodge the Dutch from the
Brazilian coast (1639).35 Even Tromp’s encounter with the Spanish
fleet at the Downs had limited strategic impact, while the large-scale
Danish–Swedish engagement off Kolberger Heide (1644) was entirely
indecisive.36 Outright victories at sea usually reflected either substantial
numerical superiority or the ability to surprise a fleet in port or on the coast
before it could deploy for battle.
All of these factors appear to point in the same direction, confirming a
traditional picture of warfare as indecisive, destructive and futile. And
150 The military contractor at war
weary’.43 The problem with this stress on the operational level of military
activity is of course summed up in Clausewitz’s familiar remark: ‘every-
thing in war is very simple, but the simplest thing is difficult’.
Seventeenth-century commanders encountered external challenges to
achieving operational effectiveness: constraints in meeting the demand
for both food and munitions; problems of communication and trans-
portation; the impact of seasons, climate and disease on numbers of
military effectives, on physical resilience and troop mobility. They also
encountered limits from within the military structure: the quality and
staying power of their troops; adequacy of equipment and logistical sup-
port; effectiveness of command and control. These constraints could only
be surmounted by adaption, flexibility and a pragmatic willingness to
adjust methods and approaches without losing sight of overall objectives.
But within the limitations of the period, and with variations in effective-
ness that reflected individual military skill, organization, adaptabilty and
leadership, it is possible to say that the armies and navies of this period
managed to achieve a more impressive level of operational effectiveness
than they are usually credited with. Moreover they achieved this not
despite the involvement of military enterprisers and their activities, but
to a significant extent because of them.
At the root of the effective management of armies at an operational level
were two fundamentals, both of which reflect the preoccupations of the
military enterprisers who dominated the unit commands and through this,
the senior posts in the military hierarchy. The first was a strong personal
and financial interest, expressed collectively, in ensuring the sustainability
of the army. If the constituent colonel-proprietors in an army had been
prepared to invest money and credit to recruit and equip units of combat-
effective troops, now that these forces were raised they were concerned to
keep them in being. They had no wish to see their investment squandered
through ill-planned, unrealistic or badly supported military ventures.
This might of course suggest the typical anti-mercenary paradigm: unit
and army commanders would inevitably prove risk-averse in combat and
campaigning, acting, for example, simply to batten on to home or neutral
territory which could then be ransacked for military contributions to
recover their initial investment. But actual campaigning was usually less
straightforward than such easy calculations. In a few territories during the
Thirty Years War rival armies did manage to agree contribution treaties
which allowed the peaceful collection of war taxes by troops in adjoining
territories, or might involve protection money being paid by each side to
the other’s army to prevent military raids and plunder on their territory.
The best-known cases were on the borders between the Spanish
Netherlands and the United Provinces, where the armies from the later
The military enterpriser in his military context 155
Fig. 4.4 The surprise and defeat of the French Army of Germany at
Tuttlingen, 24 November 1643
1630s were reluctant to initiate new military activity, and both central
governments tacitly encouraged the maintenance of a locally financed
status quo.44 But contemporary commanders were aware that such agree-
ments usually depended on an extremely volatile military calculation. The
moment that an enemy field army could see both strategic and material
advantage in advancing into territory that was occupied by an army dis-
persed in an extensive, passive operation to garrison and collect contri-
butions, the fate of the latter would be sealed.45 Dispersed forces were
acutely vulnerable to a campaign army, graphically demonstrated for
example by the disaster that overwhelmed the French Army of Germany
as it dispersed into winter quarters around Tuttlingen in late 1643.46
Prudent military commanders thus had positive strategic and subsis-
tence interests in conducting an active defence of the territory they held
and denying control of other territory to the enemy. They had equally
strong financial and military incentives for carrying the war into enemy-
occupied lands to extend their own resource base and deny its use to the
enemy. To secure either goal they needed to maintain and deploy an
156 The military contractor at war
Operational effectiveness
the larger the potential recompense for this initial speculative investment
and for any subsequent expenses that the proprietors may have been
required to meet to sustain the unit. It is easily assumed that this require-
ment to provide some or all of the capital to raise the regiment or company
would lead to cost-cutting and the levy of the lowest-quality recruits. The
temptation certainly existed. Western and central European societies of
the earlier sixteenth century had undergone sustained population increase
with accompanying economic polarization and mounting social tensions
provoked by scarcity of land, rising food prices and downward pressure on
wages. From the later sixteenth century whole territories were disrupted
by the destruction of warfare, population dislocation, high levels of unem-
ployment and underemployment amongst rural and urban labouring
populations, and family and community destabilization caused by relent-
less waves of epidemic disease. This was the background for an unprece-
dented growth in impoverished or destitute populations across most of
Europe. Given the relatively modest size of military establishments before
the later seventeenth century, the potential to recruit from this marginal
population was almost unlimited. These were men, often unfit or under-
age, abandoned by their own communities and regarded as unwelcome
vagrants or criminals by urban authorities, who could be acquired for little
or no enlistment bonus by recruiting officers. They were available in huge
numbers, easy to draw into military service by bribes of drink or food.
They were also, as military enterprisers were mostly well aware, the worst
material on which to build a militarily effective and sustainable company
or regiment.47
This did not of course mean that such men were not recruited, and
indeed they probably formed a transient majority of most ordinary regi-
ments serving in the conflicts of the later sixteenth century or the Thirty
Years War. There were many cases where colonels would simply opt to
prioritize short-term financial interests in forming a regiment predomi-
nantly from such recruits. In other cases, despite goodwill, a colonel and
his recruiting captains might lack sufficient cash-in-hand or the organiza-
tional capacity to find recruits of better quality, often in circumstances
where they needed to meet a stringent timetable to ensure that the unit
was ready for service by the beginning of a campaign.48 On some occa-
sions, and in the face of multiple, competing demands from different
enterprisers and their warlords, it might simply be impossible to find
anyone other than raw, underage or unfit recruits to fill the ranks. The
recruitment of troops after 1618 certainly did not fall into any straightfor-
ward, steady pattern of demand, but like everything else required for the
war effort was determined by peaks and troughs of demand and supply.
But, easy to enlist, these men were no less rapidly lost: often they were
158 The military contractor at war
have survived the battle. He fell back into the hands of his old Imperial
regiment, where he was recognized and re-entered service until the end of
the war.58
However, it was unlikely that an army could be formed of entire regi-
ments bribed wholesale out of the service of another power, still less that
they could be formed from prisoners of war from enemy units. The
majority of experienced troops would need to be recruited piecemeal in
the marketplace. In practice, for reasons of both availability and cost, most
colonel-proprietors set their sights for the proportions of experienced
recruits realistically. Observing the Spanish army in the 1590s Roger
Williams suggested that it was enough that one in five of the troops should
be an experienced soldier to ensure that the units took on a character
defined by these men: ‘though his levied Armie be 50,000, the ten thou-
sand will both discipline them and keep them in order’.59
If somewhere around a minimum one-fifth of the unit might be made
up of experienced troops, it was anticipated that a good proportion of the
remaining raw recruits should be men who gave the physical and psycho-
logical appearance of being capable of sustaining the burdens and
demands of campaigning long enough to acquire some of the experience,
military skills and esprit de corps that would be passed on to them by the
experienced troops. In the Swiss military system, these were the Mats,
the young men judged strong, resilient and motivated enough to carry the
pikes and to work most closely with the veterans of several campaigns (see
p. 50). Military manuals by the late sixteenth century had conventional-
ized the notion of the suitable recruit for military service, and most of
the physical and mental characteristics were predictable enough.60 This
proportion of physically resilient recruits were at least as important as the
veterans: if the unit was to take on an identity, combat effectiveness and
military permanence, the experienced core of troops needed to work
amongst and transfer skills to a solid group of soldiers who would not
melt away after a few weeks or months in the ranks.
Obtaining both experienced veterans and good-quality recruits
required first of all a willingness to spread the net of recruitment widely.
Nothing demonstrates more clearly the extent to which privatized warfare
operated within an international market in which experience would always
trump notions of local or linguistic identity. In the process of recruiting his
first army in 1626 Wallenstein informed the Emperor that he had just
despatched recruiting patents for the levy of two regiments in Milan,
which would be made up of a high proportion of experienced veterans,
and accepted the delay that bringing them over the Alps and up into
Germany would cause.61 This concern to gain experienced troops eroded
the distinction, which had been a characteristic of the sixteenth century,
Operational effectiveness 161
But the issue is not straightforward: Peter Burschel argues that soldiers’
wages were more resilient than those of skilled and semi-skilled craftsmen,
whose absolute standard of living suffered real erosion in the decades from
the 1580s.69 We certainly know that it was not until the later seventeenth
century that soldiers’ wages were formally cut across most European states,
reducing their pay – and their social and economic status – to the level of a
hired day-labourer rather than a skilled craftsman (see p. 286).70
An even more fundamental problem in discussing soldiers’ pay is that in
many circumstances wages were not paid at all, or stood heavily in arrears,
either because the colonels and captains simply lacked the means to pay
them, or more cynically because they calculated that withholding arrears
would keep the soldiers in service. More than anything else, what pre-
vented this having explosive consequences was a further characteristic of
this period, the substantial shift to provision of food, drink and lodging by
the unit commanders in return for deductions from wages. From the
perspective of the unit proprietor, this was to become an important
element of the ‘business of the regiment’, one of the financial attractions
of military command to be discussed in the next chapter (see pp. 209–12).
Evidence from soldiers’ sources suggest that this commuting of wages was
accepted; the quality of provisions and accommodation concerned them
more on a day-to-day basis, and would have a greater effect on their
operational efficiency.71 Indeed some evidence suggests that soldiers
came positively to resent being given cash for subsistence, preferring to
take their allowances in kind, whether for food or accommodation.72
So there is certainly a gap between the wage levels stipulated in docu-
ments, whether these are recruitment notices or official ordinances ema-
nating from the high command or central government, and the reality of
pay on the ground. And if these generous ‘paper’ sums were actually paid
out, most often in the form of a recruitment bonus and the first few pays of
the campaign, this would have been targeted towards recruiting experi-
enced, veteran troops. There is certainly plentiful evidence of sums much
below these levels being paid to recruit inexperienced but decent-quality
troops.73 Nonetheless, any soldier who thought that he would actually
receive a regular wage package worth precisely 6 florins per month would
have been extremely naïve. In most months his cash and benefits would
fall below that level, though it is worth noting that occasionally he might
receive substantially more than his basic rate of pay, with wages supple-
mented by bonuses for storming fortifications or other high-risk actions,
the distribution of plunder, or lavish food and lodgings in occupied enemy
territory.74
Yet despite the system of wage deductions and payment in kind that was
at the heart of the business of a regiment, the status implications and the
Operational effectiveness 163
Fig. 4.5 Ordinary soldiers of the Thirty Years War in a sketch by Stefano
della Bella
wages had eliminated the extravagance of dress and the casual cash-in-hand
wealth of the soldier, it was still the case that discipline remained to some
extent consensual, and had more to do with shared perceptions of what
helped or harmed military effectiveness or cohesion than with the external
values of society.91 Some of the army commanders and some of the colonels
were determined to impose external disciplinary norms, but many others
were prepared to act to maintain the discipline required for military effec-
tiveness while doing little to regulate military/civil relations, and having no
interest at all in regulating morality and behaviour amongst the soldiers in
camp.92 This was not lethargy or indifference on the part of the officers, but
a recognition that what made these units work as cohesive, resilient and
effective fighting forces was their internal identity and dynamics, the per-
sistence of informal bonding and the small-group dynamics of the Rott.
Few colonels showed any desire to impose rigid confessional standards
on their soldiers, and life in the armies was characterized by a remarkable
degree of de facto tolerance and religious cohabitation.93 Some men were
certainly persuaded to take up military service ‘for the cause of religion’;
Robert Monro writes that this was the case for many of the Scots serving
with Gustavus Adolphus.94 Yet these were strict Calvinist Scots serving a
Lutheran ruler whose personal tolerance was at odds with a Swedish
Lutheran establishment which had no sympathy for the beliefs and
reforming aspirations of Calvinists.95 But within the army a Protestant
common front could be achieved based on respect for soldierly qualities
and a pragmatic sense of the need to play down divisive religious quarrels
that eluded the wider Protestant cause in Germany.96 Maximilian of
Bavaria’s uncompromising insistence on Catholicism, at least amongst
his officers, seemed an eccentricity in this military world.97
The communal and social life of the troops continued to focus upon the
Troß, with its women, sutlers, servants and the facilities for drinking,
eating, playing and socializing. This still provided local opportunities to
sell pillaged goods, borrow money, pursue crafts and skills acquired out-
side military life, and to live domestically with wives, children or the camp
women. Again, senior officers recognized the logistical and operational
liabilities of this vast ‘tail’ of army followers, their baggage and support
services. A few attempts were made to restrict or reduce the size of the
baggage column or the number of women and servants, but the centrality
of this structure of the Troß to maintaining regimental identity, keeping
long-serving soldiers in the ranks by providing them with a focus for their
social and emotional lives, was simply too great to risk substantial changes
or draconian restrictions.98
All of this contributed, in the soldier’s own eyes at least, to the sense that
he was a member of a corporation which continued to enjoy respectable
168 The military contractor at war
nearly 50 per cent of these surviving more than ten years – especially as the
overall figure takes into account those large number of ‘false starts’,
regiments which suffered early disbandment as unviable or badly
managed.111
This extension of the life of regiments clearly had its own impact in
drawing many veterans into a military lifestyle which became to all intents
permanent and attractive in its own right. The well-documented trans-
formation of the Parliamentarian New Model Army from Lipsius’ ‘sol-
diers of ayde’ during the first English Civil War into a force of permanent
career soldiers serves as an excellent example of the process by which
individual soldiers were drawn to a permanent military career as an
alternative to civilian life.112 Parallels can be found in most of the armies
operating on the continent, and in many of the navies which were coming
to enjoy a more permanent existence.113
An intriguing, but insufficiently explored, issue is the possibility that
lengthy military service may have meant that veteran soldiers built up a
considerable level of epidemiological immunity. These soldiers were not
only physically resilient in the face of the strains of campaigning, but may
well have become biologically resistant as well. If so, and the growing
proportions of ‘old soldiers’ in regiments would tend to support it, this
would be vital to the effectiveness of the armies. The impact of disease-
related mortality and sickness on the effective strength of armies is every-
where apparent. The example of the parish of Bygdea has been used by
many writers to show the effect of military conscription on a typical small
Swedish community. Of the 215 conscripted soldiers who died on active
service between 1621 and 1639, 196 fell victim to disease while in garri-
sons on the eastern or southern shores of the Baltic.114 What was true of
garrisons was as true of armies in the field and at sieges, where the
proportions of deaths through plague, typhus or dysentery were cata-
strophically high. The thesis that mortality was far higher amongst newly
recruited soldiers who had previously been relatively unexposed to a range
of infections would thus further strengthen the continuity provided by the
veteran element.
Finally, an issue which will be discussed below in more detail was the
reduction in the overall size of armies in the second half of the Thirty
Years War. Falling overall numbers, especially in the campaigning armies
rather than garrison forces, increased the percentage of veterans who had
served progressively long periods in the ranks. Whether through lifestyle
choice or physical resilience, these experienced men will be dispropor-
tionately those who remain in the units as the overall strength of a regi-
ment declines from, say, 900 to 400. If a good regiment might contain
20 per cent veteran troops in the 1620s, it was getting closer to 50–60 per cent
Operational effectiveness 173
or more by the last decade of the war.115 Moreover, with smaller armies
drawing from a population which had been exposed to several decades of
continuous military activity, it was simply easier to enlist troops who had
previous military experience. Taking the well-documented case of Bavaria
once again, and looking at the decade from 1638 to 1648, the proportions of
recruits from Bavaria and nearby recruiting areas with previous military
experience reached 58 per cent.116
For all these reasons it seems extremely probable that the military
quality, combat effectiveness and operational resilience of the armies of
the Thirty Years War improved during its latter stages. This conclusion
would not be startling in other military contexts, where it is usually
assumed that the experience of warfare leads to a cumulative improve-
ment in military effectiveness. But it directly challenges the usual percep-
tions of the Thirty Years War, and assumptions about the particular
sterility and futility of its second half.
50 per cent of the total costs of the supply contract.124 From Wallenstein to
Karl Gustav Wrangel in the very last campaigns of the war, commanders’
guiding principle in negotiating the supply of their armies and therefore in
planning their military operations was inland water. Rivers meant cheap
and relatively reliable transport of bulky goods like grain and gunpowder,
and made it far easier to move heavy artillery and baggage. Much of the
conflict of the Thirty Years War was fought along axes determined by the
four great rivers of the Danube, the Rhine-Moselle, the Elbe and the Po.
Bernhard von Saxe-Weimar was prepared to attempt the siege of
Breisach in 1638 with a small army, and well into the campaign season,
thanks to his confidence that he could control transport on the Rhine and
negotiate the delivery of basic food supplies to his army.125 Throughout
the siege his army was fed and supplied with munitions via the efforts of his
banker and supply-contractor, Marx Conrad Rehlinger, based at Basle,
but with a network of supply contacts spreading into Upper Germany,
across to Lyon and down into northern Italy.126 For several months
Rehlinger assembled supplies of grain and other foodstuffs at
Schaffhausen and arranged their shipment down the Rhine to
Breisach.127 The fatal problem for the Imperial commander, Johann
Götz, in trying to break the siege was his own inability to gain access to
the Rhine and to use it as a supply artery. His troops were forced into ‘hit-
and-run’ tactics against Saxe-Weimar, as Götz proved unable to sustain
his forces long enough in the area around Breisach to pose a decisive
threat to the besiegers.
On a larger scale, it can be argued that all of Wallenstein’s military
operations in both his first and second generalships can be understood
with reference to the rough north–south axis of the Elbe, supported by
secondary use of the more easterly Oder. A huge proportion of the finance
and provisioning of his army was drawn from Moravia, Silesia and
Bohemia, not just because they were wealthy subject territories providing –
albeit grudgingly – more reliable support than the German Imperial
Circles, but because of the easy river transport of goods to Wallenstein’s
armies, whether operating in north Germany, disputing control of Saxony
or defending the Habsburg lands themselves. Key to Wallenstein’s entire
provisioning system was the port of Aussig on the Elbe, the point of
despatch by water for foodstuffs, goods and war matériel from
Wallenstein’s duchy of Friedland and across Bohemia and Silesia on to
the German battlefields.128 The centrality of rivers to logistics was no less
clear to the Swedes, who quickly learnt the lesson of Gustavus Adolphus’
1632 failure before Nuremberg, where the Swedish army had suffered
heavy losses through overconcentration and lack of access to river-borne
supplies, while Wallenstein’s defenders had been regularly supplied with
Operational effectiveness 177
Denmark
Wallenstein’s
Duchies
nia
mera Campaign of 1626
Hamburg Po
Campaign of 1627
Elb Mecklenburg
e
Campaign of 1632
Brandenburg
Sagan
Saxony 162
7
O
de
Leipzig Aussig Friedland
r
Rh
ine
Main Prague
Bohemia
Nuremberg Moravia
2
163
ary
ng
Hu
Rh
urg
16
ine
sb
26
ube Austria
Ha
b
Dan
Munich Vienna
Venice
Map 4.2 Wallenstein’s military system and the campaigns of 1626, 1627
and 1632
early 1630s. What he did best was coordinating the supply and support
mechanisms for armies occupying and defending swathes of central and
north German territory, Bohemia, Silesia and Moravia. It is not difficult to
detect the Generalissimo’s unease when operating away from this vast
recruitment, provisioning and financial base, serviced via its crucial river
artery, and easy to see why so many apparent opportunities to push his
enemies harder were missed by his reluctance to distance his forces from
this secure environment.136
In contrast to this, commanders who sought to conduct operations that
were mobile and faster-moving, and who could seize initially unantici-
pated possibilities as Werth and Pappenheim had done, had to be aware of
the dangers of overextension of their resource base. Their mercantile
agents and connections, their financial backers and supply contractors
could help to sustain the army, but only if they were given adequate notice
of intentions, were drawn into the planning, and shared common prior-
ities. However carefully prepared, provisioning an army will never work
smoothly; the great strength of the armies that these commanders led was
the presence of soldiers who might complain about shortages or poor-
quality food, but would not give up, would not quickly lose their military
effectiveness or become demoralized. Provided that they saw the conse-
quences of the operations leading to supplies and pay, they would tolerate
present hardships and continue to pursue fast-moving, hard-hitting mili-
tary operations. Indeed commanders could play upon these qualities in
the context of acknowledged, effective leadership. Encountering initial
reluctance from his Bavarian troops, who had been subjected to haphaz-
ard supplies and pay over the winter quarter of 1635/6, Jan de Werth
galvanized them with enthusiasm for his campaign into France simply by
promising to make them rich men from French booty; they then became
the cohesive, effective force on which Werth had relied so successfully in
the past.137
However, the most striking and observable change in the main cam-
paign armies of the later Thirty Years War was the progressive reduction
in their effective strength. Throughout the war the issue of army size is
complicated by the difference between the total number of troops being
maintained by a particular power or within a generic ‘army’, and the
numbers actually serving in a particular campaign force, one that might
be active in a battle or siege. In both cases the numbers rise to a peak in the
later 1620s and early 1630s. Wallenstein was considered to have more
than 100,000 men in his armies by 1628–9, and Gustavus Adolphus
perhaps 150,000 men in his service by late 1631; at Breitenfeld, 31,000
Imperial and 40,000 Swedish and Saxon troops confronted each other on
the field.138 By the later 1630s and 1640s the total numbers of troops
Operational effectiveness 181
Schleswig and Jutland by his vast army moving as three separate corps,
each providing enough mutual support to ensure that the remaining
Danish forces of Christian IV could not risk challenging any one of
these columns.142 The success of this manoeuvre stands in sharp contrast
to the worries of Tilly in the same period that he lacked sufficient troops to
defeat a Danish counter-attack or maintain close control over occupied
areas of north Germany, and indeed his attempts to borrow forces from
the Imperial army.143
When Pappenheim was planning his 1632 diversionary campaign from
Westphalia into Lower Saxony, he was still strongly under the spell of the
‘irregular’ – Wallenstein – system for raising troops and waging war. With
an initially small force of experienced troops, Pappenheim ran circles
round the Swedish and Hessian troops in Lower Saxony. Yet his inten-
tions regarding the army were conventional: as soon as he could occupy
territory, extract heavy war taxes or occasional protection money, he
intended to recruit the army to the largest possible effective force. In this
he ran up against the advice of his military collaborator, Gronsfeld, who
had brought a Bavarian detachment to support Pappenheim’s activities in
1632. General Jost von Gronsfeld, one of the many capable commanders
operating in the Thirty Years War who have almost completely disap-
peared from the historical record, argued precisely the opposite, doubtless
from the perspective of Bavarian ‘regular’ warfare. To spend contribu-
tions on raising more troops rather than using the money to pay the wages
and provisioning of the existing forces was simply to pack the ranks with
inexperienced recruits – ‘useless boys’ in Gronsfeld’s words – rather than
focusing on the strength and coherence of the existing forces.144
Pappenheim appears to have been convinced. Although his death at
Lützen in November 1632 left his ultimate intentions unknown, he had
spoken significantly in correspondence about not wishing to create a
‘giant army’ in the Westphalian Circle and the Lower Saxon territories
under occupation, suggesting instead a total force of fewer than 20,000
(including the garrisons) and well supported through regular tax
exactions.145
By the mid-1630s the trend towards smaller armies was spreading
much more widely. The recognition that a smaller army made up of
more experienced and better-quality troops would lose little in strike-
power, but gain greatly in manoeuvrability and logistical durability, inter-
acted with political realities. Looking to the operational level of military
activity, and not seeing the future in terms of attritional frontier struggles,
great set-piece sieges or the notion of the once-and-for-all decisive battle
that would settle the war, a new generation of commanders began to
recognize the clear advantage of smaller campaign forces. In some cases
Operational effectiveness 183
there was limited choice. For Banér, fighting to hold Sweden’s territories
in north Gemany and to prevent Imperial forces pushing the Swedes into
the Baltic, a large part of the Swedish military establishment had to be kept
in garrisons in the great fortresses along the coast, and after the Peace of
Prague, the recruitment opportunities for the Swedes in the Empire were
massively restricted. Banér conducted a remarkable series of defensive
campaigns through 1636–41 with an army that rarely exceeded 20,000 in
total, but was predominantly made up of seasoned German and Scottish
veterans prepared to accept campaigns every bit as hard-driven, tactically
resourceful and demanding of fighting commitment as the one conducted
by Pappenheim in 1632.146 The Swedish conscripts from the native
indelningverk system were kept as garrison troops in the Baltic territories,
ttin nia
Ste era
Elb m
e Po
Mecklenburg
Wittstock
9
163
Brandenburg
Brunswick 37
16
36 Magdeburg
16 O
Torgau de
r
Halberstadt
Hesse Saxony Pirna Silesia
Erfurt Chemnitz
Bohemia
Thuringia 1640
Prague
16
41
Franconia Cham
Moravia
Regensburg
Austria
ube
Dan Vienna
Bavaria
Campaign of 1636–37
Campaign of 1639–40
Campaign of winter/spring 1641
partly because they were less experienced, partly as the Bygdea example
suggests, because they were already hugely vulnerable to epidemic disease
in garrisons and even more likely to suffer on active campaigning in
foreign territory.
But elsewhere, more troops could have been made available to increase
the size of field armies. Garrisons could have been pared down to raise
extra effectives – as indeed they were in the aftermath of military setbacks
or campaigns with a particularly heavy toll from sickness, desertion and
military casualties. In both 1642 and 1645 Imperial troops in Westphalia
were transferred to the main army to make good the heavy losses at
Breitenfeld II and Jankow.147 In general, however, the approach was
not, as a matter of military principle, to increase the campaign armies to
levels seen in the 1620s, but to keep them small. Even when opportunities
existed for expansion by recruitment or transfer they were not necessarily
taken.
The first obvious advantage lay in such an army’s smaller logistical
‘footprint’. Supplying the troops adequately with food and munitions –
by whatever means – was an imperative both in terms of the expectations
of the colonel-proprietors and in making possible any coherent opera-
tional plan. The considerably lesser burden of sustaining an army of
10,000–15,000 that could nonetheless retain its operational effectiveness
made a lot of sense. A larger army, which would almost certainly contain a
higher proportion of infantry, would increase the need for baggage trans-
port and swell the additional human ‘tail’ disproportionately, so that an
army of 25,000 might well involve double that number of mouths to
feed.148 It was surely no coincidence that two commanders with active
experience of fighting in this period, Turenne and Montecuccoli, should
both have expressed the view that feeding 30,000 mouths in a single army
(including the supply column) represented a ‘break-point’, above which
supplying armies – by any mechanism – became highly problematic.149
A further major implication of operating smaller campaign armies also
contributed indirectly to reducing the logistical problems of sustaining
campaigns. Smaller armies could make easier the operational objectives of
commanders who thought in terms of mobile, quick-hit campaigns, who
were prepared to cut deeply behind enemy lines, to threaten communi-
cations and to bring home the impact of war on territory which had
seemed secure from enemy incursions. The advantage of smaller forces
was that it was possible to be far more selective about the composition of
these armies. Overwhelmingly, commanders of the generation of Banér,
Hatzfeld, Torstensson, Turenne and Mercy sought to ensure that they
had high proportions of cavalry, irregular horse and dragoons or other
mounted infantry in their armies. By reducing the overall size of the field
Operational effectiveness 185
Fig. 4.7 The small cavalry-dominated army of the later Thirty Years
War: the battle of Mergentheim, 5 May 1645
was more likely than not to be the decisive aspect of the engagement,
especially given the cohesion of infantry units almost always placed in the
centre. But fighting major pitched battles was rarely the intention of these
generals in their approach to warfare; or rather, none of them believed that
a single battle, even under the most ideal circumstances, would have a
decisive, war-winning impact. Engaging in battle was a means to open up
the enemy territory to deep incursion, devastation and occupation – this
was certainly Torstensson’s intention in seeking combat at Jankow very
early in 1645, and the aim of the Swedish and French forces in forcing the
Bavarian army into battle at Zusmarschausen in mid-May 1648.155 Or it
was a means, usually when all else failed, to confront such enemy tactics
and inflict sufficient losses that they would have no capacity to press
forward with their larger strategy, as Mercy and Hatzfeld did at
Allerheim in 1645.156 But it was never more than part of an overall
campaign plan which would stress all the qualities of mobility, surprise,
rapid reaction and exploitation of circumstances for which large numbers
of cavalry were especially suited.
Operational effectiveness 187
Shifting the weight of the army towards cavalry had some operational
disadvantages: horses were no less prone to disease; they also needed to be
fed, and though grazing or forage could offer them just enough sustenance
to remain healthy, to be properly effective they needed measures of oats or
barley; cavalry mounts in particular were expensive – a decent cavalry
horse cost considerably more than a basic infantry soldier. Replacement of
horses was one of the heaviest burdens on an enterpriser-colonel, and one
reason why cavalry regiments were much smaller than infantry units, and
why the financial commitment to running a cavalry unit was approached
with some trepidation by potential colonels. But the horses themselves
provided the potential to carry much larger stocks of provisions, while
cavalry mobility offered the possibility of obtaining subsistence from local
requisitioning, or moving quickly out of areas where there was minimal
scope for support. Overall flexibility was simply much greater than for a
force predominantly made up of infantry.
If the deliberate focus on cavalry was a product of the commanders’
approach to campaigning, another implication of this was a reluctance to
engage in protracted sieges. While the capture of fortified places was by no
means a negligible advantage in campaigns that sought to place cumula-
tive pressure on the enemy, the opportunity costs needed to be set in
context. Smaller armies, focused on cavalry, were not suitable for a tradi-
tional siege of blockade and entrenchment, nor would it be easy to spare
large numbers of troops to act as a garrison in the captured place.
Moreover a campaign which was conceived in terms of rapid movements,
surprise and deep strikes into enemy territory would inevitably fail if
combined with a grinding, attritional siege that would absorb six weeks
of the campaign and might cost a third or half the field army lost to disease
and casualties. The recognition that sieges, if they were to be undertaken,
would probably succeed not through formal siege warfare but, as with
Pappenheim’s capture of Hildesheim in 1632, through trickery, threats
and surprise, also shaped operational decision-making. The French Army
of Germany under Turenne and Enghien suffered heavy casualties and an
undoubted tactical defeat at the battle of Freiburg on 3–5 August 1644.157
However, the Bavarian army fell back from the positions it had earlier
defended so effectively: Mercy judged it prudent to reconstitute the forces
further south where they could safeguard Bavaria and other south
German territory.158 At Turenne’s urging, the French army rejected the
obvious next move of seeking to besiege Freiburg – the apparent objective
of the battle – and doubled back up the Rhine to take advantage of the
limited Bavarian/Imperial military presence there. Having determined not
to take Freiburg through what might well prove a slow and costly siege, the
French were now able to seize the vastly more important Mainz and
188 The military contractor at war
significance was the way in which Banér used the previous winters of 1637/8
and 1638/9 to claw back many of the losses of Swedish-held territory and
fortifications suffered as superior Imperial forces had pressed into north
Germany during the summer months.163
Again, though, while the tactical and operational advantages of winter
campaigning are obvious, sustaining these campaigns and retaining
troops capable of continuing into the summer months of the next cam-
paign was a serious challenge. Cavalry-based forces had an obvious reason
for not campaigning in the winter months given the absence of forage and
new grass for grazing, although this could be surmounted via the careful
stockpiling and transport of fodder. Waging such winter campaigns was
also about ensuring that fresh troops were fed into the army at the begin-
ning of the spring to reinforce and sustain those who had been active over
the winter: both Banér and Torstensson relied on new Swedish levies
arriving on the Baltic coast in the spring, who could replace existing
garrison troops who in turn could be used to reinforce their field armies.
It was also about finding means to guarantee the financial interests of
proprietors who were given no time in winter quarters where they could
live off local exactions and taxes that would be distributed to allow them to
re-equip or remount their troops, recruit replacement soldiers and reim-
burse themselves for some of the costs of the campaign. Matthias Gallas
on one occasion complained with some hyperbole that the ordinary
Imperial soldiers garrisoned across the Rhenish-Westphalian Circle, a
key contributions base for the Imperial army in the 1630s and 1640s,
were better fed and accommodated than the senior officers in his own
campaign army. But it was the ability to redistribute a portion of the
money and resources from those areas where contributions were collected
to the officers with the regiments on campaign that made this system of
lengthy, sometimes winter-long campaigning viable.164
To examine systematically this style of waging war would require a
detailed campaign history of the Thirty Years War, especially its second
half, and a different, or much longer, book.165 The modus operandi of
commanders like Piccolomini, Bernhard von Saxe-Weimar, Banér,
Torstensson and Mercy has been alluded to throughout the previous
section. Briefly to offer an example of military operations from the latter
stages of the war which complements the opening account of Pappenheim’s
campaign of 1632, attention could be given to the campaign conducted by
the forces of Turenne and Karl Gustav Wrangel in 1646.
In late 1645 the Swedish-backed forces of Amalie Elizabeth of Hesse-
Cassel had moved against the city of Marburg, hitherto awarded to the
Hesse-Darmstadt branch of the family in a succession dispute dating back
to the 1620s. In early 1646 Swedish and Imperial forces were drawn into
190 The military contractor at war
United
Provinces
Rh Turenne’s Army Crosses Rhine, Turenne’s Army
ine 20 July.
Wrangel’s Army
Wesel Imperial/Bavarian Forces
Dortmund Kassel
10 August
Cologne Swedish Forces Under Wrangel
Marburg
(Late June)
Giessen
Imperial Fulda
Spanish and Bavarian
Koblenz
Netherlands Forces (June)
Donauwörth
Donauwörth
Rh
Ulm 20 Sept.
Augsburg
Munich
Epilogue
It was not, however, Turenne’s theory of waging war that was vindicated
in conflict after 1648. Thereafter west-central European warfare assumed
a character familiar from traditional accounts of early modern conflict:
large-scale, cautious and slow-moving, with campaigns dominated by
sieges in which the occasional field encounters were always bloody and
most often indecisive. This transformation of warfare and the redefining
of the public–private balance in its organization will be the subject of
Chapter 6. From the perspective of the waging and character of warfare,
the most obvious consequence was the inexorable drift to military gigan-
tism that followed from elevating the authority of rulers in the organiza-
tion and control of warfare. In the first half of the sixteenth century it had
been the dynastic inheritance of the Habsburg Emperor Charles V and the
political context in which he operated that had been the primary factor in
stimulating the upward surge in the size of armed forces. In the same way,
the determination of Louis XIV to assert control over his armies and to
shape the French fiscal-military apparatus in order to underwrite his
international policies precipitated the second great round of international
military inflation. For Jacques de Guibert, whose favourable comment on
the commanders and strategy of the later Thirty Years War was cited at the
opening of the chapter, the military decay of ancien régime warfare started
with Louis XIV and his age. Guibert, whose opinions are normally only
cited in the context of the military debates of the 1760s onwards, offers a
dismal picture of growing state involvement in European warfare.
What Guibert noted was the return of war as carefully staged combat
between dynastic rivals, in which the reputation of rulers was a key
principle, both determining and restricting the ways in which campaigns
could be planned and fought. The state control of armies tended always,
and most notoriously in the second half of the seventeenth century,
towards overly large armies pursuing single objectives. Louis XIV’s deci-
sion to command his armies in person as an exercise of assertive sover-
eignty led to a concentration on siege warfare as an appropriate symbol of
an essentially dynastic struggle, and sapped resources from other cam-
paign theatres as it became a matter of dynastic reputation that the siege
Epilogue 195
should succeed.170 The ‘honour’ that Turenne had suggested was overly
associated with the capture of fortified cities and towns returned as the
determining motive in the conduct of war. Armies that were large enough
to ensure that there should be no setbacks in the royal presence were
assembled for the nineteen sieges at which Louis was personally present
between 1667 and 1692.171 The king’s personal command ensured a
further level of caution in a style of warfare that was already slow-moving,
attritional and risk-averse because of the size of the armies and the obses-
sion with maintaining supply via convoys from frontier magazines.172
Once a fortified place had been captured, there was a strong temptation
to abandon the campaign rather than risk further objectives where set-
backs might compromise the accrued gloire of the king.
A vast and inflationary expansion in armed forces did nothing to make
war more decisive or to achieve strategic goals.173 The close synthesis of
means and ends that had lain at the heart of the military enterprise of the
later Thirty Years War had been swept away at a military as well as a
political level. The dominance of the ruler and the centre in the formula-
tion of policy was accompanied by assertive control over military planning
and strategy. Behind this direct control of military force was what Marshal
Vauban identified as strategic formlessness: attritional war based on
unprecedented armies perpetuated conflict on a scale greater, costlier
and more burdensome than the Thirty Years War, but offered no guide
to winning the kind of strategic advantage that would give France or
indeed any other power the lasting political hegemony in Europe which
these expansionist political and military methods had sought.174
These developments represent a daunting challenge to unreflective
assumptions that increasing the state’s control over armies and navies
must equate with greater operational efficiency and higher levels of stra-
tegic and operational effectiveness. It was to be Europe’s tragedy that the
approach of Turenne and his military contemporaries was virtually dis-
regarded for a century after 1650, while dynastic imperatives, pursued by
armies and navies in which the state became everywhere the majority
shareholder, dominated the waging of warfare on a scale and with a
human and material cost beyond anything seen in the campaigning of
the Thirty Years War.
5 The business of war
196
Supplying war for profit 197
engagements and sieges. If they were sea captains the centrality of provi-
sioning their vessels for an entire voyage would in most cases be a self-
evident requirement before setting out from port.
Military commanders might facilitate logistical operations: they might
choose to move their armies along the routes of rivers to permit water-borne
transport of bulky supplies and equipment; they might plan their campaign
with the expectation that the army would reach locations according to a
timetable that would allow the stockpiling of food and munitions; they
might be able to requisition carts and wagons to assist in the transport of
supplies, or act directly to requisition foodstuffs from the localities through
which the army passed. Yet beyond this they would need to draw upon the
production, manufacturing and distribution capabilities of groups of spe-
cialists. These groups are themselves a vital part of the business of war, and
their activities have a direct impact on the ways and effectiveness with which
war was waged in this period.
Where armies and navies are raised and maintained by the central
state and its agents, it is frequently assumed that all these support
services will also be handled by the state. A centrally controlled system
of provisioning and administration would employ officials of varied rank
and responsibility, who would act under commission to collect together
supplies of grain, meat and other foodstuffs, or a range of munitions and
equipment, store them in magazines and issue them to garrisons, to
armies in the field, or to fleets of galleys or galleons. If transportation
of foodstuffs was required, or grain needed to be milled into flour and
baked into bread, this would be done through the agency of these
officials. Payment for all these activities and for the collection and
storage of foodstuffs would be met either directly out of state revenues,
or in the form of tax credits or other means of offsetting subjects’ fiscal
and military liabilities against provisions. Such a system could extend to
the production of armaments themselves, which in the purest form of a
state-run military support system would be manufactured in factories,
workshops or dockyards established and financed by the state, operated
by workers and specialists who were state employees, and whose activity
was exclusively determined by state contracts and demand. A total system
of procurement, distribution and production of this sort would represent
the ideal version of a system which the early modern Spanish Council of
State termed ‘administración’, the direct state control of military support
functions.
There is no reason why, even when the state’s role in the raising and
running of armies and navies is more restricted, aspects of military support
systems should not be directly administered. But in sixteenth- and
seventeenth-century Europe, there are few instances of such direct public
198 The business of war
Louis de Geer and Elias and Pieter Trip who began producing and market-
ing Swedish iron cannon from the mid-1620s. De Geer organized and
financed the production of cannon in Sweden, hugely developing the
foundries at Arboga under licence from the crown, but with technical
expertise and much of the skilled labour provided by Dutchmen and gun-
founding experts from Liège.22 The scale of the industrial activity dwarfed
English manufacture: in 1630 alone the Trips imported 1,182 cannon from
Sweden, on which they paid an advance of 223,000 guilders, and then
proceeded to sell across Europe. Again, the Swedish crown seems to have
been content to leave the manufacturing of iron cannon in the hands of
private and non-native enterprisers, and only briefly, from 1652 to 1656,
sought to establish a crown monopoly over the export of guns.23
early modern Europe, various and very different private interests were
involved in the business of war. All of the mechanisms for equipping
and supplying armed forces were in various ways inadequate to the task,
and resilience in the system was owed to the multiple levels on which it
operated.
and the daily life of armies and garrisons, an exclusive reliance on small-
scale traders and sutlers to supply troops, especially armies on campaign,
would have provided only marginally more logistical security than
dependence on foraging and living off the land.33
The Genoese galley squadrons give some sense of the profits that could
be made from Spanish contracts. In apparent contrast, the captains of the
warships built and run by the Admiralties in the United Provinces during
the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries did not make comprehensive
contracts to crew, equip and maintain their ships. As employees, like
their men, they were paid a modest salary, which would potentially be
supplemented, as with all naval activity, by prize money and other gains
from raiding or combat. But by far the most important source of income
for captains was the ‘provisioning pennies’ (kostpenningen). The provision-
ing of warships was the responsibility of the captain and the flag officer for
each ship. The Admiralty paid them a fixed allowance per crewman per
day, which varied between 5 and 7 stuivers, and this was deliberately set at
a higher rate than was necessary to cover the expense of the prescribed
rations. The margins for profit were quite generous, varying between one-
third and one-fifth, and over a lengthy voyage in a ship with a large crew,
could net a profit of several thousand florins. The less welcome side of this
arrangement was an element of risk: the commanders were expected to
purchase the provisions in advance, and were never sure that the sums of
provisioning pennies would be paid immediately on their return. When
the Admiralty coffers were near-empty, paying the provisioning costs was
always regarded as the lowest priority, and the relatively high margin of
profit afforded by good management was taken as the equivalent of formal
interest payments on the delayed repayment.43
Examples of the ‘business of a warship’ could be multiplied across the
period, and naval warfare was considerably ahead of comparable develop-
ments on land. But with the post-1560 shift towards longer-term military
contracts the potential for more comprehensive ‘regimental business’
developed in line with these maritime initiatives.
Sixteenth- and seventeenth-century military manuals for the ‘perfect
captain’ detailed an extensive range of duties, responsibilities and behav-
iour appropriate to a regimental colonel, but notably absent from these
was one of his main functions: the arming, equipping and provisioning of
his soldiers. Vehemently asserting that he was ‘no tradesman’, Franz
Albrecht von Sachsen-Lauenberg, one of Wallenstein’s colonels, was
nonetheless typical in mastering the skills of finding goods and supplies,
negotiating contracts, and arranging for the transport of these goods to his
regiment.44 As the numbers of soldiers being recruited increased, the
convention that the soldier brought along his own weapon and equipment
when he was enlisted was tacitly abandoned. Colonels also had overall
responsibility for replacing damaged or lost weapons and other equip-
ment, and, most important and expensive, making good killed or injured
horses in cavalry regiments. Army commanders considered that the
The ‘business of the regiment’ and ‘of the warship’ 209
acquiring these food supplies and services at below the rates at which they
would supply them to their soldiers.51 After paying the soldiers a large part of
their wages in food and drink or as a subsistence allowance, and taking the
various deductions for provision of weapons, equipment and clothing into
account, the remaining money owed would be held by the unit commander
until finally distributed to the troops as lump sums at occasional musters.
There were practical advantages in placing some aspects of equipping and
provisioning the troops in the hands of their colonels, quite apart from giving
them a further financial incentive to commit initial capital to the regiment.
But in a European manufacturing sector dominated by small-scale produc-
tion and supply at the level of individual workshops, obtaining weapons or
armour even for a few hundred men at very short notice, and in competition
with numbers of other colonels trying to do exactly the same thing, was no
easy task. The problem was not primarily financial, although it is notable how
large a part of the expense of raising a regiment would consist of purchasing
military equipment, leaving to one side the enormous expense of mounting
cavalry units.52 Many aspiring colonels were engaged in the hunt for credit as
well as goods. Franz Albrecht von Sachsen-Lauenberg was a younger
brother, and perennially hard-pressed for cash and credit, and in the course
of recruiting his ‘neusächsisch’ cavalry regiment in 1625 he persuaded his
lieutenant-colonel, Melchior von Hatzfeld, to raise several thousand talers
on his own credit in order to fund some of the costs of equipping the
regiment.53 The main issues, though, remained the short space of time
between receiving a commission and presenting a fully recruited, fully
equipped regiment for a first muster, and the limited access of the individual
colonel to a range of widely dispersed producers and manufacturers. If an
army was being assembled in the vicinity of a great arms-production centre,
Nuremberg, for example, or Liège, then the problems might be manageable
even if numbers of colonels were all looking to buy equipment or have it
manufactured at the same time and as quickly as possible. Or if a colonel was
well organized, and had some previous experience of raising troops, he
would delegate a competent and trustworthy subordinate to organize pur-
chase and despatch of goods from a more distant centre of arms manufactur-
ing. Wallenstein’s colonels in early 1632 were acquiring cuirasses in Milan
and Brescia, cheap muskets in Leipzig and across towns in Silesia, and
gunpowder and match from Viennese contacts.54 Jan de Werth had an
established relationship with arms suppliers in Cologne, and purchased
weapons and equipment for his regiments there.55 When Franz Albrecht
received permission to raise his regiment in 1625, Hatzfeld was immediately
sent to Nuremberg, where he organized the purchase and transport of
weapons and equipment, and obtained credit with the bankers Anton and
Tobias Geiger.56 Hatzfeld’s specialized knowledge and good contacts in the
The ‘business of the regiment’ and ‘of the warship’ 211
world of arms producers became well known; other colonels, having been
less successful themselves, approached him for advice and assistance in
equipping their units.57 Yet even Hatzfeld’s abilities could not overcome
all the problems of timing and delivery, and when after a lengthy and
financially profitable winter quarter in Silesia, Franz Albrecht’s cuirassier
regiment was inspected by Wallenstein in June 1627, a large part of the
armour that had been ordered for new recruits and to replace damaged or
missing equipment had not arrived. Wallenstein had little patience with these
failings, however explicable: the inadequately equipped companies were held
back in Silesia as garrison forces, while the main army moved off against
Christian IV.58
If colonels encountered problems in trying to collect together arms and
armour for their soldiers, the provision of munitions or foodstuffs posed
still greater difficulties, above all for an army on campaign, and these
could quickly develop beyond the resources of the regimental
commander, however potentially attractive the financial returns from
supplying his men might be. In some garrisons, the commander might
be able to draw up contracts with local merchants or even directly with
producers, or he might arrange with the local authorities for some of the
contributions payments owed to his regiment to be commuted into food
supplies, which could be regularly delivered and distributed to his troops
against deductions from their wages which he would then claim.59
However, when garrisons were established for overtly military purposes,
rather than to ensure the collection of contributions – the Hungarian
borderlands, for example, or the Spanish garrisons on the Atlantic islands
or in North Africa, or in territory in the Empire which was not unambig-
uously held by one particular power – reliance on local supply contracting
might easily be disrupted, and would render the garrison vulnerable to
external pressures.60 The problems were compounded when troops went
on campaign, especially when pursuing the fast-moving, rapid-strike style
of warfare which became characteristic of the second half of the Thirty
Years War. There was little possibility that the troops could be issued with
more than a few days’ worth of initial supplies through the particular
negotiations and supply provisioning of the colonels.61 In these cases
and in meeting many other provisioning and support demands, it was
the networks of large-scale private suppliers, manufacturers, merchants
and financiers, working in conjunction either with state administrators or
more often with the military commanders as contractors in their own
right, who provided the largest part of the military support for armies
and navies. They stood at the heart of the business of war throughout this
period.
212 The business of war
Sweden Danzig
Hamburg
London Amsterdam
The Hague Utrecht Essen
Weald Gouda
Delft
Dordrecht
Antwerp Maastricht Marsberg
Tournai Solingen
Mons Cologne Leipzig
Aachen Friedland
Liège Frankfurt
am Main Suhl
Namur Prague
Moselle
Augsburg
Vienna
Basel
Helvetic
Confederation Financial Centres
Armament Production
Milan Brescia and Distribution
Venice Financial and
Lyon Armaments Centres
Genoa
Trip, Louis de Geer and three other merchants launched a company which,
working with the Marselis firm in Hamburg, aimed to control the entire
external supply of saltpetre, whether imported from the Baltic, West Africa
or the Far East.68 This aim of achieving a monopoly of gunpowder supply
(usually through control of saltpetre) drove a series of international business
partnerships through the 1630s, each one being thwarted by the opportu-
nities that an increase in the price of gunpowder offered to other enter-
prisers who managed to obtain supplies of saltpetre from elsewhere and to
manufacture gunpowder competitively.69 The financial rewards were
exceptionally high: a Danzig merchant, Peter Möller, and his Amsterdam
business partner, Arndt Pilgrim, managed to control saltpetre imports via
Danzig over two periods of three years, and netted a return on their initial
investment of 220 per cent, while normal profits on purchase-resale busi-
ness of this sort would be 14 per cent.70
While it was certainly not in the interests of military commanders to see
the distribution and the price of gunpowder or other military materials
monopolized by a particular commercial consortium, in fact these
attempts were symptomatic of a process far more important for meeting
military needs: a drive to bring together the production and distribution of
military matériel and to concentrate it in certain centres, from where
distribution to armies would be both easier and more able to meet sudden
peaks of demand. Whether this was via Hamburg, Genoa, Amsterdam, or
the other German or north Italian cities associated with arms distribution,
the effect was to focus supply through networks which were more capable
of bringing together production, and arranging the reliable and rapid
amassing and transportation of arms, munitions, clothing and indeed
foodstuffs than any other mechanisms in early modern Europe. Almost
all major companies involved in marketing of munitions, or dealing in
bulk food supplies and other raw materials, were based on these elaborate
networks. They cut across not just national, but confessional and indeed
military boundaries. Julia Zunckel offers a telling example of a contract to
supply troops raised to defend Genoa, negotiated in 1625 by the Genoese
firm of Balbi, which involved buying gunpowder in Amsterdam via the
Amsterdam merchant and the Balbi business-partner, Guglielmo
Bartolotti. Bartolotti was born Wilhelm van der Heuvel in Utrecht and
spent his youth in Hamburg. He adopted his Italian name to cement the
partnership with his uncle from Bologna, who directed a substantial
trading company dealing between southern and northern Europe.
Bartolotti/Heuvel would ship the powder that he would purchase in
Amsterdam, via neutral Hamburg ships, back to Livorno, thence to
Genoa. Given the acute shortage of saltpetre on the Amsterdam market
in 1625–6, Bartolotti’s completion of this assignment was extraordinarily
Supplying war at an international level 215
Essential structure of the international armaments trade in the first half of the
seventeenth century
INDIA DANZIG
Saltpetre export to
Europe from the 1620s
LÜBECK
AMSTERDAM HAMBURG
Centre of the arms trade – especially Centre of the arms trade,
for the anti-Habsburg powers especially in dealings with
TRIP – DE GEER – BARTELOTTI Spain. VAN UFFELN-BERENBERG
MARSELIS (monopoly control) GROENEDAEL & VERPOORTEN
RODENBURG-DE GREVE-RULAND
MARSELIS (DENMARK)
NUREMBERG SUHL
Arms industry Arms industry
ALBERTINELLI SCHNEIDER
SOHNER – EGGHOLD JUNG – KLETT
SHÖNER – HERBERT HERLEIN
ITALY AUSTRIA
SPAIN TRIP – QUINGUETTI PESTALOZZI – VERTEMA
CALENDRINI – BARTOLOTTI FERRARI
HURREAU
efficient, and his costs reasonable, charging a commission of only 3 per cent
on the deal. The ability of the Balbi firm to deliver on the contract rapidly
and reasonably depended on their connections with Bartolotti, and in turn
Bartolotti/Heuvel’s own links with the munitions empire of Elias Trip and
Louis de Geer.71 The obvious fact that the gunpowder was being provided
from the United Provinces to support the defence of Spain’s main Italian
ally while Spain and the Dutch were at war underlines the international
character of this network and its ability to tap sources regardless of military
and religious boundaries, and on the basis of well-established networks of
business associates.
The example also underlines the high level of commercial/fiscal sophis-
tication that underpins this international system. In an early modern
context of rudimentary and limited administrative capacity on the part
of governments, the supply of armies was being integrated into a remark-
able structure of mercantile experience and organizational skill and
knowledge about supplies, available production capacity and transport
options.72 Moreover, as the Thirty Years War continued, these systems
grew more extensive. A high-point was reached with the network estab-
lished by Hans de Witte, Wallenstein’s right-hand man in finance and
supply throughout the first generalship. De Witte’s network linked an
unparalleled number of centres and personal contacts, on whose credit,
administrative efforts and connections with manufacturers and suppliers
de Witte could hope to draw. Stretching from Venice to Antwerp, and
Madrid to Prague – the centre of de Witte’s activities – all the major
trading and financial centres were represented by trusted merchant-
financier-agents of de Witte’s, from Walther de Herthoge in Hamburg,
Anton Frey-Aldenhoven in Cologne and Amsterdam, Witte’s nephew,
Arnold de Witte, in Antwerp, the Pestalozzi firm in Genoa and Milan,
Johann Schwendendörfer in Leipzig, Abraham Blommaert in
Nuremberg, Giovanni de Valli in Venice, and a wide range of high-value
contacts in both Prague and Vienna.73 De Witte’s system interlinked at
multiple levels: de Witte’s chief agent and negotiator in Hamburg, Walter
de Hertoghe, worked closely with the arms-dealing mercantile consor-
tium Verpoorten-Ruland-Groenedael, two of whom were family relatives,
and who maintained close business and personal contacts with some of
the great Amsterdam munitions dealers, headed by Elias Trip.74 De
Hertoghe’s other connections included the powerful Genoese trading
agent, based in Antwerp, Jan Paolo Dorchi, who was the key link in
moving supplies and munitions between northern Europe and the
Mediterranean for the benefit of Habsburg armies.75 The result was a
wide-ranging network of financial resources and goods in which, for
example, war taxes might be collected from populations in the Lower
Supplying war at an international level 217
- Key centres in
de Witte’s system
14
Hamburg
R. E
2
lbe
Amsterdam 17
4
3 Naumberg 10
11 16 Arnsdorf
Antwerp Dresden 7
England 8 Leipzig 19
Cologne Pirna Breslau
1 6 15 Hohenelbe
23
Aachen Aussig
12 Suhl
9 Frankfurt 20 24
Darmstadt am Main Prague Tetschen
18
Nuremberg
22
Strasbourg 5 26
Augsburg Vienna
21
Schlaggenwald
25
Venice
13
Genoa
Saxon Circle, and used in part to mobilize credit contracted with Genoese
financiers, whose loans had been used to pay Hamburg arms manufac-
turers and suppliers, who in turn had shipped their goods to an Imperial
army based in Bohemia. Such a system of highly personalized contacts,
frequently sharing the closest financial interests, would seem to be the
antithesis of bureaucratic, externally supervised administration, and a
licence for every kind of corruption and malpractice. In practice the
tight, personalized integration and the overlapping and extensive financial
interests created a strong set of shared interests, all of which ultimately
depended on sustaining the success of Wallenstein’s army.
Long before the Thirty Years War, the Spanish monarchy had already
been negotiating supply contracts for both armies and navies on a scale that
dwarfed the activity of any other European state. Once the decision to out-
source had been taken, the contracts were bold statements of confidence in
the capacity of the private sector. As the primary naval power in the Atlantic
world, the Spanish crown was prepared to negotiate contracts such as that
drawn up in 1603 with Gonzalo Vaz Countinho to pay and supply the entire
Atlantic fleet, 40 ships and 6,392 men, for eight years in return for 740,000
ducats in the first year and 790,000 in each of the remainder.79 Indeed the
Spanish crown’s administrators seem to have considered that large-scale
contracts were the most efficient and economical, and usually selected
their contractors from a tight-knit group of major financiers and merchants
capable of mobilizing money and resources on this scale. So after 1601, for
example, the provisioning of bread rations to the entire Army of Flanders was
entrusted to a single private contractor, holding the office of proveedor de
víveres, a contract worth more than 2 million escudos per year.80 By the
1620s and 1630s the government was diversifying the contracts once again,
and the largest were with the Genoese supplier Marco Antonio Gentile and
the Flemish Amand de Hornes, while in the 1640s the contact for supplying
bread to the army, made with Vincenzo Lazagna, granted him 75,000
escudos a month on the taxes from Antwerp.81
Where possible then, the Spanish administration would seek to concen-
trate financial, administrative and organizational control in the hands of a
single contractor. Thus, for example, a contract was made with the Genoese
Antonio Graffior in 1639 for the manufacture of gunpowder, giving him
rights to all the saltpetre produced in Castile in order to supply the crown
with 41,000 quintals of gunpowder over seven years.82 Some exclusive
contracts of this type could prove very successful: in 1628 a contract was
made with the Liège iron-master, Jean Curtius, to set up a cast-iron cannon
and shot factory at Liérganes, near Santander. By 1640, 1,171 guns and
nearly 250,000 assorted pieces of shot had been produced and delivered.
Though there was still heated debate about the relative weight and durability
of cast-iron guns compared with bronze, the financial factor gradually took
the upper hand. Cast-iron artillery once again demonstrated its commercial
viability, and a series of contracts would ensure that Spain could be self-
sufficient in iron guns until the end of the eighteenth century.83
Not all contracts were on this vast scale, for many military functions
simply did not permit this kind of consolidation. In December 1603 a
contract was signed with the Lisbon businessman Manuel Gómez de
Acosta to supply the garrison troops on Madeira and Terceira with all
their pay and provisions for six years. For these services the contractor
would receive a total sum of 61,770 escudos from the crown rents on the
222 The business of war
two islands. When dealing with small, isolated garrisons and their for-
tifications, the most obvious contractor for a long-term supply contract
might be the governor or captain himself. Individual deals with captains of
garrisons in the Spanish monarchia or for the upkeep of individual vessels
had been common under Philip II, and continued into the seventeenth
century.84 This was no less true of France, where the crown frequently
sought to make contracts with governors of fortifications to meet the costs
of the garrison in return for a stipulated share of locally allocated tax
revenues. When Colonel Hans Ludwig von Erlach was appointed gover-
nor of Breisach, the French crown in consideration of his expenses as
governor also gave him full rights to exploit the surrounding iron mines for
his own profit, manufacturing and selling cannon balls and other arms to
supply the French magazines in Alsace.85 Similar contracts could be made
for the construction and repair of fortifications, and it would appear that
the king himself was not above haggling over deals with his soldiers:
Jacques de Chastenet de Puységur, captain in one of the French elite
regiments, claimed that in 1639 Louis XIII in person offered him the
contract to construct some of the siege-works around the city of Hesdin,
proposing a payment of 6,000 livres. Puységur eventually argued the king
up to 7,700 livres and undertook the work on the basis of this contract.86
This was not the first time that he had been drawn into contracting for the
crown: in 1632 he had been sent by Louis XIII to Liège to purchase 4,000
muskets and 2,000 breast/backplates, and to negotiate the best price for
these – presumably under commission. Puységur bought the weapons and
armour in Liège and Utrecht, had the guns proved in Holland, and
organized the shipping of them from Holland back to Rouen.87
Puységur may well have made a decent profit on the fortification work if
the king’s original offer had been realistic. However, if the Balbi contract
to provide gunpowder for the Genoese government is typical, weapons
and munitions procurement yielded relatively small returns. Acosta’s
contract for the upkeep of the Madeira garrison over six years envisaged
total profits of around 12 per cent on 61,000 escudos.88 And of course it
was possible to make an outright loss. A large-scale shipbuilding contract
in Vizcaya made between the crown and the shipbuilder Martin de Arana
in 1625 fixed a price of 72,000 ducats for six galleons, calculated on
overall tonnage, so that the total paid was 79,752 ducats taking into
account the slightly larger ships actually constructed.89 Arana claimed
that he had spent a further 6,000 ducats without reimbursement to fulfil
the contract, extra expense which was ultimately disallowed by the audi-
tors who looked over the ships before taking delivery of them in the king’s
name and adjudicating on the completion of the contract. However, in
1631 Arana was nominated Superintendent and Captain of War over the
State administration and private supplier contracts 223
such a contract to be milled into flour, then baked into bread, where and
by whom? How far were mechanisms for transport and distribution taken
into account? The expense of providing transport could easily exceed the
cost of grain or other basic foodstuffs, and it was the area in which the
French munitionnaires proved most consistently inadequate.101 One rea-
son why naval supply contracts may have worked more efficiently, with
fewer spectacular breakdowns and failures, is that the collateral aspects of
supplying a naval squadron were less complex, at least in the area of
transport and distribution.102
Faced with contractual arrangements that seemed to institutionalize such
problems by shying away from the complexity and expense of anticipating a
dynamic and unpredictable military scenario, certain assumptions about the
character of warfare, especially land warfare, took root. In an operational
context, there were sound reasons to avoid a static, positional style of war-
fare, focused on set-piece sieges which absorbed most of the military effort of
a particular campaign. But the implicit assumption underpinning inflexible,
centrally negotiated supply contracts was that this was the one style of warfare
which could reduce – though not by any means eliminate – the risks inherent
in arrangements for supply which had very limited flexibility or adaptability
built into them. If that was the assumption of central government when
negotiating supply contracts, it was an attitude passed down to commanders
in the field, who were directly affected by the potential breakdown of supply
contracts and rightly pessimistic about the ability of contractors to deliver to
the army in any other than the most straightforward and largely static
contexts. Unsurprisingly many commanders, albeit not without frustration
directed both at the ‘grasping munitionnaires’ and the disengaged and unre-
alistic central government, simply accepted the constraints that such a
system imposed.103
The concentration of very large contracts in the hands of a small number
of powerful private enterprisers had a further potentially damaging conse-
quence. As we have seen, many of these men would be prepared to accept a
high level of financial and economic risk, even to make uneconomic con-
tracts, in part because they hoped that their activities on behalf of the ruler
would bring social recognition and benefits. In some cases the willingness to
undertake provisioning contracts and to lend financial services might also
be a lever to bargain for high military office. This latter was seen, for
example, in the military careers of various members of the Fugger family,
notably Franz Fugger, count of Kirchberg, who rose to the rank of general
in the Bavarian army.104 It appeared most extravagantly in Ambrogio
Spinola’s proposal that he would finance the entire Army of Flanders,
initially during the siege of Ostend, in return for overall military command
of the army.105 This combination, though provoking to traditional military
226 The business of war
grandees, was overall quite beneficial. After all, it brought a direct fusion of
the interests of the military suppliers and financiers and the military
commanders which centralized supply contracting tended to separate.
However, the more typical and more damaging pressure was for a direct
role in central government: this could be through the informal contacts
and connections that would be gained from access to ministers and
courtiers in the process of negotiating contracts, or through a subsequent
institionalizing of their position by assuming administrative functions
and offices. A cause of confusion in this period, which has encouraged
mistaken assumptions about the penetration of state bureaucracy into the
armed forces, is to miss the point that all of the apparently formal-
sounding titles – General/Obrist-Proviantmeister, munitionnaire-général, pro-
veedor general de víveres, factor general – were either administrative offices
purchased by the contractors, or honorific titles granted to financiers and
suppliers who had made such contracts. They tell us more about the
privatization of the administrative activities of the state than the progress
of bureaucratic encroachment on the activities of the private contractors.
Where states such as France had developed an extensive administration
based on purchasable office, the twin roles of military supplier and gov-
ernment administrator could be combined especially easily and publicly.
Debts owed by the crown on provisioning contracts could be commuted
or bargained into the purchase of office, and office which almost inevitably
either concerned the supervision of military supply, or lay at the heart of
the financial administration, and therefore dealt directly with the payment
or reimbursement of military contractors.
François Sabathier, who was granted a nine-year lease in 1634 to provide
saltpetre and to manufacture gunpowder for the French armies, consis-
tently pulled strings in central government to try to build his lease into a
monopoly, although his record of supplying the armies was patchy and
elicited widespread complaints from senior officers. Although the implied
benefit of relying on a major operator like Sabathier was to ensure France
was self-sufficient in gunpowder, his regular failure to meet stipulated out-
puts meant that large quantities of foreign powder still needed to be
imported through the later 1630s.106 Moreover Sabathier’s ambitions and
influence extended from supplying war to financing it, and in 1636 he and
his business partners offered to waive a debt of 800,000 livres for supply of
munitions in return for the two highly lucrative offices of trésoriers de
l’extraordinaire des guerres, in effect the paymasters of the army. Refused on
this occasion, in 1638 Sabathier used his connections and leverage to
acquire the office of the trésorier of the parties casuelles, with a huge financial
interest in the sale of offices in the financial and judicial administrations.
Now on the inside track for opportunities to obtain lucrative contracts to
State administration and private supplier contracts 227
lend money to the crown, Sabathier had also become financially overex-
posed with outstanding loans totalling 9 million livres by 1640. His com-
bined exercise of the roles of munitions supplier/manufacturer and crown
financier had produced a disastrously unstable situation in which his loom-
ing bankruptcy threatened a complete breakdown in the supply of gunpow-
der to the armies. Desperate attempts to shore up his position and to hold
off his creditors were driven by fear for the armies in the face of the collapse
of his activities, and were an indictment of arrangements which had in
practice brought benefit to no one except Sabathier and those of his sup-
porters and financial backers in Richelieu’s ministry.107
Even where there was no formal venality of administrative office, a
tendency for overlap between government and contractors was an inevi-
table consequence of a powerful military-supply interest which had strong
personal and business ties to government. In the United Provinces a large
numbers of the councillors on the Boards of the Admiralties, who formu-
lated, funded and administered naval policy, had begun their careers as
contractors for ship provisioning and shipbuilding, and almost all contin-
ued to maintain strong financial interests in provisioning and mercantile
activities. This meant, for example, that the councillor to the Rotterdam
Admiralty, Joost van Coulster, could demand priority payment on his
contract to provide beer to the navy, and even more typically the councillors
would give priority to the hiring out of their own ships for Admiralty use.108
Supply contractors might thus appear to be exploiting supine admin-
istrations, too ready to grant over-advantageous contracts to friends and
associates. But there was another side to the coin. The real problem for all
those prepared to enter into military contracting with European states was
the latter’s chronic lack of creditworthiness throughout the sixteenth and
seventeenth centuries.109 One good reason why such contractors sought
to extend their role into the state’s administration and to build up their
connections and dealings with elements of central government was the
simple recognition that rulers were extremely bad creditors. Most states
were encumbered with long-term debts, the servicing of which claimed a
large part of current income. A second-rank principality like Saxony
had seen its long-term debt rise from 1.6 million florins in the 1550s
to 5.4 million in 1621; this was dwarfed by the debts of the Austrian
Habsburg monarchy, which stood at 32 million florins by 1612.110 For
most European states, the Thirty Years War began under the shadow of
debts which made access to further credit a complex process that would
usually involve hard bargaining and high rates of interest. Worse, most of
these states possessed fiscal systems which either explicitly, through the
requirement of negotiating taxes with powerful Diets or Estates, or implic-
itly, through the entrenched power of privileged and tax-exempt ruling
228 The business of war
de Witte is the best known of these relationships in the Thirty Years War.
The success of Wallenstein’s entire military system during his first general-
ship depended explicitly on the extraordinarily close ties with de Witte, and
through de Witte, with a vast, international web of financiers, merchants and
suppliers. Wallenstein and de Witte first met as fellow members of the
coinage consortium set up to debase the Bohemian currency in the aftermath
of the rebel defeat.117 Their experience of the windfall profits to be made
from the exploitation of reconquered Bohemia created a shared understand-
ing of the potential that Wallenstein’s project offered for the funding of a
gigantic army through punitive contributions levied across an ever-widening
arc of German territories. His confidence in the viability of Wallenstein’s
system underpinned de Witte’s extraordinary mobilization of financial
credit, and the contracting, purchase and distribution of armaments, muni-
tions and foodstuffs.118 When confronted with the mounting resistance to
heavy contribution demands, de Witte’s warning of the dangers of allowing
the flow of payments to slacken off were recognized by Wallenstein, although
by 1629 the problems of resistance had become too widespread to permit any
solution.119 The Emperor’s dismissal of his Generalissimo in August 1630
predictably brought the whole edifice of borrowing and contracting on credit
crashing down, and led to de Witte’s suicide a few weeks later. But without
him Wallenstein’s huge system could never have taken off, and he would
never have gained his reputation as a master of the detail of military logistics.
Equally, though, without de Witte’s own profound, and ultimately mis-
judged, confidence in Wallenstein, his own capacity and willingness to
mobilize finance and resources would have been incomparably more limited.
Wallenstein’s business relationship with de Witte was far from unique,
and many other enterpriser-commanders of the period managed to achieve
similar, close partnerships with figures who, though often financiers,
extended their activities as provisioners, coordinators of supply operations
and intermediaries in acquiring arms and munitions. The working relation-
ship between Bernhard von Saxe-Weimar and Marx Conrad Rehlinger had
begun at the time of the Augsburg financier’s involvement with Gustavus
Adolphus and Axel Oxenstierna. Rehlinger had been prosecuted by the
Imperial authorities for his support for the Protestant cause in the 1620s and
had gone into exile in Switzerland, from where he gave financial support to
the Swedes, while his two sons held commands in Gustavus’ army.120 The
connection between Rehlinger and Saxe-Weimar, which followed the
duke’s establishment of an independent army after the defeat at
Nördlingen, proved far closer. It was money and supplies tirelessly
assembled on credit by Rehlinger at Basle and Schaffhausen, and shipped
down the Rhine to Saxe-Weimar’s army, which made possible the capture
of Breisach in 1638 (see p. 176). Moreover, because a significant part of
232 The business of war
Electorate
of Saxony
Elb
e Friedland (Frydiant)
r
Ije
(Liberec)
Aussig Leipa n
lze Wallenstein’s Duchy
(Ústí nad Po
Labem) of Friedland Hohenelbe (Vrchlabi)
Arnsdorf (Arnultovice)
Elb Kingdom of
e Arnau Bohemia
(Hostinné)
Gradlitz
Jitschin (Jic̆in) (Choustníkovo
Hradis
Hradis̆tĕ)
Iser
Hor̆itz Neustadt
(Nové Mĕsto
Kingdom of Bohemia
nad Metují)
Metuj
Mo
Königgrätz
ldau
(Hradec Kralove)
Prague
20 miles
20 kms
crucial importance to all this activity, Friedland was well placed for the
eastern river arteries, and munitions, weapons and grain could be trans-
ported from the port of Aussig down the Elbe as far as Dessau or
Hamburg, where they would be unloaded from barges and transported to
Mecklenburg, Holstein, Stralsund or wherever the army was present in
236 The business of war
the late 1620s. In one sense the enterprises established in the duchy should
not be seen as strictly ‘industrialized’: the producers were not a homoge-
nous labour force under a single, centralized management; rather they
remained agglomerations of individual craftsmen and their workshops.
But they had been brought together, often in shared physical space, in
Raspenau or Reichenberg, to meet production targets set by Wallenstein
for prices that he had determined, and with the assumption that the
military demand of the army would be a permanent source of employment
for them.136
Friedland was Wallenstein’s uniquely personal achievement. It
undoubtedly gave him more flexibility in both meeting the needs of the
army and managing a precarious edifice of credit and revenue anticipa-
tions. In its relationship with the army it might be seen as an early example
of a ‘military-industrial complex’, albeit singular in that army procure-
ment and industrial supply were directly controlled by one and the same
person. And as its complete collapse after his assassination and the dis-
membering of his confiscated duchy was to demonstrate, it was not strictly
necessary to ensure effective army supply: reliance on decentralized pri-
vate suppliers via capable financial and mercantile agents continued to
deliver results. Indeed, Wallenstein’s Friedland system was to some
extent a creation required to mitigate some of the self-generated problems
of supplying his own, unprecedentedly large armies, and was especially
suited to the particular circumstances in which two such armies had been
recruited from scratch in a matter of months in 1625–6 and 1630–1.
If there was a comparable agglomeration of privately owned production
capacity in the same period, albeit under the control of a consortium
rather than an individual, then the network of iron and copper mines
and furnaces, iron foundries and artillery manufacturing that Louis de
Geer financed in Sweden was the nearest equivalent. From the early
1620s the expansion of Swedish iron mining and production, above all
in the crucial context of armaments manufacturing, had been contracted
by the crown to private enterprisers. Initially the largest contracts for
control of armaments manufacturing were with the Liègois de Besche
family, who gained control of the ironworks at Nora, Lindesberg and
Österby.137 But this period of control by the de Besche family interests
quickly gave way to the capital and expertise of their hitherto junior
partner, Louis de Geer. Though originally also from Liège, the family’s
move to Amsterdam and their close business and marital association with
the Trip family of munitions dealers gave them access to resources and
financial potential far beyond their original reach. With the willing sup-
port of the crown, armaments manufacturing – from iron mining to bulk
export – was handed over to a Dutch business monopoly and based on
Military contractors and private suppliers 237
Gefle
Falun
Location of Väsland Leufsta
agents/representatives
Dannemora Forsmark
Copper mine
Öregrund
Iron mine
Avesta
Foundries of
factories owned Upsala
or rented by de Geer Torshälla Norrtälje
or Trip Flögfors
Västerås
Finnåker
Arboga
Jäder Stålboga Stockholm
Olösa Aker
Örebro Nakka
Björnedam
Julita
Bruk Skeppsta
Södertälje
Hällestad
Nyköping
Finspäng Sjösa
Fada Bränn Ekeby
Vänga
Nälvekvarn
Vänersborg
Linköping Fiskeby
Nörrkoping
Västerik
Göteborg Jönköping
huge financial investment via the partnership of de Geer himself and his
brother-in-law, Elias Trip.138 While attempts to encourage investment
from within Sweden itself had produced minimal sums, by 1626 the Dutch
consortium had already committed over 400,000 guilders.139 Although
disagreements with Gustavus Adolphus over de Geer’s aggressive market-
ing of Swedish iron cannon abroad led to the formal termination of the
monopoly agreement in 1631, in reality the Dutch association’s domi-
nance of Swedish armaments continued unchecked.140 The main arms-
producing areas were dominated by private manufacturing plants owned
and operated by de Geer on behalf of capital provided by his own family
resources, the Trip family and other Dutch financiers, and produced a
comprehensive range of weapons and munitions from heavy artillery
through to iron cannon-balls.141 The range of interests extended to
brass production, saltpetre and shipbuilding.142 Though not an arma-
ments monopoly, it was an extraordinary concentration of capital, skilled
Fig. 5.5 Hendrick Trip’s cannon foundry at Julitha Bruk, Södermanland, Sweden
Military contractors and private suppliers 239
But the relationship had another side. Given the quantities of European
capital available for investment, and the general unreliability of most rulers
and their governments as borrowers, the military enterpriser could offer a
more attractive financial proposition for financiers with capital to invest.
Unlike the state, the military enterpriser did not usually seek to borrow
money while already encumbered with long-term debts attached to his
potential income. Moreover the enterprisers’ chief means of realizing capi-
tal, direct access to money raised as contributions, for the most part looked
more attractive than most sources of normal state revenues.154 This was not
inevitably the case: some state revenues, such as farms on indirect taxes or
loans against the Spanish silver shipments, continued to attract ready capital
and competitive bids to lend money. Moreover some contributions systems,
notably Wallenstein’s and de Witte’s vast edifice of deficit finance, proved
disastrously over-ambitious in the medium term. But in general, heavy but
sustainable levels of direct war taxes, extracted under threat of military force
and in large part received directly by the military commanders who had
borrowed money or negotiated supply contracts on anticipated income from
these contributions, looked more attractive to creditors than most typical
early seventeenth-century state revenue systems, crippled by inefficiency
and corruption in collection, and handicapped by networks of privilege
and protection.
occasion profits from looting could transform the economic and social
status of the officer. Aldringen and Gallas’ three-day plunder of the city of
Mantua in 1630 allowed them to take possession of the ducal palace with
its entire contents, estimated to have a value of 18 million scudi.165 Gallas’
profits from the sack were to supply the capital which, supplemented by
the transferred Bohemian estates he received for his part in the elimination
of Wallenstein, was to provide the basis of his family’s elevation into the
great Bohemian nobility for the next three hundred years.166 In early 1647
Karl Gustav Wrangel was able to combine operations to weaken Imperial
forces in southern Germany with the opportunity to capture and loot the
city of Bregenz, of limited strategic value, but known to be a fortified
centre in which large amounts of money and goods had been deposited
from all over the surrounding area. The capture of Bregenz netted some
2 million gulden in hidden goods in the town and another 4 million in
ships laden with valuables that had been unable to get out of the lake
harbour, a large portion of which helped to consolidate Wrangel’s already
growing fortune from military enterprise.167
Such transformative profits from successful plundering or looting were a
significant factor in building the fortunes of some of the commanders over
and above any ‘regular’ income, while at a lesser but still significant level
they extended down to individual officer-proprietors, as to the individual
ships’ captains engaged in privateering or with-profit involvement in a naval
operation. But in general they were probably more important in reinforcing
a general climate of expectancy and enthusiasm for service, especially
service which naval and military enterprisers would probably need to fund
on their own account.168 Booty had always been a major inducement to
involvement in warfare, and at all levels of military service, but it was
especially important in an army based upon the capacity of proprietors to
raise private financial credit to recruit and sustain their units. One obvious
factor in the conspicuous consumption of colonels and higher officers in all
the armies of this period – the quantities of silver plate, jewellery, costly
clothing and furniture which they carried in their suite – was precisely its
capacity to maintain a confident façade of wealth and creditworthiness.169
For many officers this was indeed a façade. While involvement in
military enterprise in the right circumstances could appear an attractive
financial investment opportunity, the reality was often less profitable.
Money from a regular flow of contributions and from quartering arrange-
ments that might accord a colonel four times his already generous
monthly salary in return for rearming and recruiting his regiment up to
strength, might suggest a huge return on the initial investment. Yet these
extremely generous financial arrangements could simply reflect favour-
able but transient military-political circumstances, for example, the
For gold or honour? Military enterprisers’ motivation 245
at Dunkirk had to move slowly through the list of prizes, ascertaining own-
ership, hearing appeals, and finally ensuring that the appropriate deductions
were made from the sale prices paid before the money was handed over to
the captains.172 Adrien van der Walle, the largest of the Dunkirk armateurs,
had funded eighteen privateering ships in 1623, twelve the following year,
and was said to have paid 100,000 florins to the crown as 10 per cent of the
value of his prizes. Yet he died almost completely ruined in 1633, by that
time able to finance only one ship.173 Adrien’s son, Jacques van der Walle,
diversified his commercial activities, relying as much on trade as on privat-
eering to recover the family fortunes.174
Similar risk factors and difficulties of capital accumulation were evident on
land. While some officers did spectacularly well from the manipulation of
their military skills, deployment of credit and good fortune, this was by no
means inevitable. An element that is easily overlooked is the level of mana-
gerial skill and effort that was required to run a regiment as a business
concern, whether put in by the colonel in person, or by carefully chosen
and competent subordinates. This went hand-in-hand with direct, per-
sonal leadership in reinforcing the authority of the junior officers and
forestalling problems and disputes. Melchior von Hatzfeld can be seen
as the model of the hard-working, efficient regimental officer, subse-
quently staff officer and field marshal; he can be contrasted with the
young colonel Jakob Hannibal II von Hohenems, who levied a new regi-
ment in Upper Germany during the course of 1621 to serve under Spinola
in the Army of Flanders. The 13,000 florins required for levying and
equipping the unit had been lent to him by family and local sources, but
despite this liability he seems to have made minimal provision for the
establishment of capable subordinates or any system of good management
in the regiment, and he himself left the army to spend time in Germany
during the winter of 1621/2. When he returned to Brussels in the middle of
April 1622, Jakob Hannibal found that his regiment had been disbanded
nine days previously after months of indiscipline and high levels of deser-
tion, aggravated by the absence of senior officers. A ferocious letter from
his father left Jakob in no doubt that this was his own responsibility, and the
dismissive final remark that ‘what has been lost will not be regained, and
you have saddled yourself with a burden of debt that you will never be able
to repay’, was doubtless the fate of many other would-be colonels.175
For contractors the highest-risk activity was, for both commanders and
individual colonels, involvement in military ventures entirely at their own
expense – without a regular financial injection of subsidy and support.
The dangers here were obvious: money was advanced or borrowed to raise
regiments, purchase equipment and supplies, and the only way that this
could be repaid without some sort of subsidy from a sponsoring power was
For gold or honour? Military enterprisers’ motivation 247
than investors, and adjusted their own salaries and financial arrangements
accordingly.178 Beyond the traditional profit-making benefit of being able
to recruit their own men more cheaply than for the agreed price specified
in the contract, there was for them little scope for profiting from the
‘business of the regiment’, or from handling large sums from contribu-
tions or quartering. An initial capital investment did not seem to be within
reach of such colonels and consequently opportunities for systematic,
large-scale reimbursement of regimental costs did not arise.
Many of the Scots involved in service with the Danes, then with the
Swedes, certainly held a similar, traditional view of their contractual relation-
ship with the warlord. Even when they were prepared to cover some of the
initial costs of recruitment, they expected rapid reimbursement for the
immediate expense, rather than seeing themselves as long-term stakeholders
in the military-financial fortunes of the Swedish monarchy.179 Colonel
Robert Monro, for example, seems to have made no money at all from his
years of Danish and Swedish service which began in 1626: he returned to
Scotland in 1637 with a commission to recruit his regiment up to strength,
but then became involved in the Covenanting rebellion against Charles I, a
new direction to his military career which was ultimately to take him to
Ireland as lieutenant general of the army sent to repress the revolt.180
Colonel John Hepburn left Swedish service after a dispute in 1632, but had
no proprietary claim on the regiment that he had commanded in that army,
which was transferred to the aforesaid Robert Monro. It was rumoured that
James Ramsay had made a vast fortune of 900,000 talers from his governor-
ship of Hanau in the early 1630s, but at the time of his death after the loss of
the city his relatives were pressing the Swedish government for compensation
of 50,000 riksdalers, suggesting that his fortune may have been altogether
more modest.181 It might be added that the beginnings of the British civil
wars led a large number of Scots colonels and their regiments to return to the
British Isles at the very point, the first half of the 1640s, when the tide of war
was turning in favour of the Swedish armies and those colonels who had
invested heavily in their units and the Swedish military enterprise were likely
to see large-scale returns, culminating in the satisfactio of 1648.
Acting as a military enterpriser involved financial risks as it also involved
obvious personal, physical risk. Colonels, and indeed commanding officers,
were not distant figures, managing their regiments or armies from a safe
remove. Personal leadership meant personal hazard, and even in a world
typically characterized by high levels of mortality and of interpersonal
violence, the chances of death, injury or capture in pursuit of the business
of war were significant. Amongst senior commanders, Tilly, Gustavus
Adolphus, Pappenheim, Piet Heyn the admiral of the Dutch West India
Company, Mercy, Holzapfel, Guébriant, Richelieu’s admiral, Maillé-
Social ambition 249
Social ambition
The obvious response requires us to understand military enterprise as a
social and cultural phenomenon, not simply as an exercise in profit-making.
Moreover, as has been hinted in both this and the previous chapter, the
ability to satisfy social aspirations is one of its greatest strengths in mobilizing
capital, resources and effort, and in delivering military results beyond any
that war seen purely as financial/economic business would have yielded.
That military enterprise is about more than just financial calculation can be
seen right at the summit of the system: Fritz Redlich put the case directly and
forcefully when discussing the career of Wallenstein. Why should someone
who had managed to build up a vast fortune by essentially political means
immediately after the Bohemian revolt – through territorial confiscations,
loans to the Emperor, participation in the currency devaluation – have
became so heavily involved in military enterprise? What was the real attrac-
tion of this risky form of business activity, when we are dealing with a figure
already so well placed within the highest reaches of the political establish-
ment that other, safer options were easily available to him?184 If Wallenstein
had wanted to become the most powerful territorial prince in Bohemia with
considerable political weight at the court in Vienna, he could have achieved
this by traditional patterns of aristocratic accumulation and exploitation.
In the case of Wallenstein, as with the vast majority of those who chose to
commit capital, organizational resources and their persons to the risks of
military enterprise, the most direct answer to the question is social
250 The business of war
fast-tracked his career: he passed into the Liga army, was appointed
lieutenant colonel, and rapidly, in part thanks to profits from his military
activities, gained his own regiment. Wallenstein gave him the second
major opportunity of his career, by offering him the post of general in
the Imperial army in January 1629. From 1634, when he was one of the
leading conspiritors in the elimination of Wallenstein and went on to serve
as acting commander of the Imperial troops at Nördlingen, his social
ascent never faltered. Despite a military record characterized by medioc-
rity and incompetence, he established himself as a favourite and adviser at
the Viennese court under Ferdinand III. His vast profits from the sack of
Mantua and the substantial Bohemian estates he received in 1634 pro-
vided him with the economic base, and his court connections the social
nexus, from which he could ensure that his family were positioned
amongst the aristocracy of the central European Habsburg lands.191
Similar biographical accounts could be provided for many of the military
commanders who used the war to advance their families up through the
ranks of the noble hierarchy in a way that would normally have required
several generations of state service, land purchases and marital politics.192
Nor was this restricted to those already titled. On the supply side of war,
numbers of already wealthy merchants and financiers could see social
opportunities in supplying military needs, whether directly to the state or
indirectly to its military agents. The Spaniard Martin de Arana accepted a
contract to build six galleons for Philip IV in 1625 at a price that would
involve financial loss to himself, but saw this in the wider context of social
preferment for his family. For in return he received the military governor-
ship of Santander for himself and, more important for the social aspira-
tions of the family, a knighthood in the military Order of Santiago for his
son.193 Hans de Witte’s commercial acumen would probably have served
him better – or at least longer – had he involved himself in, say, the
Hamburg–Mediterranean trade, but his social aspirations would be sat-
isfied far more comprehensively – gaining both titles and status at court –
through his close involvement with Wallenstein.194
Cultural validation
As with Wallenstein, other instances can be found of men who had no
obvious financial need to became involved in military contracting. The
great Augsburg banking houses of Fugger and Rehlinger established family
members as colonels or senior officers. At least three Fugger served in the
Bavarian army during the Thirty Years War. Marx Conrad Rehlinger’s two
sons who served as colonels in the Swedish Protestant army were no less
part of a larger family tradition: as recently as 1622, Mathäus Rehlinger had
252 The business of war
Such men were fully aware that they were actors both in front of their
immediate audience of commanders and other officers, and in the eyes of
a public of all those who shared the common set of educational and cultural
assumptions about values associated with military leadership. The great
majority of published tracts and manuals on the art of war identify and
prescribe the qualities required of the ‘perfect captain’, while extensive and
widely disseminated narrative accounts of military campaigns, such as Peter
Abaline’s Theatrum Europaeum, continued to describe and discuss battles
and other military engagements in terms of the feats and leadership of
military commanders.204 These assumptions may help to explain the extra-
ordinary, reckless courage of commanders such as Pappenheim or Ottavio
Piccolomini on the battlefield, going far beyond any reasonable expectations
of military leadership.205 Pappenheim’s self-presentation – his claim to
recognition and status – was based on this reputation for military success
achieved through reckless leadership and personal bravery. His letters to
Wallenstein were finely crafted acts of self-presentation which, while never
directly questioning his ultimate subordination to the Generalissimo, pro-
moted his personal and, in his view, vital contribution to the Imperial war
effort.206 Pappenheim was an excellent example of traditional, lesser nobility
projected into high status through his military abilities, even if his death at
Lützen prevented him cashing in his accumulated social capital.
As striking, however, are the large numbers of those colonels and
commanders who already possessed princely status, for whom military
enterprise also held strong attractions. If Pappenheim needed to prove
himself, Ottavio Piccolomini-Pieri was already from an established and
distinguished princely family, as was Marquis Annibale Gonzaga, or
Georg von Braunschweig-Lüneburg, and his son, Johann-Friedrich.
Many of these men had imposing titles, but little to support this claim to
social pre-eminence. The progressive abandonment of partible inheri-
tance by many German and Italian princely families in the sixteenth
century, in favour of territorial consolidation under inheritance by primo-
geniture, may well have been a significant factor driving military enter-
prise. Numerous second and third sons served in the armies of the
Emperor, Sweden or Spain, men who would receive a pittance from
family lands which had been settled on their elder brother – enough
perhaps to set themselves up as colonel-proprietors. Even more impor-
tantly, they were well aware of the gap between their princely titles and
their actual standing and importance in a social and political context. The
key factor for such figures was not just that military service as enterprisers
offered them, with luck, the possibility of transforming their financial
prospects, but that they would be able to deploy the cultural values and
associations of military command to build a reputation and achieve
254 The business of war
external validation. For many of these colonels who were younger sons or
members of minor cadet branches of princely families, the ambitions were
primarily those of status recognition, gaining the attention of key power-
brokers, the respect of peers. Franz Albrecht von Sachsen-Lauenberg’s
concern to obtain approval and validation from Wallenstein seems almost
obsessive, and led him into frenetic and expensive activity to ensure that
his first regiment was better recruited and better equipped than any of the
others in the army.207 When he failed to meet the expectation that he
would set his second regiment in order as quickly and lavishly, his letters
shows that he was mortified – almost paralysed – by the prospect of ‘losing
credit’ with Wallenstein.208 For a figure like Annibale Gonzaga, sixth son
of the prince of Bozzolo – a cadet line ruling over a few dozen square
kilometres enclaved within the main Gonzaga duchy in north Italy – a
regimental command in the Imperial army, promotion and recognition of
services was the means to bring himself to the attention of the great.209
Such service was the particular métier of the Gonzaga: one of Annibale’s
elder brothers, Federico, was colonel of a German unit in the Army of
Flanders, while another, Alfonso, marquis of Pomaro, raised two regi-
ments for the French army in 1637.210 In all these cases it offered the
possibility of achieving what their ancestors from the other minor princi-
palities of Sabbioneta and Guastalla gained in the later sixteenth century:
no great territorial aggrandizement, but high status and offices at the
courts of Vienna and Madrid, recognition of status through titles and
access to the powerful at a level far higher than cadet princely status could
otherwise bring them (see p. 46). These were figures who in the course of
their military activities would frequently be presented with the choice
between straightforward capital accumulation from the profits of regi-
mental management or access to contributions, or cultural and social
self-fashioning through extravagant gestures in raising and maintaining
their troops or sustaining an impressive entourage and living extravagantly
within the army.211 In many cases they were likely to choose the latter,
probably to the material benefit of the army of the warlord.212
War remained a business, but engaging in it, far from threatening loss of
social status – the dérogeance attached to much commercial activity –
positively facilitated the assertion and fulfilment of social and cultural
ambitions. All of the triumphalism of martial imagery could be deployed
to reinforce the status of those engaged in military command, whether
they had themselves depicted dressed in full armour, or in stylized eques-
trian portraits which conveyed both a control of the surrounding battle-
field and an implied discipline and mastery of their own persons
symbolized by the perfectly controlled warhorse. A paradigm of such
self-representation can be seen in the painting of the Swedish Field
Cultural validation 255
Fig. 5.10 The painted ceiling of the main salon of the Trip House,
Amsterdam
The demobilization of the armies of the Thirty Years War during 1649
and 1650 allowed rulers to take stock of what had been an evolutionary
process in the management and operations of their armed forces. Large-
scale warfare waged for an unprecedented, continuous duration had
presented an organizational and financial challenge which swept away
the notion that armed forces could be raised and funded exclusively
through the state and its administrators. The various initiatives to bring
private investment into the organization and financing of war certainly
had not proved uniformly successful, but nor was it the case that the
co-option of private resources had been a disastrous failure. Indeed,
it would have been impossible to wage war on this scale and over this
time-scale on the basis of the resources – manpower, provisions and
finance – that could be mobilized or extracted by early seventeenth-
century governments and their direct agents. The better credit of the
private sector, its greater technical and organizational know-how, and
the access to international networks for raising resources, capital and
manpower, far outweighed anything that a state administration could
have hoped to achieve. The ability of the belligerents to protract the
Thirty Years War over decades of successive campaigns was a human
and material disaster. But it is important to recognize that the duration of
the war was not simply a consequence of military stagnation, a dismal and
universal failure of organization and strategic potential. To a large extent it
was the effectiveness and adaptability of their outsourced military organ-
izations which allowed the belligerents to continue waging war, to over-
come individual military disasters, and to stave off the prospect of
surrender on entirely unacceptable terms.
There were thus good reasons to think that for many European rulers
the organization and deployment of military force after 1650 would rest
upon the further development and refinement of various forms of public–
private partnership: they and their governments would continue to control
and finance some aspects of a military system, but would also seek to
involve the credit and the organizational resources of their subjects or of
260
The representation of seventeenth-century warfare 261
Hannibal, punished faults severely, but also rewarded good service gen-
erously. He brought the appropriate princely combination of distance and
magnificence to his actions and behaviour, but also took pains over the
welfare of his troops. Wallenstein is slotted into the well-established
rhetorical formula of the ‘Perfect Captain’, who uses his authority to
encourage devotion amongst his officers and respect from his men.2
What is absent from the account is any description of Wallenstein as
general contractor, the great ‘entrepreneur of war’. He is certainly
described as using ‘sue proprie spese’ – his own money – to raise regi-
ments, and ultimately to raise an entire army of 40,000 men. But this is
presented as a courtly strategem by a mercurial and wealthy aristocrat – a
means to seize the attention and gain the trust of his overlord, the
Emperor.3 Of the wider issues of ‘military devolution’, the huge structures
of credit, supply and subcontract on which Wallenstein’s military system
rested, there is no trace in Priorato’s account. Wallenstein’s life offers a
dramatic and tragic account of a nobleman who rises to the highest
princely status through gaining the favour of the Emperor, and is betrayed
twice by the latter’s dynastic ambitions – a fitting subject for a series of
reflections on glory, success, and the mutability of fortune. Priorato’s
biography of Wallenstein is far from historically worthless: he makes
shrewd points about Wallenstein’s attritional strategies and his aim of
overwhelming his enemies by numerical superiority; about his refusal to
accept worthless nominees to military office; about his ability to inspire
extraordinary loyalty from talented subordinates. But the basic facts about
military enterprise as a vast system of financial speculation secured against
the exaction of contributions and other income streams are entirely
excised from the account.
This would appear to be characteristic of writing on the art of war
throughout the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries.4 The vast number
of treatises on the ‘perfect captain’, the ‘management of arms’, the lives of
great commanders, make no allusion to the central aspect of military
organization and practice in the period. Mercenaries are discussed, but
they are confined to their traditionally defined role of (foreign) soldiers
raised and serving the ruler for regular pay within a traditional structure of
a royal or princely army. Even Raimondo Montecuccoli’s Trattato della
Guerra, drafted while in Swedish captivity in 1641 and full of references to
the contemporary war, offers a chapter on ‘preparations for war’ which is
clear sighted about the need for money in all areas of raising and support-
ing troops, but nowhere refers to the role of private contractors.5
Unsurprisingly, the majority of treatises declare that the prince’s own
subjects are superior to mercenaries, although there are a few dissenting
voices. Girolamo Frachetta’s Il Prencipe asserts that there may be
The representation of seventeenth-century warfare 263
capital, and thus a statement in bricks and mortar of the sovereign pre-
tensions of the ruler.9 But a vitally important series of marks of sovereignty
lay in the right to determine peace or war, to make alliances and to engage
or disengage with other states without external constraint. All of these
required control of the instruments of waging war – whether these were
citadels and fortresses emblazoned with the arms of the prince, or com-
mand and control of the armies and navies through which his military
power was projected abroad. Reliance on such marks of sovereignty did
nothing to eliminate conflicts. The hotly disputed right to determine their
own foreign policy and to make war on their own account was at the heart
of debates about whether the German (and the Italian) princes of the Holy
Roman Empire possessed outright or mediated sovereignty.10
If the direct exercise of military command, whether over subject troops
or indeed over hired forces, was deployed as a mark of sovereignty, the
delegation of even a part of such military authority to a contractor might
call into question the sovereignty of the delegating agent. Though the
ruler had full authority in theory to delegate both military and civil
functions, he might prove particularly reluctant to concede the former.
When the Council of State in Castile spoke of the shame and dangers of
relying on asiento they had in mind the perception of the crown’s sover-
eignty and its reputation.11 An idealized military hierarchy in which high-
born subjects subordinated themselves to the ruler’s authority in order to
command the ruler’s troops provided a more comfortable working out of
the implications of sovereign authority, and this idealization was what
early modern military writings assumed.
Rulers’ concerns to play down the implicit challenge to sovereignty
posed by the reality of warfare were neatly complemented by concerns
amongst the military contractors themselves. As indicated at the end of
Chapter 5, for many of those involved as military proprietors, financial
return was by no means the only motive for their involvement in contract-
ing. Investment in setting up a regiment was also an investment in the
social prestige of military service, and this would be debased if it were
overtly discussed in terms of monetary investment and capital returns.
It was akin to the more venerable presentation of war in terms of chivalry
and knightly values as the means to uphold and validate the idealized
culture and social prestige of a militarized nobility. Both sought to re-
inforce ideas of social status and hierarchy attainable through the disin-
terested pursuit of warfare as a vocation. Neither princes nor military
contractors wished to draw out the implications of war as a business or
trade, dominated by colonels who were more obviously shareholder-
investors than ‘perfect captains’. Neither would have cared much for
publications on the art of war purporting to describe the duties and role
266 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
French exceptionalism
However, not all states had emerged from the experience of early modern
warfare down to 1650 with the perception that military enterprise had
provided a means to resolve some of the financial and organizational
dilemmas of warfare. By far the most important of these exceptions, the
state which was to draw attention to the gap between military theory and
reality and was to shape a different and widely imitated public/private
military paradigm, was France.
Although France’s hiring of foreign mercenaries in the first half of
the sixteenth century had been exceptional only in its vast scale, the
Wars of Religion transformed the attitude of the crown and its central
administration towards the organization and control of military force
(see pp. 87–8). To a greater extent than anywhere else in Europe military
devolution in France was identified by the crown and successive govern-
ments with self-assertive noble power and confessional separatism. Thus
while other European powers from the early seventeenth century saw
military devolution as a potential means to deploy private credit through
a military partnership, in France it represented a return to political
anarchy in which at various points the survival of both the crown and the
French exceptionalism 267
European war in 1635 than could other European rulers. Harnessing the
credit of serving officers was, for France, no less than for the Empire or for
Sweden, the only way to make large-scale, long-duration war viable. This
imperative to find ways to draw on the credit and financial resources of
wealthy subjects, while, as a point of principle, simultaneously rejecting
overt military enterprise with its recognition of the officers’ proprietary
status, produced a deeply unsatisfactory compromise unique to France.
The typical French unit or army commander was placed under intense
pressure to commit his own funds to the recruitment and upkeep of units,
without receiving any of the benefits of outright proprietorship which
would have been the case had he been serving in a contract army.
Acquiring a commission as a colonel or captain would very frequently
involve an informal undertaking to meet the costs of recruitment, or to
contribute substantially towards them. Once his unit was in being, the
unit commander was pressured to meet wage shortfalls, pay for food and
replace equipment under the threat of disbandment or réformation if the
unit was judged to have fallen below effective strength or to be unfit for
combat. None of these personal charges and expenses were recognized by
the crown or its administrators, for to do so would imply that the officer
held some kind of proprietary right over the unit, or at a higher level, the
army. The French elites continued to compete for military office – factors
of social prestige and noble self-identification saw to that – but aware that
it was almost impossible to undertake military service without suffering
moderate to heavy financial loss, officers were for the most part reluctant
to contemplate lengthy service or to enter into sustained financial com-
mitments. The high turnover of newly created regiments in the French
army from the 1630s to the 1650s was a reflection of the officers’ decision
to treat service as a social rite de passage, whose costs were too heavy to
sustain for more than a campaign or two. It was compounded by the
administration’s own cynical calculation that it was cheaper to hire and
disband units on what was virtually a year-to-year basis, drawing on the
initial enthusiasm and capital of a steady flow of aspiring unit officers.
Though the established infantry regiments, the vieux and the petits vieux,
were permanent entities – régiments entretenues – the individual captains
and other regimental officers were placed under similar pressure since the
constituent companies could be threatened with elimination or consol-
idation, again without compensation.17
The French crown’s principled rejection of military enterprise was one
which no other European rulers followed, even if they assumed a variety of
approaches to the issue in practice, from open discussion of contracting in
the Spanish Council to a more typical position, in which the larger issues
were simply taken for granted behind a focus on detailed practice. The
French exceptionalism 269
Following the restoration of Mazarin and the end of fighting in the heart of
France, the prince de Condé took his army, composed of regiments
commanded by his clients and noble supporters, and passed into
Spanish service in the Netherlands, where he continued his armed strug-
gle against Mazarin along the Picardy/Champagne frontier until the Peace
of the Pyrenees in 1659. During that time he was joined by a trickle of
other grandees, notably the duc de Noirmoutier, the maréchal
d’Hocquincourt and the comte de Créqui, which threatened to become
a flood after any major reverse for the French royal armies.20
French responses
The experience of the entire decade 1648–59 served to confirm the
ministerial elite in its profound hostility to the devolution of military
authority in so far as it was linked with the threats of noble and provincial
assertion. What successes they had enjoyed as a result of such devolution
into the hands of foreign contractors such as Saxe-Weimar in the 1630s
and his colonel-directors in the 1640s were overlooked in the conviction
that independent military power had posed a threat to the existence of the
state. And this was the dominant attitude when the young Louis XIV and
his ministers began the project to reaffirm royal authority from the early
1660s.
The army reforms of Louis XIV have usually been presented as the
second stage in a military revolution that had begun with the Orange-
Nassau military commanders of the Dutch Republic, and had been
revealed in its full battlefield potential by Gustavus Adolphus of
Sweden. For a time, the story runs, the revolutionary thread was lost in
the supposedly aimless, devolved confusion of the later Thirty Years War.
But it reappears triumphantly in the military and administrative reforms of
the French war ministers, Michel Le Tellier and his son, the marquis de
Louvois, who created, it is considered, the first, truly modern, state-
administered, -financed and -controlled army for Louis XIV.
Soldiers, recruited by state administrators and placed under the author-
ity of an extensive and well-structured military administration, were paid,
fed, equipped and uniformed, and were subjected to exacting standards of
military discipline, control and inspection.21 A standing, peace-time army
ensured that a good percentage of French soldiers were long-serving,
drilled in tactics and use of weaponry, and possessed an esprit de corps
both within their unit and the army at large. Equally, a large-scale perma-
nent force offered a series of rewards and sanctions with which the war
minister and his administrators could curtail the independence and
organizational abuses of the officers. Those who served in the permanent
French responses 271
guise and only on condition that the outward forms of obedience and the
language of subordination were upheld.25
Ably supported by ministers of state in their dealings with institutions
and the provinces, and by the habits which Louis XIV inculcated and
rewarded at his court, this policy sought to reassert royal sovereignty over
all key aspects of political life. The combination of symbolic gesture and
image creation, the demand for appropriate behaviour from subjects,
together with some innovation and institutional transformation, all
touched heavily upon the waging of war and the control of the armies.
In what was probably a conscious echo of Thomas Hobbes, Bishop
Bossuet, in his Politique tirées de propres paroles de l’Ecriture Sainte, argued
that in the truly godly and well-governed state, the king alone would be
armed. The implications of such a claim can be seen in the assertion of the
king’s sovereignty over the armed forces of the realm, in which there can
be no sharing of military control and authority.26 The early iconographic
identification of Louis as Apollo, god of the arts, order and harmony, was
a relatively short-lived affair compared with Louis as ‘le roi de guerre’,
whose sovereignty was wrapped in the personal assumption and control of
military activity, and of his armies.27 By the 1670s this image-building had
focused upon the representation of the king as Louis le Grand, the military
ruler who was heir to Alexander and Charlemagne, and whose military
deeds should be celebrated with the same, conventional focus on the
person and the military deeds of the ruler.28 An aspect of this with con-
siderable repercussions for the management and conduct of war was the
king’s determination to command his armies in person, and in campaigns
that should be structured to reflect the greatest possible lustre on his
control of the army and his personal role in the action.29 The immediate,
distorting effects of such personal leadership, and the related problems of
command and control when France was waging war in four or five
separate campaign theatres simultaneously, were subordinated to this
determination to act out his possession of sovereign authority.
There had been monarchs before Louis who had built their iconogra-
phy and self-image on a representation of their military skills and author-
ity. But never so comprehensively as Louis XIV, nor at a moment when it
had such repercussions for wider debate about the control of armed
forces.30 From the painted ceilings of the Galerie des Glaces at Versailles
to the language of royal edicts and ordinances, from the prologues of
Lully’s court operas to religious ceremony, the king’s sovereign status as
roi de guerre was endlessly reaffirmed.31 An extraordinary range of literary,
cultural and ceremonial rhetoric celebrating the king’s authority and
sovereignty bore down time and again on the single point of the king’s
absolute and unmediated control of his armed forces.
French responses 273
The goal for Louis and his war ministers was not some abstract ideal of a
bureaucratically administered army, but the elimination of any implica-
tion of negotiated obedience or ‘bargaining’ with the officers and other
power-brokers in the existing military structure, so that Louis’ own
authority appeared direct and unchallenged. As the French crown had
never embraced formal military devolution, an explicit rejection of dele-
gated military authority was unproblematic. The implications here of
hiring foreign troops for French military service could easily be dealt
with. General contracts with foreign military enterprisers such as that
with Saxe-Weimar had never dominated French military activity, and it
was easy to return to the hiring of individual mercenary regiments which
would be fully integrated into French armies and serve under French
command and military discipline. As a result 15–20 per cent of the
French army continued to be composed of Swiss, Irish, Scottish and
German mercenaries, but there was no sense in which the colonels were
treated as more than employees of the crown.32 Effort was even made to
eliminate some of the distinctive privileges of the Swiss mercenary con-
tingent, affirming the principle that all units served under the authority of
the king on the same terms.
The more pressing issue from the 1660s was the need to define a new
relationship with the native French officers and through them the rest of
the army. On one side, the crown and its ministers wanted to affirm the
crown’s absolute control of the army, both through the language of
military authority and in the reality of command and control. On the
other side, it was vital to find some mechanism for military organization
and funding that would be more effective than the previous, disastrous
practice of arbitrarily extorting money from colonels and corps
commanders to raise and maintain their units, while conceding no pro-
prietary rights or financial security in return. Even if the second issue was
primarily a matter of securing greater operational effectiveness, the two
were clearly related: an army in which the principal officers considered
that they were placed under unacceptable levels of financial pressure in
ways that seemed to subvert the role defined for them by the terms of their
commissions and service, would be unlikely to offer unconditional obedi-
ence to the crown, whether in practice or even in language.
If a move towards an overtly contractual, proprietorial relationship with
French unit officers might have offered them the benefits of a secured
‘investment’ in their units, this would not easily be compatible with the
new political climate of the 1660s, in which the king and his ministers
explicitly rejected anything that was suggestive of negotiation or bargaining
with subjects. The opposing model would be the establishment of an army
which was directly state-administered, state-controlled and state-funded,
274 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
where the officers were not required to commit any of their own funds,
and where they were genuinely the employees and servants of the state. If
the army was small enough, it might be possible to establish a direct
relationship between the costs of the troops and available crown revenues.
The initial post-1659 demobilization had reduced the French standing
army to a permanent force of around 55,000 men – a level at which,
arguably and at a fairly basic level, the crown might have been able to
assume the operational costs and create an employee-army. However,
from the outset of the personal rule, the king and war minister were in
no doubt that France’s future foreign policy would require large-scale
military expansion above this military core, and by the War of Devolution
in 1667, the army had already been increased to 70,000 infantry and
35,000 cavalry.33 Could the model of the directly administered, state-
funded and state-raised army remain compatible with progressive military
expansion up to a standing army of 140,000 on the eve of the Dutch War
in 1672, a wartime strength of 250,000 troops between 1672 and 1678, a
post-war standing army of 180,000 which was then built up to the highest
point of military expansion, around 340,000 troops, in the early 1690s?34
The economic history of France from the 1660s until at least a decade
after the death of Louis in 1715 should be painted in the gloomy shades
of rural depression, modest urban expansion restricted to a few large
centres, and demographic stagnation. The national resource base had
not expanded since the earlier seventeenth century, when the inability
of the crown to offer adequate support for an army which was scarcely
25 per cent of the size of that established in the 1690s had precipitated
the deluge of arbitrary financial burdens on the military officers. All of this
would make it optimistic to assume that now, in the later seventeenth
century, heavier taxation or greater efficiency gains in its collection would
somehow bridge the gap between available state funds and the ever-
increasing size and demands of the French army, not forgetting
Colbert’s navy, which had itself reached 140,000 tonnes and eighty
ships of the line by the 1680s.
Recent work on Louis XIV’s reign has demonstrated that while deploy-
ing a rhetoric of royal authority, the resources and resilience of the crown
and its central government depended in large part on its practical willing-
ness to compromise with different groups of the elites, offering them
continued privileges, concessions and benefits in return for their politi-
cal cooperation and financial commitment. It was in finding ways to
extract unprecedented financial support from those who were otherwise
exempted from the normal burdens of taxation, that the flexibility of the
regime was most evident. As the costs of ever-lengthier and larger-scale
wars continued to mount, Louis’ regime sacrificed any possibility of
French responses 275
control.49 The notion that the officer corps had been subordinated to
central government is far removed from reality.
Recognition that the shift towards a state-administered and -controlled
army was little more than skin deep is underlined in those areas of military
administration where the crown did not consider that its claims to sover-
eignty were compromised. The entire operation of food supply, arms and
munitions production, and supply for the armies continued to be put out
to contract and handled by munitionnaires and other contractors far into
the eighteenth century. These contracts were still for the most part nego-
tiated centrally on a vast scale, though the crown was considerably more
capable of honouring their financial terms, at least in the first decades of
the reign.50 Much of the business of the regiment was left to unit
commanders: the supply of clothing and other regimental and company
equipment such as standards or musical instruments; the supplementary
costs of better-quality horses in the cavalry; all of the trappings of estab-
lishing a regimental headquarters. These were devolved with a shrewd
sense that the colonel-proprietors would provide better-quality materials
than would be budgeted for via a state contract or direct provision.51 For
both Louis and Louvois, Marshal Vauban’s great chains of fortresses
along France’s frontiers were potent symbols of the king’s authority and
his status as roi de guerre, and they would not for a moment have counte-
nanced the earlier practice of contracting the upkeep of garrisons to
enterpriser-governors. However, the actual construction of these for-
tresses involved no such affront to the king’s sovereign status, and
Louvois’ correspondence with the king is full of detail of contracts with
local entrepreneurs and consortia for remodelling terrain, constructing
walls and bastions, and beautifying the sites with decorative stonework,
grass and tree-planting.52
The same division between negotiable and non-negotiable areas of
sovereignty was evident in the navy of Louis XIV. Developed by Colbert
on the principle of overt royal-ministerial control, the building and supply
of the navy was underpinned from the outset by massive contracting
with financial-mercantile elites who had private and informal connections
to Colbert and the naval administration.53 The notion of centralized,
bureaucratic control was constantly subverted by the necessary deals to
maintain the flow of finance and material resources to the navy, deals
which frequently involved granting an official role in the naval adminis-
tration to individuals whose involvement had been that of private
contractor. The roles of financier-supplier and administrator-supervisor
were thus frequently conjoined: for example, François Berthelot was
commissaire général of powder and saltpetre, and he and his family were
virtually monopoly suppliers of these goods.54 Beneath the grandiose
Beyond France 279
assertion of royal power, in which the capital ships bore titles evocative of
the Bourbon monarchy and their elaborate decoration and heavy arma-
ment symbolized royal sovereignty no less than did Vauban’s fortresses,
the navy was a creature of the financial and mercantile interests on which
Colbert and his son, Seignelay, had drawn for its construction and
maintenance.55
when states with no military resources became pawns of the active bellig-
erents. The best that could be hoped for then – and probably also in the
1650s – would be a subservient neutrality, in which the state paid heavy
contributions in return for not having to billet troops.
The dilemma of the Brandenburg Elector was simply a more direct
version of the concern of many German princely rulers about drawing on
what now appeared an increasingly unreliable, ‘last-minute’ mechanism
for raising military forces, and one that might well fail to meet its targets
altogether. It was a familiar story from other parts of Europe in earlier
periods, when the local market for hiring troops had been restricted or
overburdened. In 1606–7, when trying to raise troops for what appeared
an imminent war with Spain’s Italian territories, Venice had been forced
to stretch the net of military contracting as far as the Netherlands, and still
found itself spending very heavily to raise paltry numbers of troops.68
In this context, the notion of a permanent defence force again reap-
peared on many German rulers’ agendas. The previous, pre-1618
attempts to create conscript militias were acknowledged as failures, and
few argued for reviving such projects on any grounds except the original,
flawed one of cheapness. But if a part-time militia was dismissed as a
serious option for anything other than last-ditch home defence, then the
other means of ensuring that the ruler could have assured access to
military force was through the establishment of permanent, regular units
of troops. The exposure of their territories to military contributions
imposed by the armies of the Thirty Years War had demonstrated to
rulers that their subjects possessed far higher tax-paying capacity than
had ever been envisaged before 1618.69 But the collection of contribu-
tions, even when explicitly conceded by Diets and other representative
bodies, had been underpinned by the sanction of readily available military
force. This direct recourse to force was not available to rulers in the years
after Westphalia. Neither was the strongest argument to gain grudging
consent to these impositions, deployed, for example, with success in the
Western Circles of the Empire in the 1630s and 1640s: that the alternative
to paying these defence taxes was being overrun by enemy forces and
subjected to heavier and more capricious taxes, accompanied by wide-
spread looting and destruction.
Yet at a less immediate level the arguments about the needs of defence
could still be used, and although the revenues that would be granted by
territorial Diets and Estates were smaller than the sums extracted as
contributions in the war years, there was no going back to the minimalist
tax regimes of the pre-1618 era.70 Friedrich Wilhelm of Brandenburg led
the charge towards the creation of permanent, regular ‘defence taxes’.71 A
combination of the looming threat posed by Sweden and a backstairs deal
284 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
say, almost always a degree of personal and dynastic ambition in the desire
to create standing armies more directly accountable to the ruler, even if
the price for this was to have fewer troops than military enterprise might
have given the prince. At the very least, a princely army provided oppor-
tunities for direct courtly patronage and promotion that were unavailable
in an army raised by enterpriser-colonels. Beyond this pragmatism, two
other factors may have helped to push the balance further towards perma-
nent forces.
Although falling short of the extreme assertions of sovereignty that
Louis XIV and his ministers considered an essential aspect of his govern-
ment programme, many of the rulers of the Holy Roman Empire were
sensitive to questions of sovereignty and the control of military force. In
particular, Article 65 of the 1648 Peace of Münster specifically empha-
sized that the sovereign status of the German princes was defined by their
rights to raise armies, make alliances and decide on war and peace.76 It
was on these claims that the greater territorial princes justified their free-
dom of action from their overlord, the Emperor, and their status as
independent political actors. A defence force that was clearly under the
control of the ruler, sanctioned by taxes granted by his Estates, would
make this point about the possession of sovereignty more effectively and
explicitly than troops raised through an international system of military
enterprisers and their support networks. The success of Louis XIV’s
military experiment, and indeed the speed with which Louis achieved
pre-eminence in European politics, inevitably drew attention to his rhet-
orical claims and his elaborate posturing as the roi de guerre. A model
which had apparently proved so successful naturally found its willing
imitators.
Moreover the demonizing of the armies of the later Thirty Years War
was deliberately seized upon as a means to sell the burdens of a standing
army to subjects, and to reconcile them to higher taxes and greater author-
ity in the hands of the ruler. By playing up the supposedly anarchic, self-
seeking and universally destructive character of the armies of the 1630s
and 1640s, and especially the implication that most of the soldiers came
from outside the Empire and had no purpose within its borders except
looting and indiscriminate violence, the new, permanent forces of the
post-war rulers could be presented as guarantors of restored order and
stability. To some extent, as we shall see below, the different way in which
these troops were recruited, and the changed attitudes to military life and
its relationship to wider society, could provide some support for the
contention that these were a different style of armed force. But the
representation of the Thirty Years War as a German catastrophe, wrought
by foreign, contracted troops outside the control of rulers, civil authorities
286 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
and military commanders, pursuing war for profit at the direct expense
of the people, served the interests of German post-war rulers extremely
well. It had the incidental effect of establishing a mythology of the ‘all-
destructive war’ and the ‘all-consuming armies’ that has lasted for cen-
turies, and still colours most accounts of the Thirty Years War and its
military character down to the present.77
Thus to a large extent the German princes, and indeed their few Italian
counterparts such as Carlo Emanuele and Vittorio Amedeo II of Savoy-
Piedmont, were willing victims of their own rhetoric about the control of
military force.78 By preaching the virtues of standing armies and the direct
authority of the ruler as an antidote to military chaos, the possibility of
maintaining forces on the basis of the credit and private organization of the
military contractor would seem to be restricted much more explicitly. The
previous gap between military rhetoric and military reality was signifi-
cantly harder to ignore.
soldiers’ social status, and this was mirrored in these dramatically falling
wage levels.
Less frequently remarked, but also important as part of this package of
reducing the operating costs of a permanent army, is the disappearance of
the ‘double-pay men’, the veterans who received either a full or consider-
ably higher salary for their military experience and their key role in unit
organization and deployment.80 In future the company hierarchy was sim-
plified into a majority of ordinary soldiers and a small minority of NCOs.
The latter’s pay was better than that of a traditional double-pay man, but
their numbers were far smaller, they performed more general functions, and
they were more clearly separated from the men. The double-pay men had
been a central element in the ‘informal professionalism’ of military units in
the Landsknecht and Thirty Years War tradition, the small-group dynamic
based upon the Rott and the Rottmeister, and their disappearance was sig-
nificant as part of a larger restructuring of unit dynamics.
It might have been the case that the traditional, ‘apprenticeship’ system
of military units, recognized in these differential wages between experi-
enced soldiers and recruits, would have been unsustainable outside the
context of permanent war, given the far smaller numbers of those still
available for service with significant experience of combat. But in fact this
whole system was being challenged by the fashionable importation of the
model of rigorous, externally imposed drill and uniform practice in weap-
ons and tactical deployment. When undertaken by militias and other part-
time, quasi-informal forces, the failure of ‘revolutionary’ systems of exact
discipline, taught through the drill manual and the barrack square, was
unsurprising. To produce units which deployed their weapons and man-
oeuvred on the battlefield and under fire with perfectly synchronized
collective movements in response to a formal repertoire of orders, and
where drill and punishment had eliminated individual actions and reac-
tions from this process, took a great deal of time and effort. But permanent
armies, maintained over long periods of peace, had the time to inculcate
these formalized practices, and permanent establishments of NCOs
would have the task of teaching them. After the five to six years of regular
drill which the marquis de Chamlay had suggested was the minimum
required to train infantry soldiers (see p. 100), they would have achieved
an impressive level of collective military performance both on the parade-
ground and in combat. The principles on which these military units had
been prepared for combat were radically different from those of the Thirty
Years War: they were characterized by a shared, uniform base of drill and
rigorous subordination to instructions from above to provide cohesion in
attack and under fire, rather than the previous, balanced mix of experi-
enced and inexperienced troops held together by a common sense of esprit
288 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
greater powers.84 Faced with the massive burden on small state resources
of trying to maintain permanent military forces, the obvious way to try to
cover the costs and maintain the army without a crippling or unacceptable
tax burden was to lease out all or part of the army. Mercenary units had
been returned to the status of individual force-enhancers – a means to
raise additional troops quickly, especially when domestic recruitment was
sluggish. They were still there in the mid-eighteenth century when, noto-
riously, a high proportion of ‘British’ troops fighting anywhere from
Brunswick to Boston were Hessian mercenaries in the direct pay of the
British crown, and where the armies of Frederick the Great made equally
heavy use of Germans who were not the king’s subjects.85
The growth in the size of permanent forces and the range of military
functions over which the state took some direct responsibility also had an
impact on the size and status of central military bureaucracies. France was
by no means a unique example of this, but during the 1660s the office of
secretary of state for war was elevated to the status of war minister, with a
permanent seat in the conseil d’en haut going to Louvois in 1672.86 This
was paralleled in the growing importance of the Generalkriegskommissariat
in Brandenburg or the Hofkriegsrath in Austria.87 In all cases the number
of salaried officials grew, together with the scale and range of supervisorial
activities, and the perception of the army as being directly under the
control of the ruler and his expanding power base.88 The growth in the
scale of administrative activity connected with the armies and navies of
European powers from the later seventeenth century speaks for itself in the
exponential increase in paperwork generated and preserved in the various
state war archives, many of which were officially founded as depots for this
material in the same period.
Probably the most unambiguous practical example of the direct
increase in state control over armed force came not with land forces, but
with navies. The decisive factor here was not some ideologically motivated
decision to take direct control of navies, but a technological change in
warfare at sea, in its decisiveness akin to the role of siege artillery and the
trace italienne for fortress design back in the early sixteenth century.
Although the importance of shipborne gunnery had been steadily growing
through the sixteenth and the early seventeenth century, this remained
relatively unsystematic: heavier, ship-smashing guns, whether mounted in
the prow, stern or along the side-decks, were certainly used with the aim of
disabling an enemy vessel to permit subsequent boarding, or intimidating
a crew with firepower so that they surrendered. But there was nothing that
dictated a particular form of ship to carry such weapons, or the number
and weight of guns carried. As we have seen, throughout the first half of
the century, a substantial proportion of fleets would still be made up of
State control of military activity 291
armed merchantmen (see above pp. 83–6). This dual role lay at the heart
of the private/state conduct of naval warfare down to the 1650s, and
underwrote the willingness of shipowners and merchant captains to par-
ticipate in naval campaigns, whether deploying their vessels as acting
warships or as privateers. When rulers had built and controlled most of
their navies before the 1650s it had usually – as in the case of Denmark and
Sweden – been a reflection of the smallness and weakness of their mer-
chant fleets, rather than a deliberate decision to concentrate resources in
the hands of the state.89
The Anglo-Dutch Wars and the evolution of the line of battle had a
decisive effect on maritime technology. The shift from naval tactics that
aimed to intimidate or damage ships prior to boarding, to fleet actions
which would be decided overwhelmingly by broadside batteries of heavy
guns, was a major step in the emerging technology of warships.90 It
inaugurated fleets made up entirely of rated vessels, the firepower of
which would dictate the place they held in the fleet and their role in the
artillery duel which would characterize future naval actions. A single gun-
deck posed much less of a structural problem to the role of the ship as
cargo-carrier than did the designs for custom-built, rated warships after
1650, which from the third-rate upwards needed to be built to far higher
specifications, with the capacity to carry sixty to seventy cannon on two or
three reinforced gun-decks.91 At this battle-fleet end of the business, naval
and mercantile technology were no longer interchangeable. It simply
made no economic sense for private shipowners, who might have envis-
aged a partial military role for their previous ships, to build to the speci-
fications of a rated warship. Armed merchant ships might act as privateers
in time of war and supplement the naval activities of the main fleet, but
they would be a dangerous liability if they tried to fight as part of the main
navy. The last major sea engagement involving substantial forces which
combined purpose-built warships and hired merchant ships was at the
Listerdyb in May 1644, when Dutch armed merchantmen were heavily
outclassed by the Danish warships of Christian IV.92
European states therefore faced a simple challenge after the 1650s. If they
wanted a fleet capable of fighting in line of battle they would have to build it
and maintain it at their own expense. Heavy warships could not double as
commercial carriers and they were too costly and unfit for purpose as
privateers; the most obvious private–public funding mechanism for operat-
ing navies would no longer work. These ships would only come into
existence if the ruler was prepared to spend heavily from tax revenues to
build, arm and crew them. It was this strategic realization which underlay
Colbert’s massive naval building programme, and was felt no less forcefully
amongst all the other powers with substantial maritime pretensions.93
292 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
Fig. 6.2 A custom-built third-rate warship; contrast this with Figure 2.2
The persistence of military enterprise 293
Britain 14 33 62 55 80
France 1 45 60 68 73
Netherlands 0 32 29 30 64
Sweden 3 14 9 17 27
Denmark/Norway 6 13 15 16 30
Source: Figures taken from J. Luh, Kriegskunst in Europa, 1650–1800 (Cologne, 2004), p. 17.
The persistence of military enterprise 295
between the world of military contractors and the world of the ‘permanent
army’ breaks down once this is addressed. Both before and after 1650 the
rulers of states, whether German or Italian principalities or the greater
powers, sought means to enlist the capital, and to some extent the con-
nections and organizational resources, of their elites in the raising of
armed forces and the waging of war. The public–private military partner-
ships might vary in form and emphasis, but the underlying assumptions
remained that substantial private involvement in the organization of war
was both a practical requirement and not necessarily incompatible with
the ruler’s authority over his armed forces.
At the most basic level, in almost all armies the officers remained the
creditors of the crown, lending money to feed, clothe or pay the basic
wages of their troops when central funds and provisioning proved inad-
equate. This could take a number of forms. In some cases the senior
officers were expected or encouraged, as in the past, to lend directly to
the ruler. In the 1670s when it proved necessary to quarter the Electoral
army on Brandenburg territory over the winter months, the colonels were
expected to lend up to 10,000 talers each to sustain the costs of their
regiments.98 This was a common phenomenon in the 1670s and 1680s
when the armies of the smaller states frequently grew beyond the capacity
of tax revenues to sustain even their basic expenses. In fact, such direct
loans or voluntary contributions to military expenses continued far later
into the ancien régime. Field Marshal Ludwig Johann, count of Bussy-
Rabutin, claimed that he had advanced more than 300,000 florins on the
Emperor’s behalf from 1705 to 1707.99 Continuing the traditions of his
forebears, who had provided loans to fund Habsburg military operations
in both the Long Turkish War and the early years of the Thirty Years War,
Field Marshal Joseph Wenzel, prince of Liechtenstein, carried out his
reform of the Austrian artillery in the 1740s in significant part on the
back of private funds that he was prepared to invest in new developments
and better field guns.100
At its highest level this sort of ‘investment’ in the ruler’s military
activities of course was a traditional aristocratic or courtly gambit: large,
one-off financial commitments to military expenses, such as that of
Liechtenstein, were aimed at gaining political favour or some later advant-
age. Lesser but probably more frequent loans, provided by colonels and
senior officers in order to keep the army operational and the troops fed,
would not be ‘gifts’ in this respect, and they would expect, and in some
cases need, to receive reimbursement. Here we see a familiar pattern
reasserting itself the moment that war can be waged outside the immedi-
ate territory of the ruler, as the officers who had provided loans continued
to see themselves as shareholder-investors in the army, and looked to
296 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
their activities into smaller units. From another perspective, it can be seen
as an efficient version of the French mechanism for maintaining and
widening the extent of recognized investment by the elites in military
service: now every officer from captain upwards was a direct financial
stakeholder in the organization and the effectiveness of the army. In the
case of the British military administration, it seems that the playing-off of
colonels against captains in their respective fiscal and military responsi-
bilities and benefits allowed the government to strike a considerably
tougher bargain when offering remuneration to the captains for their
company expenses, while maintaining the goodwill of the colonels by
tolerating a higher level of perquisites and benefits at this senior level.117
Such mechanisms were not restricted to land forces: the Dutch Navy
Board continued the practice of paying the captains ‘provisioning pennies’
in return for the captains’ requirement to furnish the supplies for their
crews until 1808.118
The persistence of entrepreneurship across the armies of the later
seventeenth century had the same benefits and costs as in the French
case. The prestige and status of officer service continued to grow, and with
it the competition to obtain commands. The structure of all of these
armies ensured that the vast majority of posts would be filled by those
whose wealth would be channelled into the upkeep of their units, offering
in return official recognition of this commitment through marketability of
the office and some potential for investment return. One obvious cost of
this system was in the blocking of military promotion to those who lacked
the capital resources to purchase a company or regiment, and the very
rapid promotion of those whose financial resources, rather than military
skill and experience, gave them the wherewithal to purchase the unit and
to sustain the subsequent financial burdens of its management. This did
not necessarily mean that the regiment or company was badly led and run:
large numbers of units were run by competent and experienced lieutenant
colonels and company lieutenants acting as captains. But it generated the
tensions and resentments that non-professional barriers to promotion
would inevitably establish. The other cost was that the much-vaunted
administrative initiatives and controls identified with these standing
armies – the commissioners, inspectors, intendants – were in reality prag-
matic and limited agents of central authorities; these in turn recognized
that the military officers were engaged in the financing of the war machine
and that the administrators needed to tread carefully around issues of
discipline, moderate levels of financial misappropriation and proprietary
interest.119 Above all, the system turned proprietary officer corps across
Europe into a distinct caste, increasingly professional as the length of their
service increased, but acutely aware of points of social status within the
300 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
had no doubt that the system worked better, more flexibly and more
cheaply than the creation of a state-run and -financed supply corps. On
the one hand, there was a widely shared awareness that any specifically
created government system would suffer from a comparative lack of the
skills, experience and flexibility possessed by networks of established
merchants and producers.134 On the other, setting aside an extravagant
public rhetoric and a few egregious examples, in reality corruption was far
from endemic amongst contractors, and state employees operating a
supply corps would be quite capable of exceeding systematically any
graft and fraud practised by their private counterparts. Even apparently
model ‘bureaucracies’, such as the British excise administration and the
militarized officials who collected the excise and the contributions from
the Prussian territories, have been subject to substantial historical revi-
sionism as their inefficiencies, inflexibility and compromises with estab-
lished interests have been given more attention.135
Recent work on the supply of the British armies and fleet in the eight-
eenth century has made the same point on the basis of substantial and
persuasive evidence: ‘the remarkable feature of contracting in eighteenth-
century Britain was its efficiency . . . One can see a glaring double standard
in historical studies relating to contractors.’136 The success of contracting,
and its ability to satisfy the operational needs of army and navy, under-
pinned a substantial growth in the use of contracting through the eight-
eenth century. By 1763, as Gordon Bannerman illustrates in his study of
British army contractors, government had expanded its use of contracting
for all aspects of military supply and had tested its capacities through a
series of conflicts culminating in the operations of the Seven Years War.
The duties of military commissaries were almost entirely confined to
monitoring the activities of contractors; as in France, only the collection
of forage typically remained a concern for military officials.137 The expan-
sion of contracting was just as marked in the administration of the navy.
Shipbuilding itself, gun and cannon-ball founding, copper and lead min-
ing and manufacturing, rope making, manufacture of equipment and
uniforms, all drew upon the resources of the private manufacturers and
supplies. The Victualling Board served to coordinate the vast mass of
contracts by which the navy was fed and supplied with munitions.138
Despite the royal shipyards at Chatham, Portsmouth and Plymouth, the
Navy Board considered it essential throughout the eighteenth century to
turn to private shipyards to build and maintain part of the fleet, and
especially to respond to war-driven surges in demand.139 Between 1793
and 1815 some 71 per cent of naval tonnage was the product of private
shipyards, and only the very largest ninety- or one hundred-gun ships
were always built in royal dockyards.140 Where the contracting differed
The contractor state 303
from that of Continental states was in the greater willingness of both army
and navy officials to make use of large numbers of smaller manufacturers,
merchants and suppliers to meet their needs.141 The Victualling Board,
for example, was willing to sacrifice the potential convenience of handling
contracting through large-scale suppliers in order to maintain a more
flexible and perhaps more secure system of small-scale contracts. It
remained the case here that reliability and efficiency weighed heavily in
decisions about making and renewing contracts.142 Use of smaller-scale
contractors was not an attempt to stimulate cost-cutting, and contractors
were more likely to be appointed on the basis of their known reputation,
reliability and experience, while the outsider offering a deceptively cheap
tender would be rejected.
The developing system of contracting for military and naval supply was
undertaken not primarily to save money, but because it did the job better
than a state-run alternative. Private contracting offered, as it had done at
the time of the Thirty Years War, access to a much wider range of markets,
both domestic and foreign, in which a supply administration of govern-
ment officials would have found it difficult or impossible to deal – whether
for organizational or political reasons. It offered specialized expertise in
the face of complex and often diffuse markets: as in an earlier age, private
contractors were better at gathering together the relatively small-scale
production from many different locations or markets and concentrating
its delivery to meet the needs of the armed forces. Behind this lay the
enduring problems of gaining technical expertise and specialist skills in
manufacturing, supply and transport, of bringing together diffuse local
and regional markets to meet military demand, reducing costs and obtain-
ing credit.143 Moreover, the state could make use of a large-scale, diverse
and efficient system of manufacturing and supply without having to
capitalize its structure and operations on any significant scale, as would
have been the case if the decision was taken to set up a supply corps. While
it was accepted by all those directly involved in negotiations that contracts
would – and should – incorporate a reasonable level of profitability, as
with the figures cited in Chapter 5 for the purchase and transport of
gunpowder in the United Provinces for Genoese military needs in the
1620s, the profits were by no means outrageous or unreasonable given the
levels of risk run by the contractors.144 For the majority of states, and in
comparison with the extortionate costs of anticipating tax revenues via
short-term loans, military provisioning under contract was good value.
This was especially true given that contracting was much more adaptable
to the rhythms of war and peace; the contractor bore the risk of over-
stocking with military goods which might then need to be sold in a glutted,
post-war market. He took the risks of building up an infrastructure of
304 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
Conclusion
The most extensive and wide-ranging study of military enterprise as an
economic system is provided in Fritz Redlich’s monumental German
Military Enterpriser and his Work Force. The subtitle to the third and final
section gives an unambiguous indication of the approach to the subject
after 1650: ‘The Decay and Demise of Military Entrepreneurship’. After
nearly half a century, Redlich’s work still offers by far the most detailed
account of German military proprietorship. His approach therefore con-
tributes powerfully to the general perception that after 1650 a process of
inexorable decline occurred, each stage representing a further enfeeble-
ment of a system which had lost its raison d’être by the end of the Thirty
Years War.
Yet an alternative interpretation can be taken from the evidence. Military
organization after 1650 was characterized by a new series of private–public
partnerships between rulers, their administrations and various types of
military contractors, partnerships which were of themselves no more inher-
ently unstable and unworkable than their predecessors. As before, rulers
Conclusion 305
confronted the essential reality that military force on the scale that they
deemed necessary to secure their political objectives could only be mobi-
lized and maintained through the financial and organizational support of
their own elites or other, external sources of military force and funding. The
benefits for the ruler came through mobilizing otherwise unattainable
financial resources to raise more, better-equipped and better-provisioned
armed forces, and increasing levels of organizational competence and
flexibility in negotiating supply, manufacturing and transport of support
services. Early modern rulers, despite the implicit assumptions of Redlich
and other historians writing about military enterprise, held no a priori
assumptions about the practical superiority of state-controlled military
organization, even if in a few documented cases they may have expressed,
as did successive kings of Spain, an ideological preference for such central
administración. Indeed, the working knowledge that the latter would not
deliver comparable results in terms of efficiency and flexibility was the
strongest inducement to pursue the range of partnerships with private
capital and organization that have been examined in this chapter.
Moreover it should not be assumed that the direction in which these
state–private partnerships would move was inevitably further down the
path towards a preponderant state interest in the control of armies and
navies, albeit still underpinned with massive levels of private investment,
organization and support. Even in the later seventeenth century, it was still
possible to return to altogether more autonomous military activity. Under
the overwhelming fiscal pressure of the War of the League of Augsburg
(1689–97), the French Atlantic navy provides an example of how a radical
redrafting of the public–private partnership was still possible, turning the
clock back to an earlier style of military organization. Despite the success
of the Colbertian navy at the battle of Béveziers in July 1690, the inability
of the state to maintain even partial funding for both army and navy led to
a series of decisions by which the main Atlantic fleet was effectively
dissolved in 1694/5. The great majority of the larger-rated vessels were
simply laid up in the ports. The individual captains were offered letters of
marque, and encouraged to pursue their own financial interests via a
guerre de course to be sustained as long as the war lasted. Many of those
financiers and merchants who under Colbert’s aegis had been granted
lucrative contracts for building, maintaining and provisioning the navy
shifted their activities across to funding this wholesale privateering activ-
ity. They joined forces with a substantial number of merchant-skippers
who either had been involved in privateering previously or now saw in the
collapse of the navy the end of any chance of protection for legitimate
maritime activity. All of this was now organized at a local, sometimes
individual level, in business association with the venture capital of the
306 Continuity, transformation and rhetoric after 1650
307
308 Conclusion
respect for established interests are the price of support for policies sits
awkwardly with the knowledge that many European states by the later
seventeenth century had achieved an exponential increase in their ability
to tap their subjects’ financial resources and to spend these on raising and
maintaining unprecedented military forces.
As noted earlier in the book, the first clear and permanent increase in
the scale of military resources maintained by the major powers after the
mid-sixteenth century comes in the decades from the 1670s. The long-
term increase in military establishments in the later seventeenth century,
above all when the hugely increased costs of navies are added to land
forces, is unprecedented until the armies of the French Revolutionary
Wars. Yet the costs and the burdens of raising and maintaining these
forces were sustained on the back of societies and economies that experi-
enced, in most cases, limited or no economic growth and demographic
stagnation or decline. Confrontational and aggressive fiscal policies in
France during the 1630s and 1640s had failed to provide sufficient
resources to raise and maintain an army that was around a quarter of the
size of the forces maintained by Louis XIV in the Nine Years War. It is
therefore hard to see how this supposedly ‘consensual’ later regime,
respecting the privileges of the French elites and allowing the full burden
of taxation to rest on the impoverished and unprivileged, would find the
wherewithal to sustain its unprecedented war effort. The case for the
French state in the 1690s could equally be applied to the Spanish mon-
archy a generation earlier, or the Swedish state of the Vasas: how did
regimes with such apparently restricted access to fiscal and material
resources and without the capacity for coercion of their privileged subjects
manage to raise and maintain these massively increased military
establishments?
This challenge underpins a major shift in thinking about the nature of
early modern state power, and can be summarized in the shift of nomen-
clature from the ‘absolutist state’, with its assumptions about a general
level of unconditional authority and coercive power in the hands of the
ruler, to the ever-more widespread use of the term ‘fiscal-military state’ in
an early modern context. The concept of the ‘fiscal-military state’ gets to
the heart of a system of government whose priorities were focused on a
primary objective: the efficient raising – and spending – of money to
achieve the state’s military objectives in a competitive environment in
which the capacity to mobilize ever-larger military resources appeared
crucial to political success and failure. It is because the raising and main-
tenance of military force is identified as the fundamental concern and key
priority of the government and its administrators that political systems
which seem riddled with fiscal exemptions, institutional and individual
314 Conclusion
elites. The magistrates of the Parlement of Dijon, who paid over huge sums
to the crown, gained ever-tighter legal guarantees of the property rights in
their own offices so that they could use their value as collateral in raising
loans.8 In general the exploitation of venality of office, and the raising of
massive loans from institutions and their individual members, was bought
at the price of permanently reinforcing their privileges and autonomy
within the political system. But as the aim was the maximizing of fiscal
resources for the war effort, not the creation of some model of unimpeded
central authority exercised by an ‘absolutist’ crown, the bartering contin-
ued down to and beyond the end of the Sun King’s reign.
Whether seen in the relationship of the French crown with its ‘Fourth
Estate’, or the relationship of the Spanish crown with the great aristocratic
families whose financial and military support helped to sustain the war
effort down to 1659, the impact was the same: resources to boost the war
effort were bought through selling out on conventional notions of state-
formation through the centralization and concentration of authority and
the erosion of autonomous rights and privileges.9 In most respects an
autonomous state administration continued relatively weak and under-
developed, except in its ability to mobilize military resources.
If discussions of the fiscal-military state have focused on the fiscal,
rather than the military, side of its operations, there is certainly scope
to consider the latter as part of the explanation for the remarkable and
growing military capacity of the European state-system after 1670.
Raising unprecedented revenues from taxation and other sources,
expanding access to credit, and tapping wealth which lay well outside
the normal reach of government, was one key to sustaining unprecedented
military resources. Equally important is the effectiveness or otherwise with
which that money was spent on waging and sustaining war. A state like
Sweden, if forced to rely on its own modest fiscal resources to wage
warfare, could only hope to sustain its armies and navies through greater
efficiencies and more careful management than might be the case for
France or Russia. But in all cases the question of how effectively these
financial resources were used deserves some of the attention that has
previously been devoted to obtaining them in the first place.10 In this
context military enterprise and military outsourcing to private contractors
occupy far more than the marginal historical role to which conventional
accounts of European state-formation would consign them. Instead of
being unimportant throwbacks to a pre-modern world of uncontrolled
condottiere and militarized ‘overmighty’ subjects, the implications of rely-
ing in whole or part on contracted military force become central to the
mobilization capacity of the fiscal-military state. Indeed the debate about
whether historians should discuss ‘fiscal-military’ or ‘military-fiscal’ states
316 Conclusion
healthy troops on the field of Valmy in 1792, a different and altogether less
dramatic picture of change and continuity in European warfare might
have emerged.18 Events did, however, validate the national, citizen army,
whether in France, Prussia or eventually across the entire Continent.
Regardless of their initial military quality, the capacity of the French
Revolutionary state to deploy ideology and coercion to put 700,000 con-
scripts in the field by 1794 irrevocably altered the nature of European
warfare.19 This shift marked the real end of military enterprise. Once the
state regarded war as the duty of all citizens, it was inconceivable that it
could make additional use of hired mercenaries, that it could outsource
the organization and recruitment of troops, or even that it could rely on
private enterprise for the provisioning and supply of troops. By 1793 the
French state had abandoned contracting for the production and transport
of military supplies, and had guillotined several contractors as counter-
revolutionaries.20 Military service was now defined as a sacred duty to the
state, and in return the maintenance and well-being of the citizen-soldier
could only be organized and provided by the state. All that might remain
in the hands of private interests was the manufacturing and production of
armaments in cases where the state did not choose to assume direct
control of these or where, in wartime, continuous demand exceeded the
capacity of state-run facilities to supply military needs.21
The contingent outcome of military events in north-west Continental
Europe in the early 1790s could thus explain the disappearance of systems
of military enterprise that had hitherto proved a capable and adaptable
element of war-waging. But were there longer-term issues about the
privatization of military force that also require consideration? Was it
simply a straightforward consequence of the development of mass con-
scription and the political claims and reciprocal obligations implied by
building loyalty to the nation-state, or were there other issues relating
to the use of private military contractors in warfare waged by and for the
state?
It is fundamental to the argument of the present book that there is no
necessary incompatibility between the growth of the military power of the
state and the development of a substantial sphere of private military
activity; indeed, the latter made available a level of resources and robust-
ness of organization that would otherwise have been unattainable by
government authorities in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. This
is even more true of European military activity beyond the borders of the
Continent. An area of military privatization which has not been examined
in this work is in many respects the most visible example of such dele-
gation for the historian of early modern Europe. The establishment of
colonial trading companies, most notably but by no means exclusively the
The eclipse of military enterprise 321
English and Dutch East India (VOC) Companies in 1600 and 1602,
delivered a remarkable expansion of Europe’s military ‘reach’. The licens-
ing of private shareholder companies to engage in trading activity on their
own initiative, to use private military force to conquer territory which
would provide trading stations and organizational centres, to mobilize
troops and vessels in order to fight wars both against local populations and
against other European competitors, represented a huge level of delegated
military authority by European states. The most successful of these com-
panies grew continuously in scale and scope of activities throughout the
seventeenth century. In advancing their commercial interests on behalf of
their shareholders, the companies were virtually sovereign actors, with
powers to make war and to raise and command troops and warships, to
make treaties, to occupy territory, and to exercise rights of justice.
To some extent, however, the idea that these were purely private share-
holder companies was a fiction. It was no exaggeration of Hugo Grotius in
1613 to say that the directors of the VOC were to a large extent the men
who were responsible for the political affairs of the Dutch Republic.22 For
many of the ordinary investors, the early policies of the VOC, which
included heavy capital investment in colonial fortification programmes
and garrisoning, seemed a politically motivated evasion of the fiscal
responsibilities of the company to its shareholders. In the event, the
directors may have made the correct decision to commit capital to such
military projects, ensuring the longer-term success of the company’s
Asiatic ventures while also pursuing policies which could be seen to
serve the larger political interests of a Holland-dominated United
Provinces. In the medium and longer term, the VOC developed and
operated in ways that satisfied both the shareholders – whether these
were the bewindhebbers, the active investors with ships and merchandise
of their own serving the company, or the passive investors of capital, the
participanten – and the policy-makers in Holland. The dividends to VOC
shareholders climbed through the 1630s and 1640s, while the company
itself achieved its greatest military and commercial successes.23
In contrast, the Dutch West India Company (WIC), founded in 1621
with still stronger government intervention in the formulation of policy
through its board of directors and its deployment of resources, was
altogether less successful.24 Committed as its primary objective to acquir-
ing and establishing colonies at the expense of Portugal and Castile, rather
than building up trade networks or engaging in privateering against the
Spanish treasure and merchant fleets, the investment policy of the com-
pany was skewed against the wishes of the majority of its shareholders.
First attempts at this policy of colonization, including the bid to consol-
idate control of Bahia, captured from the Portuguese in 1624, proved
Fig. 7.1 Dutch East India Company magazine and dockyard
The eclipse of military enterprise 323
expensive failures. By the end of the first decade of its life, the WIC had
bought or built 220 ships and spent more than 18 million guilders on
wages for its soldiers, sailors, agents and officials.25 Pushed towards these
overtly political-military objectives by the directors, the company was
instrumental in establishing Johann Maurice of Nassau-Siegen as gover-
nor general of newly conquered ‘Dutch’ Brazil. The costs of a major
colonial military policy were being borne by the company throughout
the early 1640s. Only in 1646, with the collapse in the value of WIC
shares and threatened bankruptcy, did the directors accept ‘the trans-
formation of the Company from a trading war-machine into a non-
belligerent commercial organization, content to supply the colonies of
other powers and relying for protection of its own modest assortment of
territories on the States General’.26
This experience of some of the shareholder companies in their overly
close or at least ambiguous relations with government and government
priorities to some extent foreshadows a much larger problem in the
relations between military contracting and the military and political claims
of the state. As the scale of military operations grew larger under the aegis
of the fiscal-military state and its beneficial public–private partnerships, so
the relations between the ruler, his government and key figures in the
private sector, above all that concerned with manufacturing, supply and
distribution of food and matériel, became closer. There was certainly a
tension in the seventeenth, as in the twenty-first, century between the
temptation to rely on a safe pair of hands in matters as important as
military supply, and promoting competition by putting contracts out to
tender. United States’ governments in the past two decades provide
numerous examples of contracts made with logistical support companies,
not because they offer the lowest price, but because they have a proven
track record of successful contracts, and therefore seem to offer greater
reliability. Brown and Root Services, particularly after its contracts in
Bosnia and Kosovo in the late 1990s, had the reputation with the
Pentagon of a military company whose strongest selling point was speed
of deployment and response to rapidly changing circumstances, which
none of its other competitors looked likely to match, even if they could
undercut on price.27 And as the examples in Chapters 5 and 6 indicated,
early modern governments reacted to similar concerns in similar ways.
Yet such close relations between government and the highest strata of
military enterprisers and contractors had significant repercussions. They
could easily – and increasingly did – mean a reliance on those with strong
court or government influence and patrons, those who were such patrons
themselves, or those whose financial dealings and interests overlapped
significantly with the court and government.28 Reliability or resources
324 Conclusion
could easily slide into influence and favour when it came to choosing
contractors. Brown and Root won US military contracts on the basis of its
known resources and flexibility, but this was in part because the company
was a major subsidiary of another and better-known corporate giant,
Halliburton, whose links with senior government ministers under
President George W. Bush were exceptionally strong.29 To take just one
early modern state, similar doubts could be raised about the French
government’s munitions contracts with Cardinal Mazarin and his finan-
cial associates in the 1640s and 1650s, about the networks that linked the
building and supply of the navy in the 1670s and 1680s to a Colbertian
clientele of contractors, or the extraordinary hold exercised by the Pâris
brothers over the financial and munitions contracts drawn up for the
French armies under Louis XV.30 Large-scale, often monopolistic con-
tracts with well-connected military contractors became more common,
and were easy targets for the criticism of those who set themselves in
opposition to particular court and government factions, or who took the
line of general public concern against corrupt court interests and favour.
The increasingly large scale of military activity which had originally
served as the spur to private enterprise, making substantial capital invest-
ment in the business of war viable and financially attractive, thus had a
paradoxical consequence. When contracts started to draw upon those
directly involved in – or closely linked to – government as contractors,
organizers and suppliers, the ability to offer a military option that was
responsive, flexible and tailored to a particular set of circumstances was no
longer a recognized priority. A process of institutionalization took place
which did not lead to a conventionally understood ‘monopoly over the
means of violence’, but involved a private sector which was heavily infil-
trated by the capital and interests of members of government and other
established political elites; this is only a few steps away from the institu-
tional ‘military-industrial complex’ of the late nineteenth and twentieth
century.31
The obvious consequence was a very public association of private and
public interest in the waging of war, especially as the most prominent
aspect of enterpriser involvement was not now the recruitment and mili-
tary operations of privately funded regiments and companies, but the
outsourcing of military supply and other logistical operations. Military
failure could very easily lead to a public backlash against private interests
who occupied the profitable role of supplier and contractor and could
more easily be made the scapegoat for military setbacks than the officers,
soldiers and sailors. As they were separated from active and more hon-
ourable military roles, and heavily linked to government policy-making
from which they appeared to be the prime beneficiaries, the way was
The eclipse of military enterprise 325
NOTES TO INTRODUCTION
1. Michael Roberts, ‘The Military Revolution, 1560–1660’ (Belfast, 1956), repr.
in Roberts, Essays in Swedish History (London, 1967), pp. 195–225.
2. For the extensive bibliography on the ‘military revolution’, see notes 36, 38,
39, 43 and 45.
3. Jacques de Guibert, Essai général de tactique (1772), ed. Jean-Pierre Bois
(Paris, 2004).
4. See introduction and chapters by Whitby, Hornblower and Roy in R. Lane-
Fox (ed.), The Long March. Xenophon and the Ten Thousand (New Haven and
London, 2004).
5. A. Goldsworthy, The Roman Army at War, 100BC–AD200 (Oxford, 1996),
pp. 19–24, 35–7.
6. K. Fowler, Medieval Mercenaries, Vol. I: The Great Companies (Oxford, 2001).
7. P.W. Singer, Corporate Warriors. The Rise of the Privatized Military Industry
(Ithaca, 2003).
8. A very recent volume of essays published under the aegis of the
Militärgeschichtliches Forschungsamt, Potsdam, suggests that this situation
may be changing: S. Förster, C. Jansen and G. Kronenbitter (eds.), Rückkehr
der Condottieri? Krieg und Militär zwischen staatlichem Monopol und
Privatisierung: Von der Antike bis zur Gegenwart (Paderborn, 2010).
9. A. Mockler, Mercenaries (London, 1969); G. Trease, The Condottieri. Soldiers
of Fortune (London, 1970); W. Urban, Medieval Mercenaries. The Business
of War (London, 2006); Urban, Bayonets for Hire: Mercenaries at War,
1550–1789 (London, 2007).
10. D. Avant, The Market for Force. The Consequences of Privatizing Security
(Cambridge, 2005); D. Isenberg, A Fistful of Contractors. The Case for a
Pragmatic Assessment of Private Military Companies in Iraq (London, 2004).
11. C. Kinsey, Corporate Soldiers and International Security. The Rise of Private
Military Companies (London, 2006); Singer, Corporate Warriers, pp. 49–70,
who argues for the importance of the end of the Cold War for the establish-
ment of private military companies (PMCs), though also considers that future
growth lies with multi-functioned private security companies (PSCs); see also
S. Percy, Mercenaries. The History of a Norm in International Relations (Oxford,
2007), pp. 206–43.
328
Notes to pages 4–10 329
12. J. Scahill, Blackwater. The Rise of the World’s Most Powerful Mercenary Army
(London, 2007); for an account of non-Blackwater PSC activity in Iraq,
G. Schumacher, A Bloody Business. America’s War Zone Contractors and the
Occupation of Iraq (St Paul, MN, 2006).
13. D. Avant, ‘Mercenaries’, Foreign Policy, 143 (2004), 20–8.
14. Percy, Mercenaries, pp. 49–67.
15. J. Thomson, Mercenaries, Pirates and Sovereigns (Princeton, 1994),
pp. 69–142.
16. Percy, Mercenaries, pp. 68–93.
17. S. Percy, ‘Mercenaries: Strong Norm, Weak Law’, International Organization,
61 (2007), 367–97.
18. Percy, Mercenaries, pp. 212–18, on the overwhelming political and moral
consensus against using PMCs in Angola, Sierra Leone and Papua New
Guinea in the late 1990s.
19. Recent examples would include: R. Bean, ‘War and the Birth of the Nation
State’, Journal of Economic History, 33 (1973), 203–21; B. Porter, War and the
Rise of the State. The Military Foundations of Modern Politics (New York, 1994),
pp. 23–61; M. Van Creveld, The Rise and Decline of the State (Cambridge,
1999), pp. 59–125.
20. F. Lane, ‘Economic Consequences of Organized Violence’, Journal of
Economic History, 18 (1958), 401–17; Lane, ‘The Economic Meaning of
War and Protection’, in Lane, Venice and History (Baltimore, MD, 1966);
C. Tilly, ‘War Making and State Making as Organized Crime’, in P. Evans,
D. Rueschemeyer and T. Skocpol (eds.), Bringing the State Back In
(Cambridge, 1985), pp. 169–91, pp. 175–80 criticizes the underlying
assumptions of Lane that a monopoly of force will prevail because it is able
to provide protection more cheaply: ‘the very activity of producing and con-
trolling violence favoured monopoly, because competition within that realm
generally raised costs . . . The production of violence, he suggested, enjoyed
large economies of scale.’
21. For a succinct account, see R. Gothelf, ‘Frederick William I and the
Beginnings of Prussian Absolutism’, pp. 47–67, and H. Scott ‘Prussia’s
Emergence as a European Great Power, 1740–1763’, pp. 153–76, in
P. Dwyer (ed.), The Rise of Prussia, 1700–1830 (London, 2000).
22. P. Wilson, ‘The German “Soldier Trade” of the Seventeenth and Eighteenth
Centuries: a Reassessment’, The International History Review, 18 (1996),
757–92.
23. For example: A. Dareste de La Chavanne, Histoire de l’administration en France
(4 vols., Paris, 1848).
24. A. Forrest, ‘La Patrie en Danger. The French Revolution and the First Levée en
Masse’, in D. Moran and A. Waldron (eds.), The People in Arms. Military Myth
and National Mobilization since the French Revolution (Cambridge, 2003),
pp. 8–32.
25. M. Weber, ‘The Presuppositions and Causes of Bureaucracy’, in R. Merton
(ed.), A Reader in Bureaucracy (New York, 1960), pp. 66–7.
26. Otto Hintze, Historical Essays, ed. F. Gilbert (Oxford, 1975), see ‘The
Hohenzollern and the Nobility’, pp. 33–63; ‘Military Organization and the
330 Notes to pages 10–14
Organization of the State’, pp. 178–215; ‘The Commissary and his Significance
in General Administrative History: a Comparative Study’, pp. 267–301.
Hintze, Gesammelte Abhandlungen zur allgemeinen Verfassungsgeschichte, ed.
G. Oestreich (3 vols., Göttingen, 1962–7), see esp. ‘Der österreichische und
der preußische Beamtenstaat im 17. und 18. Jahrhundert; Eine vergleichende
Betrachtung’ (1901), I, 321–58; ‘Machtpolitik und Regierungsverfassung’
(1913), I, 424–56; ‘Der Ursprung des preußischen Landratsamts in der Mark
Brandenburg’ (1915), III, 164–203.
27. ‘Machtpolitik und Regierungsverfassung’, III, 429.
28. ‘This [standing army] was not a product of princely caprice and arbitrariness,
but was a European necessity from which no state could escape . . .’,
‘Hohenzollern’, p. 45.
29. H. Scott (ed.), The European Nobilities of the Seventeenth and Eighteenth
Centuries (2 vols., London, 1995), I, pp. 35–52.
30. P. Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. Economic Change and
Military Conflict from 1500–2000 (London, 1988), pp. 89–91; D. Kaiser,
Politics and War. European Conflict from Philip II to Hitler (London, 1990),
pp. 7–137; Porter, Rise of the State, pp. xiii–147.
31. W. Reinhard, ‘Power Elites, State Servants, Ruling Classes and the Growth of
State Power’, pp. 1–18, and R. Braun, ‘Staying on Top: Socio-cultural
Reproduction of European Power Elites’, pp. 235–59, in W. Reinhard (ed.),
Power Elites and State Building (Oxford, 1996); T. Skocpol, ‘Introduction’,
pp. 3–37, pp. 3–11, and C. Tilly, ‘War Making and State Making as
Organized Crime’, pp. 169–91, pp. 175–7, in Evans, Rueschemeyer and
Skocpol (eds.), Bringing the State Back In.
32. P. Contamine, ‘Introduction’, in Contamine (ed.), War and Competition
between States (Oxford, 2000), pp. 1–7. For an excellent survey of recent
trends in this area of research, see B. Kroener, ‘Vom “extraordinari
Kriegsvolck” zum “miles perpetuus”. Zur Rolle der bewaffneten Macht in
der europäischen Gesellschaft der Frühen Neuzeit’, in Kroener, Kriegerische
Gewalt und militärische Pråsenz in der Neuzeit (Paderborn, 2008), pp. 3–63;
Kroener, ‘“Das Schwungrad an der Staatsmaschine?” Die Bedeutung der
bewaffneten Macht in der europäischen Geschichte der Frühen Neuzeit’, in
B. Kroener and R. Pröve (eds.), Krieg und Frieden. Militär und Gesellschaft in
der Frühen Neuzeit (Paderborn, 1996), pp. 1–23.
33. W. McNeill, The Pursuit of Power. Technology, Armed Force and Society since AD
1000 (Chicago, 1982), pp. 117–84.
34. For example, C. Tilly, Coercion, Capital and European States AD 990–1990
(Oxford, 1990); B. Downing, The Military Revolution and Political Change.
Origins of Democracy and Autocracy in Early Modern Europe (Princeton, 1992);
T. Ertman, Birth of the Leviathan. Building States and Regimes in Early Modern
Europe (Cambridge, 1997).
35. D. Kolff, Naukar, Rajput and Sepoy. The Ethnohistory of the Military Labour
Market in Hindustan, 1450–1850 (Cambridge, 1990), pp. 32–116;
J. Gommans, Mughal Warfare (London, 2002), pp. 67–97. Another
good example is provided by medieval Japan: ‘law enforcement and
defence, like most operations of government during the Heian era, simply
Notes to pages 14–22 331
NOTES TO CHAPTER 1
1. N. Machiavelli, Florentine Histories, ed. and trans. L.F. and H.C. Mansfield,
(Princeton, 1988), pp. 226–7.
2. D. Le Fur, Marignan, 13–14 septembre 1515 (Paris, 2004), pp. 95–6.
3. Le Fur, Marignan, pp. 106–7.
4. E. von Frauenholz, Entwicklungsgeschichte des deutschen Heerwesens (5 vols.,
Munich, 1935–41), II, Pt 1, p. 114, cites a contemporary account of the battle:
‘das ist im namen des vaters, sohns und heiligen geists; das soll unser kilchhof
sin, frommen lieben Eydtgnossen’.
5. R.J. Knecht, Renaissance Warrior and Patron. The Reign of Francis I
(Cambridge, 1994), pp. 71–7; F. Lot, Recherches sur les effectifs des armées
françaises des Guerres d’Italie aux Guerres de Religion, 1494–1562 (Paris,
1962), pp. 41–4; Le Fur, Marignan, p. 116.
6. M. Mallett, Mercenaries and their Masters. Warfare in Renaissance Italy (London,
1974), p. 197, indicates that some 900 soldiers were killed overall. The myth that
condottiere warfare was bloodless choreography was comprehensively challenged
by W. Block, Die Condottieri. Studien über die sogenannten ‘unblutigen Schlachten’
(Berlin, 1913), but remains an integral part of the case against mercenaries.
7. For sixteenth-century perceptions of the mercenary as exclusively motivated
by wages, see especially D. Trim, ‘Fighting “Jacob’s Wars”. The Employment
of English and Welsh Mercenaries in the European Wars of Religion: France
and the Netherlands, 1562–1610’ (Ph.D. thesis, King’s College London,
2002), pp. 74–81.
8. D. Potter, Renaissance France at War. Armies, Culture and Society, c. 1480–1560
(Woodbridge, 2008), pp. 76–7, based on a gendarmerie of 1,500 ‘lances’
funded through the ordinaire des guerres.
9. R. Quatrefages, La revolución militar moderna. El crisol espanol (Madrid, 1996).
10. For examples of this from the Netherlands, see S. Gunn, D. Grummitt and
H. Cools, War, State and Society in England and the Netherlands, 1477–1559
(Oxford, 2007), pp. 142–7, 151.
11. The terms are usefully deployed in J. Thomson, Mercenaries, Pirates and
Sovereigns (Princeton, 1994).
12. W.H. McNeill, Europe’s Steppe Frontier, 1500–1800 (Chicago, 1964), pp. 113–20.
13. H. von Zwiedineck-Südenhorst, Kriegsbilder aus der Zeit der Landsknechte
(Stuttgart, 1883), pp. 257–60, gives 16,700 troops in 1589, and identifies
six strongpoints with garrisons of 900 men or more.
14. G. Rothenberg, The Austrian Military Border in Croatia, 1522–1747 (Urbana,
IL, 1960), pp. 27–30.
15. The Hajduks further east in the Hungarian borderlands would have provided
an equally effective example of this co-opting of local interests: P.F. Sugar,
Southeastern Europe under Ottoman Rule, 1354–1804 (Seattle, 1977),
pp. 242–7; F. Szakály, ‘The Hungarian–Croatian Border Defence System
and its Collapse’, pp. 141–58, and F. Maksay, ‘Peasantry and Mercenary
Service in Sixteenth-Century Hungary’, pp. 261–74, in J. Bak and B. Király
(eds.), From Hunyadi to Rákóczi: War and Society in Late Medieval and Early
Modern Hungary (New York, 1982).
Notes to pages 32–7 333
16. Rothenberg, Military Border, pp. 28–9; C.W. Bracewell, The Uskoks of Senj.
Piracy, Banditry and Holy War in the Sixteenth-Century Adriatic (Ithaca and
London, 1992), p. 43.
17. Bracewell, Uskoks, p. 91.
18. Bracewell, Uskoks, pp. 130–1; A. Tenenti, Piracy and the Decline of Venice,
1580–1615 (London, 1967), pp. 5–11.
19. Rothenberg, Military Border, pp. 54–5.
20. Bracewell, Uskoks, pp. 148–50.
21. Bracewell, Uskoks, pp. 112–13, who maintains that few Uskok pirates died
wealthy men.
22. J. Glete (ed.), Naval History, 1500–1680 (Aldershot, 2005), pp. xi–xxvi.
23. K.R. Andrews, Elizabethan Privateering. English Privateering during the Spanish
War, 1585–1603 (Cambridge, 1964), p. 5.
24. Thomson, Mercenaries, pp. 22–3; N. Rodger, The Safeguard of the Sea.
A Naval History of Britain, 660–1649 (London, 1997), pp. 199–202.
25. Thomson, Mercenaries, pp. 43–4.
26. A. James, Navy and Government in Early Modern France, 1572–1661 (London,
2004), pp. 14–15; M. Augeron, ‘Coligny et les Espagnols à travers la course’,
in M. Acerra and G. Martinière (eds.), Coligny, les Protestants et la mer (Paris,
1997), pp. 155–76; B. Dietz, ‘The Huguenot and English Corsairs during the
Third Civil War in France, 1568–70’, Proceedings of the Huguenot Society of
London, 19 (1952–8), 278–94.
27. E.O. Lana, Los corsarios espagñoles durante la decadencia de los Austrias. El corso
español del Atlántico peninsular en el siglo XVII (Madrid, 1992), pp. 97–155,
253–70.
28. In many cases the shipowners, armadores, would own multiple vessels and
therefore determine the collective policies of their hired captains: Lana, Los
corsarios, pp. 99–107.
29. R. Baetens, ‘The Organization and Effects of Flemish Privateering in the
Seventeenth Century’, in Glete (ed.), Naval History, pp. 453–80, pp. 461–3.
30. Thomson, Mercenaries, p. 43.
31. P. Rambeaud, ‘L’admiral à La Rochelle: l’union du ciel et de la mer’, in
Acerra and Martinière (eds.), Coligny, pp. 131–43; James, Navy and
Government, pp. 14–16.
32. Lana, Los corsarios, pp. 53–60; R. Stradling, The Armada of Flanders. Spanish
Maritime Policy and European War, 1568–1668 (Cambridge, 1992), pp. 35–6.
33. R. Stradling, ‘The Spanish Dunkirkers, 1621–48: a Record of Plunder and
Destruction’, in Glete (ed.), Naval History, pp. 488–9; Stradling, Armada of
Flanders, pp. 80–9.
34. J. Heers, The Barbary Corsairs. Warfare in the Mediterranean, 1480–1580
(London, 2003), pp. 33–70; P. Williams, ‘Piracy and Naval conflict in the
Mediterranean, 1590–1610/20’ (D.Phil. thesis, Oxford University, 2001),
pp. 50–62; P. Earle, Corsairs of Malta and Barbary (London, 1970),
pp. 23–36, 47.
35. G. Hanlon, The Twilight of a Military Tradition. Italian Aristocrats and European
Conflicts, 1560–1800 (London, 1998), pp. 30–6; U. Ubaldini, La marina del
sovrano militare ordine di San Giovanni di Gerusalemme di Rodi e di Malta
(Rome, 1971), pp. 46–56, 60–8.
334 Notes to pages 37–42
56. Covino, Esercito, pp. 285–351, examines the military policy of Galeazzo Maria
Sforza, duke of Milan, who wanted the flexibility of creating his own army but
also hired large numbers of condottiere to meet specific crises in the 1470s.
57. F. Cardini, ‘Condottiere e uomini d’arme nell’Italia del Renascimento’, in
M. Del Treppo (ed.), Condottiere e uomini d’arme nell’Italia del Renascimento
(Naples, 2001), pp. 1–10.
58. Peter Blastenbrei, Die Sforza und ihr Heer. Studien zur Strukture-, Wirtschafts-
und Sozialgeschichte des Söldnerwesens in der italienischen Frührenaissance
(Heidelberg, 1987), pp. 50–60.
59. Mallett, Mercenaries, pp. 82–3.
60. Mallett, Mercenaries, pp. 83–4. In the mid-fifteenth century Galeazzo Maria
Sforza was paying a typical prestanza of 40–60 florins per lance, and 4–6 florins
per footsoldier to his condottieri on a one-year contract: Blastenbrei, Sforza, p. 204.
61. M. Mallett and J. Hale, The Military Organization of a Renaissance State.
Venice, c.1400–1617 (Cambridge, 1984), pp. 21–9 on the problems faced by
Venice in defending the Terraferma in the early years of the fifteenth century.
62. Mallett, Mercenaries, pp. 84–5, indicates one-third, rising in cases to half the
full pay.
63. Mallett and Hale, Venice, p. 319.
64. Blastenbrei, Sforza, p. 221.
65. Mallett and Hale, Venice, pp. 153–9, 284–312.
66. Covini, Esercito, pp. 285–328.
67. W. Caferro, ‘Continuity, Long-Term Service, and Permanent Forces: a
Reassessment of the Florentine Army in the Fourteenth Century’, Journal of
Modern History, 80 (2008), 219–51.
68. N. Labanca, ‘Clio, Mercurio e Marte: aspetti economici delle guerre in
Europa’, Ricerche storiche, 14 (1984), 645–72, p. 658.
69. I. Affò, Vita di Vespasiano Gonzaga (1780; repr. Mantua, 1975), pp. 12–47;
L. Amadè, Il duca di Sabbioneta (Milan, 1990), pp. 75–241; R. Tamalio,
‘Vespasiano Gonzaga al servizio del Re di Spagna’, in U. Bazzotti,
D. Ferrari and C. Mozzarelli (eds.), Vespasiano Gonzaga e il Ducato di
Sabbioneta (Mantua, 1993), pp. 121–51.
70. M. Brambilla, Ludovico Gonzaga, Duca di Nevers, 1539–1595 (Udine, 1905),
pp. 4–15.
71. C. von Elgger, Kriegswesen und Kriegskunst der schweizerischen Eidgenossen im
XIV, XV und XVI Jahrhundert (Lucerne, 1873), pp. 280–9; the Haufen
evolved gradually towards a rectangular formation with more depth than
breadth.
72. E. Dürr, ‘La principauté de Habsbourg et la formation de la Confédération
des VIII cantons, 1315–1379’, in M. Feldmann and H. Wirz (eds.), Histoire
militaire de la Suisse (4 vols., Berne, 1915–35), IV, pp. 23–64; C. Padrutt, Staat
und Krieg im Alten Bünden (Zurich, 1965), p. 29.
73. R. Durrer, ‘Premier combats de la Suisse primitive’, in Feldmann and Wirz,
Histoire militaire, I, pp. 60–1; R. Baumann, Landsknechte. Ihre Geschichte und
Kultur vom späten Mittelalter bis zum Dreißigjährigen Krieg (Munich, 1994), p. 23.
74. R. von Fischer, ‘Les Guerres de Bourgogne (1474–77)’, in Feldmann and
Wirz, Histoire militaire, II, pp. 155–201.
336 Notes to pages 47–9
75. Fischer, ‘Les Guerres’, pp. 164–5: though the entire Burgundian artillery of
some four hundred guns fell into Swiss hands; M. Mallett, ‘Mercenaries’, in
M. Keen (ed.), Medieval Warfare. A History (Oxford, 1999), pp. 209–29.
76. J. Häne, ‘L’organisation militaire des anciens Suisses’, in Feldmann and
Wirz, Histoire militaire, III, pp. 16–19.
77. R. Baumann, Das Söldnerwesen im 16. Jahrhundert im bayerischen und
süddeutschen Beispiel. Eine gesellschaftsgeschichtliche Untersuchung (Munich,
1978), p. 244.
78. Quatrefages, La revolución militar moderna, on the early evolution of the tercios.
79. Figures taken from contracts with the French crown from 1475 to the time of
François I. These were not the highest sums paid: a contract for service in Milan
in 1518 offered the ordinary soldier 5½ gulden: Elgger, Kriegswesen, p. 167.
80. W. Schaufelberger, Der Alte Schweizer und sein Krieg. Studien zur Kriegsführung
vornehmlich im 15. Jahrhundert (Zurich, 1952), pp. 165–85, devotes an entire
chapter to booty as an essential factor in understanding the motivation of the
Swiss troops, and as part of what he terms ‘the triumph of disorder’ in Swiss
military organization.
81. Schaufelberger, Alte Schweizer, pp. 146–7, gives an example of an order from
Zurich in 1422 which forbade any unauthorized military service, whether with
other cantons or abroad; but he recognizes that in practice these prohibitions
were a dead letter: pp. 149–50.
82. Elgger, Kriegswesen, pp. 78–80; M.H. Koerner ‘Der Einfluss der
Europäischen Kriege auf die Struktur der Schweizerischen Finanzen im 16
Jahrhundert’, in O. Pickl (ed.), Krieg, Militärausgaben und Wirtschaftlicher
Wandel (Graz, 1980), pp. 37–45; for the relations between the French mon-
archy and the cantonal authorities, see M. Burin de Roziers, Les capitulations
militaires entre la Suisse et la France (Doctoral thesis, University of Paris, 1902).
83. Elgger, Kriegswesen, pp. 75–8.
84. Frauenholz, Heerwesen, II, Pt 1, p. 58, taken from an estimate from 1481,
though adds that contemporaries considered little over one-third of this
number could actually be raised without creating insuperable problems of
subsistence.
85. Häne, ‘Organisation militaire’, 7–9; Schaufelberger, Alte Schweizer, p. 19.
86. Schaufelberger, Alte Schweizer, pp. 84–7, 98–102.
87. Elgger, Kriegswesen, pp. 56–7. Though the capacity of the authorities to
mobilize all those in theory subject to military service should not be over-
estimated: A. Sennhauser, Hauptmann und Führung im Schweizerkrieg des
Mittelalters (Zurich, 1965), p. 129.
88. Machiavelli had a high opinion of the Swiss system of collective obligation: The
Art of War, trans. E. Farneworth (1521; repr. New York, 1965), pp. 35, 61.
89. On seeking consensual decisions with subordinate officers via the Kriegsrat see
Padrutt, Staat und Krieg, pp. 133–5; all accounts of Swiss military organiza-
tion emphasize the extent to which the officers had limited power to compel or
discipline their troops.
90. Elgger, Kriegswesen, pp. 199–200. Where, in Berne and Zurich, for example,
the post-reformation political consensus opposed significant foreign military
service, the impact was overwhelmingly apparent in the military
Notes to pages 49–52 337
132. B.S. Hall, Weapons and Warfare in Renaissance Europe (Baltimore and
London, 1997), pp. 192–9, who draws extensively on François de La
Noue’s accounts of pistolier cavalry.
133. F. de La Noue, ‘Premier paradoxe: qu’un escadron de reitres doit battre un
escadron de lances’, in Discours politiques et militaires (Geneva, 1967),
pp. 355–62.
134. Fiedler, Kriegswesen, pp. 216–17.
135. Fiedler, Kriegswesen, p. 96: fully armoured, often noble, Reiters received
double this pay: F. Lammert, ‘Von den deutschen Pistolenreitern und
ihrem Führer Graf Günter von Schwarzburg’, Zeitschrift für Historische
Waffen- und Kostümkunde, 12 (1931), 209–28.
136. Frauenholz, Heerwesen, II, Pt 2, pp. 50–3.
137. Lot, Recherches, pp. 41–2.
138. Lot, Recherches, pp. 62–3.
139. Lot, Recherches, pp. 131–2, 140, 176–85.
140. Millar, Tudor Mercenaries, pp. 65–95; 1,200–1,400 Landsknechte under
Conrad Pennink were in England in 1549 and assisted the earl of Warwick
in the suppression of Ket’s Rebellion: ibid., p. 176.
141. D. Potter, ‘The International Mercenary Market in the Sixteenth Century:
Anglo-French Competition in Germany, 1543–50’, English Historical
Review, 111 (1996), 24–58, pp. 27–8; Millar, Tudor Mercenaries, pp. 90–3;
Gunn et al., England and the Netherlands, pp. 147–50.
142. E. Hedegaard, Landsknaegtene i Danmark i det 16. århundrede. En kulturhis-
torisk studie (Helsingør, 1965), pp. 15–18. Hedegaard discusses both the
hiring of German Landsknechte and the evolution of a parallel military system
in Denmark.
143. H. Dihle, ‘Das Kriegstagebuch eines Deutschen Landsknechts um die
Wende des 15. Jahrhunderts’, Zeitschrift für Historische Waffen- und
Kostümkunde, n.s., 3 (12) (1929), 1–11.
144. Burschel, Söldner, pp. 145–65, who specifically rejects the assumption that
the recruitment of the Landsknechte had a homogeneity lost in the later
period of military enterprise.
145. Wohlfeil, ‘Adel und neues Heerwesen’, pp. 215–16; Burschel, Söldner,
pp. 60–72.
146. Baumann, Frundsberg, pp. 215–17; the topic is judiciously discussed in
H.M. Möller, Das Regiment der Landsknechte. Untersuchungen zu Verfassung,
Recht und Selbstverständnis in deutschen Söldnerheeren des 16. Jahrhunderts
(Wiesbaden, 1976), pp. 67–71, who identifies a degree of common identity
only in antipathy to non-Germans.
147. Baumann, Frundsberg, pp. 123–5, 272–5.
148. Frauenholz, Heerwesen, II, Pt 1, p. 114: ‘Aber sind mannlich und gedenckt
dheiner heimb’.
149. For the Swiss, see the article by W. Meyer, ‘Religiös-magisches Denken und
Verhalten im eidgenössisches Kriegertum des ausgehenden Mittelalters’, in
M. Kaiser and S. Kroll (eds.), Militär und Religiosität in der Frühen Neuzeit
(Münster, 2004), pp. 21–32; Landsknecht piety and practice in Möller,
Regiment des Landsknechte, pp. 112–13.
340 Notes to pages 60–5
150. M. Kaiser and S. Kroll, ‘Introduction’, in Kaiser and Kroll (eds.), Militär
und Religiosität, pp. 11–19.
151. G. Parker, The Army of Flanders and the Spanish Road, 1567–1659 (2nd edn,
Cambridge, 2004), pp. 152–3.
152. Baumann, Landsknechte, pp. 131–45.
153. Baumann, Frundsberg, pp. 274–5.
154. Möller, Regiment der Landsknechte, pp. 77–80. The Swiss premium was one
of the many reasons for the mortal antagonism between Swiss and
Landsknechte: Bächtiger, ‘Andreaskreuz und Schweizerkreuz’, pp. 218–19;
Burschel, Söldner, pp. 170–8, cautions against simplistic wage-for-wage
comparisons with civilian life, but does not doubt that as an indication of
status through remuneration this wage of nearly 50 gulden per annum places
the soldier high amongst the ranks of skilled craftsmen (p. 173).
155. Though a full set of infantry armour would cost up to 16 gulden: Möller,
Regiment der Landsknechte, p. 76.
156. Baumann, Landsknechte, pp. 64–6.
157. Zwiedineck-Südenhorst, Kriegsbilder, p. 9; Möller, Regiment der Landsknechte,
pp. 52, 58–67.
158. Burschel, Söldner, pp. 38–53, sums up the process in terms of the perceptions
of society: ‘vom “schlauen Landsknecht” zum “dummen Soldaten”’.
159. Baumann, Landsknechte, p. 117.
160. Or the customary address of the Provost to the assembled Landsknechte
before justifying to them the execution of a condemned soldier and asking
for their agreement to the sentence: ‘Einen guten Morgen, liebe, ehrliche
Landsknechte, edel und unedel, wie uns denn Gott zu einander gebracht
und versammelt hat!’: F. Blau, Die deutschen Landsknechte. Ein Kulturbild
(Görlitz, 1882), pp. 42–3.
161. M. Rogg, Landsknechte und Reisläufer: Bilder vom Soldaten. Ein Stand in der
Kunst des 16. Jahrhunderts (Paderborn, 2002), esp. pp. 148–210.
162. Baumann, Landsknechte, pp. 98–9; Möller, Regiment der Landsknechte,
pp. 95–9.
163. The system was paralleled in the Swiss companies, and indeed originated
with them: Frauenholz, Heerwesen, II, Pt 2, pp. 54–5.
164. For one of the best accounts of small-group dynamics written from imme-
diate experience, see S.L. Marshall, Men against Fire. The Problem of Battle
Command in Future War (New York, 1947), pp. 60–1, 138–56.
165. Parker, Army of Flanders, pp. 151–2; La Noue, Discours, pp. 340–7
(‘Seiziesme Discours’), praised the military virtues of the Spanish system
of camaradas and urged – unsuccessfully – its adoption by France.
166. Baumann, Landsknechte, p. 101.
167. Blau, Deutschen Landsknechte, pp. 36–42.
168. Ibid., p. 107, also describes cases where, for reasons which the texts do not
make clear, the colonel might choose to try the soldier before a tribunal of the
soldiers, where the verdict would be reached by popular vote; Frauenholz,
Heerwesen, II, Pt 2, pp. 38–9.
169. A detailed contemporary acount of the involvement of the company in the
administration of justice is given in L. Fronsperger, Kriegsordnung und
Notes to pages 65–9 341
Regiment, sampt derselbigen befehl, statt und Ampter zu Roß und zu Fuß . . .
(Frankfurt, 1564), lxx recto–lxxv verso; all of this, whether by conscious
borrowing, or shared tradition, exactly reflected the Swiss procedures:
Sennhauser, Hauptmann und Führung, pp. 53–4.
170. The soldiers’ perception of their social status was reflected in this view of the
executioner, his assistants and guards as ‘dishonourable’, set outside the
‘regiment’/corporation by their performance of these roles: W. Danckert,
Unehrliche Leute. Die Verfemten Berufe (Berne and Munich, 1963), pp. 36–49;
K. Stuart, Defiled Trades and Social Outcasts. Honour and Ritual Pollution in
Early Modern Germany (Cambridge, 1999), pp. 69–93.
171. See, for example, the case from Sennhauser of a Swiss captain killed by one
of his men for trying to restrain him from stealing goods from the collective
booty of the unit, and the soldier then being protected by his company:
Hauptmann und Führung, p. 86.
172. Möller, Regiment der Landsknechte, pp. 202–8.
173. Zwiedineck-Südenhorst, Kriegsbilder, pp. 192–3.
174. Padrutt, Staat und Krieg, p. 136.
175. For the Swiss Kriegsrat see Elgger, Kriegswesen, pp. 195–6; Frauenholz,
Heerwesen, II, Pt 1, pp. 47–51.
176. See, for example, I. Clendinnen, ‘The Cost of Courage in Aztec Society’,
Past and Present, 94 (1982), 44–89.
177. B. Bei der Wieden, ‘Niederdeutsche Söldner vor dem Dreißigjährigen Krieg.
Geistige und mentale Grenzen eines sozialen Raums’, in B. Kroener and
R. Pröve (eds.), Krieg und Frieden. Militär und Gesellschaft in der Frühen
Neuzeit (Paderborn, 1996), pp. 85–107; Burschel, Söldner, pp. 27–53.
178. Rogg, Landsknechte, pp. 18–143; J.R. Hale, Artists and Warfare in the
Renaissance (New Haven and London, 1990), pp. 1–72; Hale, ‘The Soldier
in Germanic Graphic Art of the Renaissance’, in R. Rothberg and T. Rabb,
Art and History. Images and their Meanings (Cambridge, 1988), pp. 85–114.
179. For example, Hedegaard, Landsknaegtene, p. 28 for the strident condemna-
tion of Peder Palladius, bishop of Zealand, in 1555; Blau, Deutschen
Landsknechte, pp. 113–20 on the contemporary condemnation of the
Pluderhosen (fashionable, puffed-out breeches, often tied at the knee).
180. M. Rogg, ‘“Zerhauen und zerschnitten, nach adelichen Sitten”. Herkunft,
Entwicklung und Funktion soldatischer Tracht des 16 Jahrhundert im
Spiegel zeitgenössischer Kunst’, in Kroener and Pröve (eds.), Krieg und
Frieden, 109–35; M. Rogg, ‘“Wol auff mit mir, du schoenes weyb”.
Anmerkungen zur Konstruktion von Männlichkeit im Soldatenbild des 16.
Jahrhunderts’, in K. Hagemann and R. Pröve (eds.), Landsknechte,
Soldatenfrauen und Nationakrieger (Frankurt am Main, 1998), pp. 51–73.
181. J. Lipsius, Sixe Bookes of Politickes or Civil Doctrine (London, 1594; facsimile
edn, Amsterdam and New York, 1970), p. 157.
182. Blau, Deutschen Landsknechte, pp. 98–104, from whose 1880s account all
mention of the Hurenwaibel and whores has been carefully excised; cf. also
pp. 27–9 on regimental officers.
183. Burschel, Söldner, pp. 248–52, 257–8: ‘Ohne Huren kein Krieg’.
184. Baumann, Landsknechte, pp. 150–1.
185. Burschel, Söldner, pp. 129–45.
342 Notes to pages 71–3
NOTES TO CHAPTER 2
1. F. Baumgartner, Henry II, King of France, 1547–1559 (Durham, NC and
London, 1988), p. 87.
2. A. Orlandi, Le Grand Parti. Fiorentini a Lione e il debito pubblico Francese nel
XVI secolo (Florence, 2002); R. Doucet, ‘Le Grand Parti de Lyon au XVIe
siècle’, Revue historique, 171 and 172 (1933 and 1934), pp. 473–513, 1–41;
R. Ehrenberg, Das Zeitalter der Fugger: Geldkapital und Creditverkehr im 16.
Jahrhundert (2 vols., Jena, 1896), II, pp. 93–107.
3. M.J. Rodríguez-Salgado, The Changing Face of Empire. Charles V, Philip II and
Habsburg Authority, 1551–59 (Cambridge, 1988), pp. 139–40.
4. J. Tracy, A Financial Revolution in the Habsburg Netherlands. Renten and
Renteniers in the County of Holland, 1515–1565 (London, 1985), pp. 91–107;
Rodríguez-Salgado, Empire, pp. 55–9.
5. Ehrenberg, Fugger, II., pp. 91–3; Doucet suggests that the project for the
Grand Parti had its origins in the levels of military expenditure from 1542:
‘Grand Parti’, pp. 475–6.
6. Doucet, ‘Grand Parti’, p. 507.
7. Ehrenberg, Fugger, II, pp. 104–7.
8. H. Hauser, ‘The European Financial Crisis of 1559’, Journal of Economic and
Business History, 2 (1929–30), pp. 241–55; Ehrenberg, Fugger, II, pp. 159–69.
9. D. Potter, Renaissance France at War. Armies, Culture and Society, c.1480–1560
(Woodbridge, 2008), pp. 212–20, demonstrates this massively increasing
financial burden of the 1550s via a series of bar charts.
10. Rodríguez-Salgado, Empire, pp. 238–42; Ehrenberg, Fugger, II, pp. 147–59.
11. Rodríguez-Salgado, Empire, pp. 240–52.
12. The chancellor, Michel de L’Hôpital, announced to the Estates General of
1560 that the crown’s debt stood at 43 million livres, of which more than
15 million was contracted at ‘grands et insupportables intérêts’: Doucet,
‘Grand Parti’, 172, p. 9.
13. This statement contradicts the apparent evidence of a number of widely cited
tables showing comparative European army sizes from 1500 to 1700, which
indicate an apparently vast growth in military establishments during the 1620s
and 1630s. However, almost all of that projected growth is based on mislead-
ing documents and statements by contemporaries which need qualification: a
few short-term ‘surges’ in military strength are not evidence of a real and
permanent growth in military establishments. In practice the military mobi-
lization atttained in the 1550s was not significantly and lastingly surpassed
until the later seventeenth century.
14. A. Guéry, ‘La naissance financière de l’état moderne en France’, in J. Bouvier
and J.-C. Perrot, États, fiscalités, economies (Paris, 1985), pp. 53–62; Guéry,
‘Les finances de la monarchie française sous l’Ancien Régime’, Annales ESC,
33 (1978), 216–39, pp. 223–8.
15. J. Collins, Fiscal Limits of Absolutism. Direct Taxation in Early Seventeenth-
Century France (Berkeley, CA, 1988), pp. 48–64; P. Hamon, L’argent du roi.
Les finances sous François I (Paris, 1994), pp. 135–247; J. Tracy, Emperor
Charles V, Impresario of War (Cambridge, 2002), pp. 95–108, 249–303.
Notes to pages 73–8 343
16. J.R. Hale, War and Society in Renaissance Europe, 1450–1620 (London, 1985),
pp. 232–52, is robustly dismissive of the extent to which the demands of war
could overcome these political limitations.
17. Figures from F. Lot, Recherches sur les effectifs des armées françaises des Guerres
d’Italie aux Guerres de Religion, 1494–1562 (Paris, 1962), pp. 125–88.
18. J. Glete, Navies and Nations. Warships, Navies and State-Building in Europe and
America, 1500–1860 (2 vols., Stockholm, 1993), II, pp. 504–6.
19. S. Gunn, D. Grummitt and H. Cools, War, State and Society in England and
the Netherlands, 1477–1559 (Oxford, 2007), p. 27.
20. S. Pepper and N. Adams, Firearms and Fortifications: Military Architecture and
Siege Warfare in Sixteenth-Century Siena (Chicago, 1986), pp. 3–31; C. Duffy,
Siege Warfare. The Fortress in the Early Modern World, 1494–1660 (London,
1979), pp. 1–105.
21. G. Parker, The Military Revolution. Military Innovation and the Rise of the West,
1500–1800 (2nd edn, Cambridge, 1996), p. 12.
22. N.A.M. Rodger, ‘The Development of Broadside Gunnery, 1450–1650’, The
Mariner’s Mirror, 82 (1996), 301–24.
23. G. Parker, ‘The Dreadnought Revolution of the Sixteenth Century’, The
Mariner’s Mirror, 82 (1996), 269–300, p. 286 gives the example of Philip II,
who by the end of 1588 had commissioned twelve new warships, each dis-
placing 1,500 tons.
24. Glete, Navies and Nations, I, pp. 36–7.
25. Even the Habsburg rulers of the Netherlands, for whom the availability of a
vast pool of merchant shipping had previously discouraged direct ship own-
ership, started to fit out purpose-built warships with substantially heavier
armaments from the 1550s: L. Sicking, Neptune and the Netherlands. State,
Economy and War at Sea in the Renaissance (Brill, 2004), pp. 376–90.
26. J. Guilmartin, Gunpowder and Galleys. Changing Technology and Mediterranean
Warfare at Sea in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge, 1974), pp. 194–220.
27. For France, it can be assumed for the period 1500–59 that the largest part of
the expenses of the extraordinaire des guerres was for foreign mercenaries (the
gendarmerie and heavy cavalry were funded from the ordinaire); the dramatic
rise in the costs of mercenaries is strongly evident: Potter, France at War,
pp. 215–18, 356–7.
28. R. Baumann, Landsknechte (Munich, 1994), p. 87.
29. An extensive literature on this subject reflects recent research and thinking
about the nature of the early modern state, and in particular the compromises
and negotiations at the heart of most early modern fiscal systems: see, for
example, Tracy, Financial Revolution; W. Beik, Absolutism and Society in
Seventeenth-Century France: State Power and Provincial Aristocracy in
Languedoc (Cambridge, 1985), pp. 245–78; M. Potter, Corps and Clienteles.
Public Finance and Political Change in France, 1688–1715 (Aldershot, 2003),
pp. 3–25; H. Root, The Fountain of Privilege. Political Foundations of Markets in
Old Regime France and England (Berkeley, CA, 1994), pp. 23–40.
30. M. Burin de Roziers, Les capitulations militaires entre la Suisse et la France
(doctoral thesis, University of Paris, 1902), pp. 97–8; Potter, France at War,
pp. 124–51; Redlich, I, p. 48.
344 Notes to pages 78–83
31. G. Parker, The Army of Flanders and the Spanish Road (2nd edn, Cambridge,
2004), pp. 32–3; Redlich, I, pp. 56–7.
32. R. Baumann, Georg von Frundsberg. Der Vater der Landsknechte (Munich,
1984), shows how the most famous of all the Landsknecht commanders was
ruined by ‘irrational’ financial behaviour in the context of short-term merce-
nary contracts: see especially Frundsberg’s reported comments – p. 297.
33. For Blaise de Monluc, the Swiss were ‘vrais gens de guerre’, but had also been
the cause of great losses and damage to the king’s affairs by their rapacious
behaviour and demands ‘to be paid in money, not words’: Commentaires
(Paris, 1964), pp. 31–2, referring to the defeat at La Bicocca. For a passionate
contemporary denunciation of the use of foreign mercenaries in place of
native French troops see Guillaume du Bellay, Instructions sur le faict de la
Guerre, extraictes des livres de Polybe, Frontin, Vegece, Cornazan, Machiavelle, &
plusieurs autres bons autheurs (Paris, 1553), Book One, pp. 13–21r.
34. Baumann, Landsknechte, p. 114.
35. Glete, Navies and Nations, I, p. 14.
36. This latter problem is admittedly less pressing in the case of galleys, which are
simple and light enough to be deconstructed and laid up in store: P. Williams,
‘Piracy and Naval Conflict in the Mediterranean, 1590–1620’ (D.Phil. thesis,
Oxford University, 2001), pp. 17–18.
37. Williams, ‘Piracy’, pp. 11–16, 32–6.
38. J. Glete, Warfare at Sea, 1500–1650. Maritime Conflicts and the Transformation
of Europe (London, 2000), p. 66.
39. Glete, Navies and Nations, I, pp. 140–2.
40. I.A.A. Thompson, War and Government in Habsburg Spain, 1560–1620
(London, 1976), pp. 226–33. As Thompson points out, this was not always
a correct assumption, and the chronic financial weakness of early modern
states could lead to default even in areas where it was clear that the conse-
quences would undermine any military effectiveness.
41. C. Fusero, I Doria (Milan,1973), pp. 388–404.
42. G. Doria, ‘Conoscenza del mercato e sistema informativo: il know-how dei
mercanti-finanzieri genovesi nei secoli XVI e XVII’, in A. de Maddalena and
H. Kellenbenz (eds.), La republica internazionale del denaro tra XV e XVII
secolo. Annali dell’Istituto storico italo-germanico 20 (Bologna, 1986),
pp. 57–121, pp. 66–7; Guilmartin, Gunpowder and Galleys, pp. 25–6;
T. Kirk, Genoa and the Sea. Policy and Power in an Early Modern Maritime
Republic, 1559–1684 (Baltimore and London, 2005), p. 41.
43. Kirk, Genoa, p. 67, n. 37.
44. Kirk, Genoa, p. 42; Thompson, War and Government, p. 32; R. Savelli,
‘Giovanni (Gian) Andrea Doria’, in Dizionario Biografico degli Italiani
(Rome, 1960–), XLI, pp. 361–75.
45. Kirk, Genoa, p. 44; Williams, ‘Piracy’, pp. 32–6.
46. Kirk, Genoa, pp. 112–16, though Kirk stresses the chimerical character of
most of these self-funding aspirations.
47. This had been the means to augment the very limited permanent naval
resources in the Habsburg Netherlands throughout the first half of the six-
teenth century: Sicking, Neptune and the Netherlands, pp. 370–8, 407–19.
Notes to pages 84–7 345
48. Glete, Navies and Nations, I, pp. 53–5; J. Guilmartin, Galleons and Galleys
(London, 2002), pp. 158–81.
49. Glete, Navies and Nations, I, p. 141; F.W. Carter, Dubrovnik (Ragusa).
A Classic City State (London, 1972), pp. 308–13, 392–5.
50. Thompson, War and Government, pp. 193–9; D. Goodman, Spanish Naval
Power, 1589–1665. Reconstruction and Defeat (Cambridge, 1997), p. 30, gives
the later example of Jerónimo Masibradi, who served Philip IV from 1624
until his death in 1650 at the head of a squadron of six Ragusan galleons, after
which the contract was continued by his heirs.
51. V. Kostic, Ragusa and the Spanish Armada (Belgrade, 1972), pp. 205–7.
52. Glete, Navies and Nations, I, p. 149.
53. Kirk, Genoa, p. 45.
54. P.W. Klein, ‘The Trip Family in the Seventeenth Century: a Study of the
Behaviour of the Entrepreneur on the Dutch Staple Market’, Acta Historiae
Neerlandica, 1 (1966), 187–211, p. 201; J. Bruijn, The Dutch Navy of the
Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries (Columbia, SC, 1993), p. 24.
55. Glete, Navies and Nations, I, p. 155.
56. Klein, ‘Trip Family’, p. 201; A. James, Navy and Government in Early Modern
France, 1572–1661 (London, 2004), p. 73, gives five warships and a number of
lighter vessels, and, p. 113, emphasizes that these were the largest and most
heavily armed vessels in the navy in the 1620s. Four warships had been
ordered from the Dutch for French Mediterranean use back in 1618
(p. 94), and another six were to be delivered in the later 1630s (p. 116).
57. Klein, ‘Trip Family’, p. 198.
58. E. Dahlgren, Louis de Geer, 1587–1652, Hans lif och verk (2 vols., Uppsala,
1923), II, pp. 441–505; R.C. Anderson, Naval Wars in the Baltic, 1522–1850
(1910; repr. London, 1969), pp. 47–50; N. Probst, ‘Naval Operations during
the Torstensson War, 1643–45’, Revue internationale d’histoire militaire,
84 (2004); G. Edmundson, ‘Louis de Geer’, English Historical Review,
6 (1891), 685–712, pp. 702–9.
59. Dahlgren, De Geer, II, p. 491.
60. A large-scale example from the early 1630s involving the Genoese Centurión
family in R. Mackay, The Limits of Royal Authority. Resistance and Obedience in
Seventeenth-Century Castile (Cambridge, 1999), p. 51.
61. J. Wood, The King’s Army. Warfare, Soldiers and Society during the Wars of
Religion in France, 1562–1576 (Cambridge, 1996), pp. 55–66.
62. M. Greengrass, ‘Pieces of the Jigsaw: Making Sense of French Taxation under the
Last Valois, 1574–1589’, in M. Ormrod, R. Bonney and M. Bonney (eds.), Crises,
Revolutions and Self-Sustained Growth. Essays in European Fiscal History, 1130–
1830 (Stamford, UK, 1999), pp. 138–69; Wood, King’s Army, pp. 275–86.
63. H. Koenigsberger, ‘The Organization of Revolutionary Parties in France and
the Netherlands during the Sixteenth Century’, in Koenigsberger, Estates and
Revolutions (Ithaca, 1971), pp. 224–52, pp. 227–30; R. Harding, Anatomy of a
Power Elite. The Provincial Governors of Early Modern France (New Haven,
1978), pp. 58–9.
64. J. de Pablo, ‘L’armée huguenote entre 1562 et 1573’, Archiv für
Reformationsgeschichte, 48 (1957), 192–216, pp. 198–201; M. Wolfe, The Fiscal
346 Notes to pages 88–91
NOTES TO CHAPTER 3
1. Wallenstein contributed 40,000 florins of his own funds to the recruitment:
K. Koch, ‘Wallenstein 1583–1625’ (Dissertation, Düsseldorf, 1908–9), p. 12.
2. A. de Villermont, Ernest de Mansfeldt (2 vols., Brussels, 1865), I, pp. 77–80.
3. Villermont, Mansfeldt, I, pp. 104–5, 251–66.
4. O. Chaline, La bataille de la Montagne Blanche. Un mystique chez les guerriers
(Paris, 2000), pp. 82–4; Villermont, Mansfeldt, I, pp. 296–9.
5. C. Jarrys de La Roche, Die Dreißigjährige Krieg vom militärischen Standpunkte
aus beleuchtet (3 vols., Schaffhausen, 1848), I, pp. 77–82; Villermont,
Mansfeldt, II, pp. 395–8, letter from Mansfeld to Frederick, 19 May 1621.
6. Villermont, Mansfeldt, II, pp. 71–6.
7. An army which, including the forces of Christian of Halberstadt, totalled
around 21,000 infantry and 8,000 cavalry: Villermont, Mansfeldt, II, p. 71.
8. Villermont, Mansfeldt, II, pp. 120–31. The hostile Villermont sees all of these
manoeuvres to gain subsidy treaties as pure opportunism by a cynical manip-
ulator, and details all the attempts by ‘le Bâtard’ to win similar deals with the
Catholic powers.
9. Villermont, Mansfeldt, II, pp. 240–6; P. Lockhart, Denmark in the Thirty Years
War, 1618–48 (Selinsgrove, 1996), pp. 129, 136.
10. The contemporary of Mansfeld, Christian of Brunswick, provided a very
similar model: see H. Wertheim, Der tolle Halberstädter, Herzog Christian von
Braunschweig (2 vols., Berlin, 1929). And at least one Catholic general con-
tractor, Charles IV of Lorraine, operated on the same terms after his duchy
had been occupied by the French from the 1630s.
11. G. Droysen, Bernhard von Weimar (2 vols., Leipzig, 1885), I, pp. 27–32.
12. Droysen, Weimar, I, pp. 150–60.
Notes to pages 108–11 351
102. A. von Wrede, Geschichte der K. und K. Wehrmacht. Die Regimenter, Corps,
Branchen und Anstalten von 1618 bis Ende des XIX Jahrhunderts (5 vols.,
Vienna, 1898–1903); vols. I and III (2) provide details of regiments of infantry
and cavalry in the Imperial army established and dissolved from 1618.
103. J. Glete, Swedish Naval Administration, 1521–1721 (Leiden, 2010), pp. 252,
663–4; M. Roberts, Gustavus Adolphus. A History of Sweden, 1611–32
(2 vols., London, 1958), II, pp. 272–94.
104. Glete, War, p. 203; R. Frost, The Northern Wars, 1558–1721 (London,
2000), pp. 127–8.
105. T. Lorentzen, Die Schwedische Armee im Dreißigjährigen Kriege (Leipzig,
1894), p. 8; Fallon, ‘Scottish Mercenaries’, pp. 261–301.
106. H. Landberg, L. Ekholm, R. Nordlund and S. Nilsson (eds.), Det kontinen-
tala krigets ekonomie. Studier i krigsfinansierung under svensk stormaktstid
(Kristianstad, 1971), p. 459.
107. Fallon, ‘Scottish Mercenaries’, pp. 43–5.
108. Landberg et al. (eds.), Krigets ekonomie, pp. 463–7.
109. S. Lundkvist, ‘Schwedische Kriegsfinanzierung, 1630–35’, in H. Rudolf
(ed.), Der Dreißigjährigen Krieg: Perspectiven and Strukturen (Darmstadt,
1977), pp. 298–303; Böhme, ‘Geld’, p. 54.
110. Lorentzen, Schwedische Armee, pp. 8–9. Pappenheim reported to Wallenstein
on 18 November 1630 that Knyphausen had commissions to raise six
regiments of troops for Gustavus, but instructions not to start recruitment
until early January: DBB, IV, p. 338.
111. Heilmann, Kriegswesen, p. 161; A. Grosjean ‘Scotland: Sweden’s Closest
Ally?’, in S. Murdoch (ed.), Scotland and the Thirty Years War, 1618–48
(Brill, 2001), pp. 143–71, pp. 145–51.
112. Lorentzen, Schwedische Armee, p. 36. This continued through the rest of the
war: see, for example, G. Björlin, Johan Banér (3 vols., Stockholm, 1908–
10), III, pp. 631–2 – Banér’s army at Stettin, 16 July 1638.
113. Redlich, I, pp. 255–6.
114. Droysen, Weimar, I, pp. 147–9.
115. The system was also practised in central and north Germany under Swedish
occupation: Banér was granted a large part of the city and surrounding
territory of Magdeburg as a contribution to his military expenses:
Lorentzen, Schwedische Armee, p. 28.
116. H. Laber, ‘Die Schweden in Augsburg von 1632 bis 1635’, in Münchener
Historische Abhandlungen, 2nd ser. Kriegs- und Heeresgeschichte, Vol. I
(Munich, 1932), pp. 22–7.
117. R. Hildebrandt, ‘Handel und Kapitalverkehr um 1630. Außenwirtschaftliche
Beziehungen Deutschlands im Dreißigjährigen Krieg’, in J. Schneider (ed.),
Wirtschaftskräfte und Wirtschaftswege V. Festschrift für Hermann Kellenbenz
(Stuttgart, 1981), pp. 135–59, p. 146.
118. Hildebrandt, ‘Handel und Kapitalverkehr’, p. 140.
119. Laber, ‘Schweden in Augsburg’, pp. 37–8; F. Blendinger, ‘Augsburger
Handel im Dreißigjährigen Krieg’, in J. Schneider (ed.), Wirtschaftskräfte
und Wirtschaftswege II. Festschrift für Hermann Kellenbenz (Stuttgart, 1978),
pp. 287–323, pp. 335–6.
Notes to pages 129–34 357
143. Böhme, ‘Geld’, pp. 68–9; this visible partitioning of the financial allocations
had been started in 1632–4: Friedlaender, ‘Protokoll’.
144. Useful tables of regiments provided in W. Guthrie, The Later Thirty Years
War (Westport, CT, 2003), pp. 105–55.
145. F. von Geyso, ‘Beiträge zur Politik und Kriegsführung Hessens im Zeitalter
des Dreißigjährigen Krieges’, Zeitschrift für Hessische Geschichte, 53 (1921),
14–30.
146. C. Leestmans, Charles IV de Lorraine, 1604–75. Une errance baroque (Lasne,
2003), pp. 43–71.
147. See, for example, the blend of public–private arrangements detailed for the
Spanish recruitment of Irish soldiers in the 1640s and 1650s in R. Stradling,
The Spanish Monarchy and Irish Mercenaries. The Wild Geese in Spain,
1618–68 (Dublin, 1994), pp. 143–52.
NOTES TO CHAPTER 4
1. Comte Jacques de Guibert, Essai général de tactique (1772), ed. J.-P. Bois,
(Paris, 2004), p. 29: ‘Ce fut le temps des grands généraux, commandant de
petites armées et faisant de grandes choses . . .’
2. B. Stadler, Pappenheim und die Zeit des Dreißigjährigen Krieges (Winterthur,
1991), p. 577.
3. Stadler, Pappenheim, p. 612: ‘auserlesen volck, starck und überaus begierig zu
fechten’.
4. Stadler, Pappenheim, pp. 591–4.
5. Stadler, Pappenheim, pp. 656–7, 692–3.
6. Stadler, Pappenheim, pp. 689–90.
7. P. Villiers, Les corsaires du Littoral. Dunkerque, Calais, Boulogne de Philip II à
Louis XIV (1568–1713) (Lille, 2000), pp. 62–75; R. Stradling, The Armada of
Flanders (Cambridge, 1992), pp. 167–9.
8. H. Malo, Les corsaires dunkerquois et Jean Bart (2 vols., Paris, 1912/13), I, p. 298.
9. Malo, Corsaires, I, pp. 320–1; J. Israel, The Dutch Republic and the Hispanic
World, 1606–1661 (Oxford, 1982), pp. 264–5.
10. Account from Stradling, Armada, pp. 86–7, who cites eighty-nine trawlers
and five Dutch warships sunk.
11. Malo, Corsaires, I, pp. 322–3.
12. Stradling, Armada of Flanders, p. 87; Israel, Dutch Republic and Hispanic World,
p. 265.
13. J. Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 1585–1740 (Oxford, 1989), pp. 134–40;
Malo, Corsaires, I, pp. 335–42.
14. M. Kaiser, ‘“Sed vincere sciebat Hanibal”. Pappenheim als empirischer
Theoretiker des Krieges’, in H. Neuhaus and B. Stollberg-Rilinger (eds.),
Menschen und Strukturen in der Geschichte Alteuropas (Berlin, 2002), pp. 201–27,
pp. 219–23.
15. Stradling, Armada of Flanders, pp. 96–7.
16. R. Weigley, The Age of Battles. The Quest for Decisive Warfare from Breitenfeld to
Waterloo (Bloomington, IN, 1991), pp. 1–23. The perception that Breitenfeld
was ‘no ordinary victory’ probably derives from H. Delbrück, History of the Art
Notes to pages 145–7 359
28. J. Heilmann, Das Kriegswesen der Kaiserlichen und Schweden zur Zeit des
Dreißigjährigen Krieges (Leipzig, 1850; repr. Krefeld, 1977), p. 66, points out
that the great disadvantage of the light ‘leather guns’ pioneered then aban-
doned by Gustavus Adolphus was that they overheated after a few shots.
29. Heilmann, Kriegswesen, pp. 51–73.
30. Heilmann, Kriegswesen, pp. 279–85, prints an état of the French artillery
battery in 1646 showing guns of between six and twenty-four pound shot,
the six-pounders requiring six horses to move them; Parrott, Richelieu’s Army,
pp. 69–70.
31. For a detailed, modern battle history from which this seems the obvious
conclusion, see W. Guthrie, Battles of the Thirty Years War from White
Mountain to Nördlingen 1618–35 (Westport, CT, 2002) and Guthrie, Later
Thirty Years War. It is a view confirmed in P. Wilson’s magisterial new history,
Europe’s Tragedy. A History of the Thirty Years War (London, 2009), where
Wilson points explicitly to the tendency to denigrate the military flexibility
and capabilities of the Imperial armies: pp. 84–97.
32. Though even in the period supposedly dominated by choreographed siege
warfare, a recent work points out the frequency with which these methodical
approaches were overruled in favour of direct assault, which entailed high risk
and casualties but saved time and money: J. Ostwald, Vauban under Siege.
Engineering Efficiency and Martial Vigor in the War of the Spanish Succession
(Brill, 2007), pp. 215–321.
33. G. Parker, The Military Revolution. Military Innovation and the Rise of the West,
1500–1800 (2nd edn, Cambridge, 1996), pp. 7–16, 83–103, and Parker, ‘The
Dreadnought Revolution of the Sixteenth Century’, The Mariner’s Mirror,
82 (1996), 269–300.
34. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 127–61.
35. R. Manning, An Apprenticeship in Arms. The Origins of the British Army,
1585–1702 (Oxford, 2006), pp. 108–19; Israel, Dutch Republic and the
Hispanic World, pp. 280–1.
36. Israel, Dutch Republic and the Hispanic World, pp. 269–71; M. Bellamy,
Christian IV and his Navy (Brill, 2006), p. 23.
37. Rheinfelden, in 1638, involved Saxe-Weimar’s extraordinary feat of reassem-
bling his army after an initial defeat at the hands of Jan de Werth, and
launching a surprise attack on the Imperial forces three days later which
gained him an overwhelming victory: G. Droysen, Bernhard von Weimar
(2 vols., Leipzig, 1885), II, pp. 336–46.
38. Guthrie, Later Thirty Years War, p. 121 (Breitenfeld II), pp. 140–1 (Jankow).
39. It is often the case that troops who have held their ground in a hard-fought
combat and are then expected to abandon these positions in what will be seen
as a retreat, even for the best of tactical reasons, are prone to demoralization
and disillusionment. A classic case was the 1645 Bavarian ‘defeat’ at
Nördlingen II/Allerheim, where the decision to retreat after inflicting massive
casualties on the French army led to the collapse of Bavarian morale and mass
surrenders: J. Heilmann, Die Feldzüge der Bayern in den Jahren 1643, 1644,
1645 unter den Befehlen des Feldmarschalls Franz Freiherrn von Mercy (Leipzig,
1851), pp. 270–303.
Notes to pages 152–8 361
40. V. Kiernan, ‘Foreign Mercenaries and Absolute Monarchy’, Past and Present,
11 (1956–7), 66–86, p. 78.
41. H. d’Orleans, duc d’Aumale, Histoire des princes de Condé pendant les XVIe et
XVIIe siècles (7 vols., Paris, 1893–6), IV, pp. 139–77, esp. pp. 145–9.
42. B.P. von Chemnitz, Der Königlich Schwedische in Teutschland geführte Krieg
(4 vols., 2 only extant; Rideholm, 1855), IV (v), p. 33: on Torstensson’s
campaign plan to force a major battle and then press deep into the Habsburg
lands; L. Höbelt, Ferdinand III (Graz, 2008), pp. 231–5; P. Broucek, Der
Schwedenfeldzug nach Niederösterreich, 1645–46 (Vienna, 1967), pp. 6–8.
43. Monro, His Expedition with the worthy Scots Regiment called Mac-Keys, ed.
W. Brocklington (Westport, CT, 1999), p. 235.
44. O. van Nimwegen, ‘Deser landen crijchsvolck’. Het Staatse leger en de militaire
revoluties, 1588–1688 (Amsterdam, 2006), pp. 127–30; M. Gutmann, War
and Rural Life in the Early Modern Low Countries (Princeton, 1980), pp. 62–4
examines a later set of treaties between France and the Spanish Netherlands.
45. K.-R. Böhme, ‘Geld für die schwedischen Armeen nach 1640’, Scandia,
33 (1967), 54–95, p. 79, gives the example of Königsmarck ending the pay-
ment of protection money by the bishopric of Verden in 1647 by simply
overrunning the Imperial garrisons in Westphalia which had been making
the demands.
46. Heilmann, Feldzüge der Bayern, pp. 61–92.
47. Manning, Apprenticeship, pp. 44–7; it was state-coordinated military opera-
tions that were most likely to draw excessively heavily upon such low-quality
conscripts, and often for reasons that were overtly linked to social order and
removing a financial charge on local communities: see D. Trim, ‘Fighting
“Jacob’s Wars”. The Employment of English and Welsh Mercenaries in the
European Wars of Religion: France and the Netherlands, 1562–1610’ (Ph.D.
thesis, King’s College London, 2002), pp. 226–35.
48. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, pp. 245–6.
49. H. Salm, Armeefinanzierung im Dreißigjährigen Krieg (Münster, 1990), p. 35,
quoting Imperial Field Marshal Hatzfeld in 1644.
50. The inception and diffusion of this military theory amongst a narrow group of
Calvinist princely families and their in-laws deserves more sceptical attention,
in the same way that the later sixteenth-century campaigns in the Netherlands
have been given undue emphasis as a ‘school of war’ over the Hungarian
theatre of war from 1593 to 1606: Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 27–32.
51. R. Williams, A Briefe Discourse of Warre (London, 1590), p. 6.
52. P. Burschel, Söldner im Nordwestdeutschland des 16. und 17. Jahrhunderts.
Sozialgeschichtliche Studien (Göttingen, 1994), p. 79, n. 106; G. Parker, The
Army of Flanders and the Spanish Road, 1567–1659 (2nd edn, Cambridge,
2004), pp. 27–9; Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 44–6; C. Kapser, Die bayerische
Kriegsorganisation in der zweiten Hälfte des Dreißigjährigen Krieges, 1635–1648/
49 (Münster, 1997), pp. 68–70, 262–3.
53. One of the literary sources most frequently cited in this context,
Grimmelshausen’s Simplicissimus, trans. S. Goodrich (Sawtry, 1989), cer-
tainly does not suggest that all soldiers are a feeble, duty-shirking rabble,
recruited at the lowest price by exploitative officers: see, for example, the
362 Notes to pages 159–61
implicit view of ‘real’ soldiers in book IV, chapter 11, ‘Discourse of the Order
of the Marauder Brothers’ (Merode-brüder).
54. M. Duffy, ‘The Foundations of British Naval Power’, in Duffy (ed.), The
Military Revolution and the State (Exeter, 1980), pp. 49–85, pp. 67–72: though
of course when wages failed to attract enough of each group, impressment, at
least in the British navy, took its place.
55. G. Frachetta, Il Prencipe, nel quale si considera il Prencipe, & quanto al governo
dello Stato, & quanto al maneggio della Guerra (Venice, 1599), p. 208, places
inexperienced recruits into three categories in terms of their exposure to
campaigning.
56. Kaiser, Politik und Kriegsführung, pp. 272–3, who argues that this was encour-
aged by Wallenstein, who saw it as useful in both strengthening his own army
and weakening the independence of the Liga.
57. B. Kroener, ‘Der Soldat als Ware. Kriegsgefangenenschicksale im 16.
und 17. Jahrhundert’, in H. Duchhardt and P. Veit (eds.), Krieg und
Frieden im Übergang vom Mittelalter zur Neuzeit (Mainz, 2000),
pp. 271–95, pp. 282–3, though Kroener is sceptical about the real extent
of such incorporation.
58. J. Peters (ed.), Ein Söldnerleben im Dreißigjährigen Krieg (Berlin, 1993),
pp. 143–6. For the identity of the soldier, taken from what is an anonymous
manuscript, see P. Burschel, ‘Himmelreich und Hölle. Ein Söldner, sein
Tagebuch und die Ordnungen des Krieges’, in B. von Krusenstjern and
H. Medick (eds.), Zwischen Alltag und Katastrophe. Der Dreißigjährige Krieg
aus der Nähe (Göttingen, 2001), pp. 181–94, pp. 184–5.
59. Williams, Discourse, pp. 12–13.
60. For example, Frachetta, Il Prencipe, pp. 207–8.
61. DBB, IV, p. 143: Wallenstein to the Emperor, 2 September 1626 (Olmütz):
‘erfahren, kriegstüchtig Soldaten’. Jan de Werth drew heavily on experienced
Italian recruits in raising a new cavalry regiment for Bavarian service in 1644:
H. Lahrkamp, Jan von Werth (Cologne, 1962), p. 209.
62. P. Burschel, Söldner, pp. 145–65.
63. B. Kroener, ‘Soldat oder Soldateska? Programmatischer Aufriß einer
Sozialgeschichte militärische Unterschichten in der Ersten Hälfte des 17.
Jahrhunderts’, in Kroener, Kriegerische Gewalt und militärische Präsenz in der
Neuzeit (Paderborn, 2008), pp. 125–51, p. 126, who points out that the word
only gained pejorative connotations through later seventeenth-century
French usage.
64. Redlich, I, p. 485. Pay for ordinary Reiter in the sixteenth century in S. Fiedler,
Kriegswesen und Kriegsführung im Zeitalter der Landsknechte (Koblenz. 1985),
p. 96, and corroborated in other texts.
65. Heilmann, Kriegswesen, p. 156: this sum (25 talers) was paid by Wallenstein’s
colonels for good infantry recruits. For the high wages paid by Christian IV to
his mercenaries compared with those in the United Provinces see J. Fallon,
‘Scottish Mercenaries in the Service of Denmark and Sweden, 1626–32’
(Ph.D. thesis, University of Glasgow, 1972), p. 200.
66. Gindely, Waldstein, I, pp. 131–3: ordinances for the payment of the army in the
Altmark and Schleswig-Holstein in 1627 stipulated wages of 1¼ talers per week
Notes to pages 161–3 363
for the ordinary soldiers, roughly 7 florins per month, with wages between 1½
and 2½ talers for ‘double-pay men’ (Gefreiten and Landspassaten).
67. Heilman, Kriegswesen, pp. 190–3, indicates that the wages in the Swedish
army were consistently lower than those of the Imperial. If the average wage
of the Imperial musketeer in this period was 6 florins per month, in the
Swedish army it was just under 5 (3½ talers).
68. G. Freytag, Der Dreißigjährigen Krieg. Das Heer. Soldatenleben und Sitten (1859;
repr. Bad Langensalza, 2003), pp. 112–13; Heilmann, Kriegwesen,
pp. 169–79; Redlich, I, pp. 487–9; Pohl, ‘Die Profiantirung der keyserlichen
Armaden ahnbelangendt’. Studien zur Versorgung der kaiserlichen Armee,
1634–35 (Vienna, 1994), pp. 37–8, 63–5.
69. Burschel, Söldner, pp. 167–9; Fallon, ‘Scottish Mercenaries’, pp. 379–80.
70. Burschel, Söldner, pp. 188–92.
71. The soldier Peter Hagendorf makes frequent reference to the quality of
accommodation and food in his Tagebuch: Peters, Söldnerleben, cf. pp. 136,
139, 141, 146, 149, 150, etc.; Redlich, I, p. 491, cites a Swedish soldiers’ song
praising Gustavus Adolphus for giving the soldiers good quarters and food,
even though he did not pay them much money; Fallon, ‘Scottish
Mercenaries’, pp. 380–2.
72. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, p. 252.
73. Jean de Werth was paying between 7 and 10 gulden in 1644 for troops
depending on whether they were experienced or new recruits, and up to 15
gulden for experienced troops recruited in Italy: Lahrkamp, Jan von Werth,
p. 209.
74. Peters (ed.), Söldnerleben, p. 136, citing Peter Hagendorf: ‘here (around
Stralsund) we weren’t interested in eating beef anymore, but only goose,
duck or chicken’; Burschel, Söldner, pp. 207–11; Fallon, ‘Scottish
Mercenaries’, pp. 351–5.
75. Especially as the sources for the recruitment and origins of soldiers in the
eighteenth century are much more extensive: Burschel, Söldner, pp. 57–8.
76. Very clear about the appeal of soldiering to craftsmen and journeymen, albeit
on the eve of the war, is H. Glümer, ‘Die Braunschweigischen
Söldnertruppen zu Fuß und Roß in den Jahren 1599–1615’, Jahrbuch des
Braunschweigischen Geschichtsvereins, 8 (1936), 47–76; Redlich, I, pp. 456–7.
This point about the appeal of soldiering to ‘respectable’ workers and farmers
is clearly evident in the work of those who have examined recruitment through
archival sources: Trim, ‘Fighting “Jacob’s Wars”’, pp. 67–71, 279–84; Fallon,
‘Scottish Mercenaries’, pp. 90–2.
77. Kapser, Bayerische Kriegsorganisation, pp. 68–73, 270–3: gives a particular
breakdown by previous employment of 1,069 soldiers recruited into the
Bavarian army between 1638 and 1648, of whom fewer than 5 per cent were
previously unemployed, but Kapser would take this as untypically low.
78. Grimmelshausen, Der Seltsame Springinsfeld, trans. as Tearaway by
M. Mitchell (Sawtry, 2003), provides a campaign-by-campaign fictional
account of the war, in which the military qualities – especially esprit de
corps – of the soldiers are at least as apparent as cowardice or evasion.
79. Peters (ed.), Söldnerwesen, pp. 133, 150.
364 Notes to pages 163–8
118. Kaiser, Politik und Kriegsführung, pp. 105–51; Heilmann, Feldzüge der
Bayern, pp. v–xi.
119. R. Rebitsch, Matthias Gallas (1588–1647). Generalleutnant des Kaisers zur
Zeit des Dreißigjährigen Krieges (Münster, 2006), pp. 264–71. Much of the
provisioning for the army on its 650 kilometre advance from Bohemia to Kiel
was provided from Saxony, and shipped along the Elbe.
120. Rebitsch, Gallas, pp. 274–7.
121. Rebitsch, Gallas, pp. 277–8; despite his reputation as an inept drunkard,
Gallas had given orders for 200,000 lb of bread to be baked in Hamburg
prior to the retreat and distributed to the army, enough to feed the troops for
thirteen days’ full rations, and distributed in much more meagre portions to
get the troops back to the Bohemian frontier: Salm, Armeefinanzierung, p. 45.
122. Rebitsch, Gallas, pp. 148–57.
123. Pohl, ‘Profiantirung’, pp. 155–6.
124. Pohl, Profiantirung, p. 151 – examples from supplying troops in the Balkans.
125. E. Leupold, ‘Journal der Armee des Herzogs Bernhard von Sachsen-Weimar
aus den Jahren 1637 und 1638’, Basler Zeitschrift für Geschichte und
Altertumskunde, 11 (1912), 253–362, pp. 297–9.
126. R. Hildebrandt (ed.), Quellen und Regesten zu den Augsburger Handelshäusern
Paler und Rehlinger, 1539–1642 (2 vols., Stuttgart, 2004), II, pp. 222–34.
Characteristic of their epoch of military history, neither the study of Saxe-
Weimar by Droysen nor that by Noailles makes any mention of this vital
supply operation and the accompanying provision of financial credit from
Rehlinger, without which the siege could never have been sustained.
127. Hildebrandt (ed.), Rehlinger, II, pp. 225, 227, 234.
128. A. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte – Finanzmann Wallensteins (Wiesbaden, 1954),
p. 217.
129. DBB, V, p. 97: Wallenstein to Cardinal Dietrichstein, 10 September
1632, concerning grain shipments from Moravia to the army outside
Nuremberg.
130. Banér uses the term ‘vohrmauer’: Rebitsch, Gallas, p. 193.
131. Heilmann, Kriegsgeschichte von Bayern, II, p. 999.
132. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 265–6; F. Gonzalez de León, The Road to
Rocroi. Class, Culture and Command in the Spanish Army of Flanders (Brill,
2009), pp. 183–96, 233–4.
133. Lahrkamp, Jan von Werth, pp. 52–8; W. Schulze, ‘Der Sommerfeldzug
Johann von Werths in Nordostfrankreich im Jahre 1636’, in Münchener
Historische Abhandlungen, 2nd ser., Kriegs- und Heeresgeschichte, Vol. VI
(Munich, 1934), pp. 25–66; A. Baran and G. Gajecky, The Cossacks in the
Thirty Years War (2 vols., Rome, 1983), II, p. 44.
134. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 120–1.
135. Stadler, Pappenheim, p. 610.
136. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, p. 60, on Wallenstein’s reluctance to move into Hungary
in 1626 in pursuit of Bethlen Gabor: Gindely, Waldstein, I, pp. 124–6;
G. Mann, Wallenstein. His Life Narrated, trans. C. Kessler (London, 1976)
pp. 290–3.
137. Lahrkamp, Jan von Werth, p. 54.
Notes to pages 180–9 367
138. Guthrie, White Mountain to Nördlingen, pp. 20–3; Breitenfeld was the largest
battle of the Thirty Years War, and these numbers were not to be surpassed
on land in the West until Seneffe in 1674.
139. Pohl, Profiantirung, pp. 23–32; Lorentzen, Schwedische Armee, p. 39, esti-
mates the Swedish/allied forces to be ‘more than 50,000’.
140. Heilmann, Feldzüge der Bayern, pp. 264–9.
141. Stadler, Pappenheim, p. 610.
142. DBB, IV, pp. 16–17.
143. Kaiser, Politik und Kriegsführung, pp. 258–60.
144. Stadler, Pappenheim, p. 613: ‘nichtswürdige Buben’, as opposed to the ‘alten
Knechte’.
145. Stadler, Pappenheim, p. 607.
146. Guthrie, Later Thirty Years War, pp. 48–74.
147. Salm, Armeefinanzierung, pp. 63–8.
148. The most comprehensive account of the Troß and its operational burden is
still Freytag, Der Dreißigjährige Krieg, 1618–1648 – (3 vols.; reprinted Bad
Langensalza, 2003), I, pp. 120–31.
149. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, p. 282.
150. It received attention in a thoughtful article by P. Sörensson first published in
1932: ‘Das Kriegswesen wahrend der letzten Periode des Dreißigjährigen
Krieges’, in H. Rudolf (ed.), Der Dreißigjährige Krieg. Perspectiven und
Strukturen (Darmstadt, 1977), pp. 431–57.
151. Broucek, Schwedenfeldzug, p. 5; Guthrie, Later Thirty Years War, pp. 152,
201–2. Torstensson’s figure for the Swedish army does not include the 900
officers in the army.
152. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, p. 119.
153. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 59–65.
154. Guthrie, Later Thirty Years War, pp. 219–21.
155. K. Ruppert, Die kaiserliche Politik auf dem Westfälischen Friedenskongreß,
1643–48 (Münster, 1979), pp. 72–85; E. Höfer, Das Ende des
Dreißigjährigen Krieges. Strategie und Kriegsbild (Cologne, Weimar and
Vienna 1997), pp. 175–7.
156. Heilmann, Feldzüge der Bayern, pp. 219–24, 270–3.
157. Heilmann, Feldzüge der Bayern, pp. 150–71.
158. Heilmann, Feldzüge der Bayern, pp. 156–7.
159. Heilmann, Feldzüge der Bayern, pp. 157–60; Berenger, Turenne, pp. 200–11.
160. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 117–18, for the immense difficulties in getting
French commanders to begin campaigning early; despite draconian threats,
Wallenstein found it no less difficult to get his armies assembled and ready
for action before late spring: DBB, V, pp. 87–8, 14 May 1632 (Pilsen).
161. Heilmann, Feldzüge der Bayern, pp. 85–6.
162. M. Fieger, Der kriegerische Ereignisse in der Oberpfalz. Vom Einfalle Baners
1641 bis zum Westfälischen Frieden (Dillingen, 1909–10), pp. 14–16.
163. Rebitsch, Gallas, pp. 184–203; F. Barthold, Geschichte des großen deutschen
Krieges, vom Tode Gustav Adolfs ab (2 vols., Stuttgart, 1842/3), II,
pp. 129–32, 163–81.
164. See Salm, Armeefinanzierung, pp. 42–6.
368 Notes to pages 189–96
165. William Guthrie’s two volumes on the battles of the Thirty Years War,
despite their implicit organizing principle, provide additional material
about the campaigning context between these battles. The near-
contemporaneous major works by Barthold, Geschichte des großen deutschen
Krieges, and Carl du Jarrys, Freiherr von La Roche, Der Dreißigjährige Krieg
vom militärischen Standpunkte aus beleuchtet (3 vols., Schaffhausen, 1848),
both argued back in the 1840s for the crucial importance of the second half of
the war and, by implication, the operational context, and provide abundant
detail of particular campaigns. The new study of the Thirty Years War by
Peter Wilson, Europe’s Tragedy, both focuses on the latter part of the war and
gives fuller detail about the pursuit of campaign objectives.
166. This description of the 1646 campaign is largely taken from the detailed
account in D. Croxton, Peacemaking in Early Modern Europe. Cardinal
Mazarin and the Congress of Westphalia, 1643–48 (Selinsgrove, 1999),
pp. 227–49; see also Croxton, ‘A Territorial Imperative? The Military
Revolution, Strategy and Peacemaking in the Thirty Years War’, War in
History, 5 (1998), 253–79; E. Gyllenstierna, ‘Henri de Turenne et Charles
Gustave Wrangel’, in Turenne et l’art militaire. Actes de Colloque International,
2/3 Oct. 1975 (Paris, 1975), pp. 201–6.
167. See the account of the disputes between Maurice of Nassau and the States
General after the 1600 victory at Nieuwpoort, in G. Parker, ‘The Limits to
Revolutions in Military Affairs’, 354–8.
168. Richelieu to Louis XIII, cited in Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 155–6.
169. Cited in Höfer, Ende, p. 53; F. Gambiez, ‘Turenne et la Renaissance du style
indirect’, in Turenne et l’art militaire, pp. 15–21; J. Revol, Turenne. Essai de
psychologie militaire (Paris, 1910), pp. 260–1.
170. Louis XIV, Memoirs for the Instruction of the Dauphin, ed. P. Sonnino
(London, 1970), pp. 180–1, 230–4.
171. Cornette, Le roi de guerre. Essai sur la souveraineté dans la France du Grand
Siècle (Paris, 1993), pp. 255–61.
172. Guibert, Essai général de tactique, pp. 30, 217–18; G. Perjés ‘Army
Provisioning, Logistics and Strategy in the Second Half of the Seventeenth
Century’, Acta Historica Academiae Scientarium Hungaricae, 16 (1970), 1–51.
173. See, for example, the excellent study of the 1706 campaign following
Ramillies: J. Ostwald, ‘The “Decisive” Battle of Ramillies, 1706:
Prerequisites for Decisiveness in Early Modern Warfare’, Journal of
Military History, 64 (2000), 649–77.
174. W. Gembruch, Staat und Heer. Ausgwählte historische Studien zum ancien
régime, zur Französischen Revolution und zu den Befreiungskriegen. Historische
Forschungen 40 (Berlin, 1990), p. 158.
NOTES TO CHAPTER 5
1. On Wallenstein’s assumed prescience in prioritizing logistics, see, for example,
W. Hummelsberger, ‘Kriegswirtschaft und Versorgungswesen von Wall-
enstein bis Prinz Eugen’, in Militärgeschichtliches Forschungsamt (ed.),
Notes to pages 198–200 369
Die Bedeutung der Logistik für die militärische Führung von der Antike bis in die
neueste Zeit (Bonn, 1986), pp. 61–85, p. 62.
2. J. Glete, War and the State in Early Modern Europe (London, 2002), pp. 200–1.
3. R. Romano, ‘Economic Aspects of the Construction of Warships in Venice in
the Sixteenth Century’, in J. Glete (ed.), Naval History, 1500–1680
(Aldershot, 2005), pp. 129–57; E. Concina, L’Arsenale della Repubblica di
Venezia (Milan, 1984), pp. 135–53; F.C. Lane, Venetian Ships and
Shipbuilders of the Renaissance (Baltimore and London, 1992), pp. 133–43;
R.C. Davis, Shipbuilders of the Venetian Arsenal: Workers and Workplace in the
Pre-industrial City (Baltimore, 1991), pp. 19–36.
4. I.A.A. Thompson, War and Government in Habsburg Spain, 1560–1620
(London, 1976), p. 192; D. Goodman, Spanish Naval Power, 1589–1665.
Reconstruction and Defeat (Cambridge, 1997), pp. 29–32.
5. G. Parker, ‘The Dreadnought Revolution of the Sixteenth Century’, The
Mariner’s Mirror, 82 (1996), 269–300, p. 273; N. Rodger, The Safeguard of
the Sea. A Naval History of Britain, 660–1649 (London, 1997), pp. 331–8;
A. James, Navy and Government in Early Modern France, 1572–1661 (London,
2004), pp. 112–14.
6. N.A.M. Rodger, The Command of the Ocean. A Naval History of Britain, 1649–
1815 (London, 2004), pp. 41–3, 109, 192–4.
7. J.R. Hale, ‘Renaissance Armies and Political Control: the Venetian
Proveditorial System, 1509–1529’, Journal of Italian Studies, 2 (1979), 11–
31, pp. 16–17; M. Mallett and J. Hale, The Military Organization of a
Renaissance State. Venice, c. 1400–1617 (Cambridge, 1984), pp. 279–81.
8. C.S.L. Davies, ‘Provisions for Armies, 1509–50: a Study in the Effectiveness
of Early Tudor Government’, Economic History Review, 17 (1964–5), 234–48,
pp. 238–40.
9. Thompson, War and Government, pp. 254–5.
10. J. Zunckel, Rüstungsgeschäfte im Dreißigjährigen Krieg: Unternehmerkräfte,
Militärgüter und Marktstrategien im Handel zwischen Genua, Amsterdam und
Hamburg (Berlin, 1997), p. 86.
11. Thompson, War and Government, pp. 174–5; Goodman, Spanish Naval
Power, pp. 141–2, on concern that Dutch merchants would supply faulty
rigging to Spanish ships.
12. Hummelsberger, ‘Kriegswirtschaft und Versorgungswesen’; F. Redlich, ‘Plan
for the Establishment of a War Industry in the Imperial Dominions during the
Thirty Years War’, Business History Review 38 (1964), pp. 123–6.
13. R. Murphey, Ottoman Warfare, 1500–1700 (London, 1999), esp. pp. 65–103;
C. Finkel, The Administration of Warfare. The Ottoman Military Campaigns
in Hungary, 1593–1606 (Vienna, 1988), pp. 130–203 on state organization of
food provisions. For the Ottoman administration’s direct control of arms
manufacture and munitions supply, see G. Ágoston, Guns for the Sultan.
Military Power and the Weapons Industry in the Ottoman Empire (Cambridge,
2005), pp. 96–189.
14. I.A.A. Thompson, ‘The Impact of War’, in P. Clark (ed.), The European Crisis
of the 1590s (London, 1985), pp. 261–84, p. 269; I. Bog, ‘Krieg und
Wirtschaft im 16 Jahrhundert: ein Essay über Kriegswirkungen and
370 Notes to pages 200–4
29. DBB, IV, 324: Christoph Lode, secretary to the king of Poland, to
Wallenstein, 5 October 1629.
30. Originally appearing as an anti-hero of one of Grimmelshausen’s novels, and
better known through Bertold Brecht’s play of the 1940s.
31. J. Lynn, Women, Armies, and Warfare in Early Modern Europe (Cambridge,
2008), pp. 130–50.
32. Redlich, ‘Marketender’, pp. 242–4.
33. An article on Muscovite logistics suggests that the sixteenth-century army was
mostly supplied by the private activity of sutlers and merchants supplemented
by the requisitioning or occasional purchase of bulk foodstuffs by military
officials: D. Smith, ‘Muscovite Logistics, 1462–1598’, Slavonic and East
European Review, 71 (1993), 35–65, pp. 50–1.
34. M. Burin de Roziers, ‘Les capitulations militaires entre la Suisse et la France’
(Doctorate, Paris, 1902), pp. 96–7 gives details of the agreement specified
between Henri II and the cantons in 1553, in which these terms were established.
35. G. Doria, ‘Conoscenza del mercato e sistema informativo: il know-how dei
mercanti-finanzieri genovesi nei secoli XVI e XVII’, in A. de Maddalena and
H. Kellenbenz (eds.), La republica internazionale del denaro tra XV e XVII secolo.
Annali dell’Istituto storico italo-germanico 20 (Bologna, 1986), pp. 57–121,
p. 67, n. 37.
36. Thompson, War and Government, pp. 182–3.
37. J. Guilmartin, Gunpowder and Galleys (Cambridge, 1974), p. 29.
38. T.A. Kirk, Genoa and the Sea. Policy and Power in an Early Modern Maritime
Republic, 1559–1684 (Baltimore and London, 2005), pp. 43–4: Centurión’s
proposal was rejected as the crown refused to concentrate so many galleys in
the hands of one contractor, but a contract to run nine of these Spanish galleys
was awarded to the Centurión family in 1608.
39. Kirk, Genoa, p. 43; Guilmartin, Gunpowder and Galleys, pp. 30–2.
40. Kirk, Genoa, p. 44.
41. Guilmartin, Gunpowder and Galleys, p. 34.
42. Such strictly speaking illegal income-supplementing activity continued well
into the eighteenth century: N.A.M. Rodger, The Wooden World. An Anatomy
of the Georgian Navy (London, 1986), pp. 318–21.
43. J.R. Bruijn, The Dutch Navy of the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries
(Columbia, SC, 1993), pp. 50–1; Bruijn gives examples of very substantial
kostpenningen profits to be made by commanders in the 1670s, pp. 116–17.
44. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, p. 82. Like many other colonels, Franz Albrecht relied
heavily for this contracting on the assistance of his lieutenant colonel, in this
case the future Imperial Field Marshal, Hatzfeld.
45. DBB, V, p. 120; Wallenstein to Gallas, 3 January 1633, concerning the
decision about the cavalry; Krebs, Hatzfeld I, p. 120, for the charcoal mills;
Hatzfeld II, p. 5, for the colonels’ search for hand mills for grain.
46. P. Burschel, Söldner im Nordwestdeutschland des 16. und 17. Jahrhunderts.
Sozialgeschichtliche Studien (Göttingen, 1994), pp. 178–9.
47. The potential for officer profiteering in this new system was held by Sir John
Smythe to have been the ruin of later sixteenth-century armies such as that led
to the Netherlands by Leicester: Certain Discourses Military (London, 1590;
372 Notes to pages 209–11
edited and republished by J. Hale, 1964), but the previous system was no less
disadvantageous to the soldiers.
48. J. Pohl,‘Die Profiantirung der keyserlichen Armaden ahnbelangendt’. Studien zur
Versorgung der kaiserlichen Armee, 1634/35 (Vienna, 1994), pp. 37–8, 63–5,
gives a monthly wage of 2 florins 6 kreuzer for an ordinary Imperial footsoldier
in 1634, but this was in addition to rations of bread, meat and wine, which
more than doubled the real value of the wage. See examples of
Verpflegungsordonnanzen, specifying the quantities of food and drink to be
supplied per day: J. Heilmann, Das Kriegswesen der Kaiserlichen und Schweden
zur Zeit des Dreißigjährigen Krieges (Leipzig, 1850; repr. Krefeld, 1977),
pp. 167–9, 185–6, for the Liga army in 1623 and the Swedish army in 1632.
Heilmann, Kriegsgeschichte von Bayern, Franken, Pfalz und Schwaben von
1506–1651 (2 vols., Munich, 1868), II, 1002: Bavarian army in the winter of
1632 (27 November 1632) specifies each infantryman is to receive 5 florins
per month, or 2 pounds of bread a day and 1 florin per week (i.e. a basic bread
ration and 4 florins per month).
49. Redlich, I, p. 484, gives a case in 1620 when Saxon recruits were paid a daily
subsistence (Liefergeld) of 6 groschen per day, double-pay men receiving
8 groschen. When the meat ration was suspended in the Imperial army,
additional monthly wages of 1.5–2 florins a month were paid to the ordinary
soldiers: Pohl, Profiantirung, p. 64.
50. Redlich, I, p. 484.
51. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, pp. 281–4: regulation for the delivery of foodstuffs as
contributions directly to Franz Albrecht von Sachsen-Lauenberg for the
supply of his three regiments.
52. Wallenstein himself had to provide an extra 1,000 gulden per company for
arming and equipping his regiment of cuirassiers in January 1620:
K. Oberleitner, ‘Beiträge zur Geschichte des Dreißigjährigen Krieges mit
besonderer Berücksichtigung des Österreichischen Finanz- und
Kriegswesens’, Archiv für Österreichischen Geschichte, 19 (1858), pp. 25–6.
53. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, pp. 29–30: Hatzfeld raised a further 3,000 talers from the
merchant company of Hermann Heffing in Cologne and the bankers Anton
and Tobias Geiger in Nuremberg to supplement sums that Franz Albrecht
had already borrowed from Geiger to pay for weapons and armour.
54. Krebs, Hatzfeld II, p. 5.
55. H. Lahrkamp, Jan von Werth (Cologne, 1962), p. 206.
56. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, p. 43.
57. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, p. 84, gives the particular example of Colonel Hebron
(Hepburn); Krebs, Hatzfeld II, p. 2.
58. Krebs, Hatzfeld, I, pp. 89–90.
59. D. Maffi, ‘Milano in guerra. La mobilitazione delle risorse in una provincia
della monarchia, 1640–59’, in M. Rizzo, J. Ibáñez and G. Sabatini (eds.), Le
forze del principe (2 vols., Murcia, 2004), I, pp. 345–408, pp. 366–71.
60. Thompson, War and Government, pp. 230–1.
61. DBB, V, pp. 87–8: Wallenstein to all regimental commanders, 14 May 1632,
Pilsen: order to ensure that all soldiers carry a full week’s worth of provisions
before setting out.
Notes to pages 212–20 373
62. This was the case even in the urbanized United Provinces: H. Vogel, ‘Arms
Production and Exports in the Dutch Republic, 1600–1650’, in M. van der
Hoeven (ed.), Exercise of Arms. Warfare in the Netherlands (1568–1648) (Brill,
1998), pp. 197–210, pp. 197–204.
63. Zunckel, Rüstungsgeschäfte, p. 67; W. Maeßer, ‘Suhl und Lüttich als
Großzeuger von Schußwaffen’, Zeitschrift für Historische Waffenkunde,
7 (1915–17), 254–61, p. 255; H. Valentinitisch, ‘Suhler Waffenhändler in
den Habsburgischen Erbländern in der Frühen Neuzeit’, in H. Edner,
W. Höflechner, H.J. Mezler-Andelberg, P. Roth et al., Festschrift Othmar
Pickl zum 60. Geburtstag (Graz and Vienna, 1987), pp. 683–8; H. Langer,
‘Army Finances, Production and Commerce’, in K. Bussmann and
H. Schilling (eds.), 1648. War and Peace in Europe (3 vols., Munich, 1998),
I, pp. 293–9; Gaier, Liège Gunmaking, pp. 29–40.
64. Zunckel, Rüstingsgeschäfte, pp. 30–53; C. Kapser, ‘Handel und Militär in
Frankfurt zur Zeit des Dreißigjährigen Krieges’, in R. Koch (ed.), Brücke
zwischen den Völkern – Zur Geschichte der Frankfurter Messe (3 vols., Frankurt
am Main, 1991), II, pp. 140–6.
65. The Hamburg firm of Berns-Marselis also dealt extensively with the military
needs of the Danish crown: J. Jorgensen, ‘Denmark’s Relations with Lübeck
and Hamburg in the Seventeenth Century’, Scandinavian Economic History
Review, 11 (1963), 73–116, pp. 97–100.
66. Zunckel, Rüstungsgeschäfte, p. 118.
67. Klein, ‘Trip Family’, pp. 196–8; H. Kellenbenz, Unternehmerkräfte im
Hamburger Portugal- und Spanienhandel, 1590–1625 (Hamburg, 1954),
pp. 224–5 for more attempts to control Swedish war materials in early 1630s.
68. Klein, ‘Trip Family’, p. 200; Zunckel, Rüstungsgeschäfte, pp. 105–7.
69. M. Bogucka, ‘Saltpeter Production and Saltpeter Trade between Gdansk and
Amsterdam in the First Half of the Seventeenth Century’, in W.G. Heeres
(ed.), From Dunkirk to Danzig. Shipping and Trade in the North Sea and the
Baltic (Amsterdam, 1988), pp. 167–70.
70. Zunckel, Rüstungsgeschäfte, p. 107.
71. Zunckel, Rüstungsgeschäfte, pp. 132–3, 166–8.
72. Zunckel, Rüstungsgeschäfte, p. 159. This had been true of naval provisioning
companies much earlier: see Doria, ‘Conoscenza del mercato’.
73. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, pp. 213–24: the list of Hauptfaktor, Nebenfaktor
and other business associates runs to several hundred names and several
scores of European centres.
74. Zunckel, Rüstungsgeschäfte, p. 233, n. 111; Kellenbenz, Unternehmerkräfte,
pp. 182–240.
75. J. Zunckel, ‘Rüstungshandel im Zeitalter des Dreißigjährigen Krieges.
“Militärische Revolution”, internationale Strategien und Hamburger
Perspektiven’, in B. von Krusenstjern and H. Medick (eds.), Zwischen Alltag
und Katastrophe (Göttingen, 2001), pp. 83–112; Zunckel, Rüstungsgeschäfte,
pp. 208–24 (Dorchi).
76. A. Nusbacher, ‘Civil Supply in the Civil War: Supply of Victuals to the New
Model Army on the Naseby Campaign, 1–14 June 1645’, English Historical
Review, 115 (2000), 145–60, esp. pp. 156–9.
374 Notes to pages 220–4
pp. 304–12, on the supply contractors Antonio Machado and Jacob Pereira in
the 1670s; in the English case, as early as the Civil War, see C. Holmes, The
Eastern Association in the English Civil War (Cambridge, 1974), pp. 155–6, and
A. Nusbacher, ‘The Triple Thread: Supply of Victuals to the Army under
Sir Thomas Fairfax, 1645–46’ (D.Phil. thesis, Oxford University, 2001),
pp. 99–201.
99. Kroener, B. Les routes et les étapes. Die Versorgung die französischen Armeen in
Nordostfrankreich (1635–61) (Münster, 1980), pp. 7–11, 183–7; B. Kroener,
‘Rechtstellung und Profite französicher Heereslieferanten in der ersten
Hälfte des 17. Jahrhunderts’, Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial- und Wirtschafts-
geschichte, 76 (1989), pp. 457–93; D. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army,
(Cambridge, 2001), pp. 381–90.
100. Estríngana, ‘La ejecución del gasto militar’, examines in detail the contracts
with suppliers for the Army of Flanders from the 1620s to 1640s.
101. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 256–8; Kroener, ‘Heereslieferanten’, p. 469
makes the point that supplying daily rations for 30,000 requires a minimum
of 1,000 horses and 250 wagons.
102. Goodman, Spanish Naval Power, pp. 151–8, though Goodman emphasizes
the extent that gathering and transporting naval supplies was also potentially
subject to crippling difficulties and delay.
103. For examples of the former, see Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 413–14.
104. C. Kapser, Die bayerische Kriegsorganisation in der zweiten Hälfte des
Dreißigjährigen Kneges, 1635–1648/49 (Münster, 1997), pp. 83, 88.
105. J. Lefèvre, Spinola et la Belgique (1601–1627) (Brussels, 1947), pp. 20–4;
Parker, Army of Flanders, p. 212.
106. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 389–90.
107. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 234–5, 389–90; R. Bonney, The King’s Debts.
Finance and Politics in France, 1589–1661 (Oxford, 1981), pp. 186–8; Elias
Trip achieved a similar position in respect to the export of copper from
Sweden by the late 1620s, largely because the Swedish crown and its agents
found it convenient to acquiesce in Trip’s virtual control of copper sales, to
the extent that his dominance of the copper trade could block any attempt by
the Swedish crown to manage the price of copper against his interests: Klein,
‘Trip Family’, pp. 204–5.
108. Bruijn, Dutch Navy, pp. 34–7.
109. Pohl, ‘Profiantirung’, pp. 146–7.
110. M. Hüther, ‘Der Dreißigjährige Krieg als fiskalisches Problem:
Lösungsversuche und ihre Konsequenzen’, Scripta Mercaturae, 21 (1987),
52–81, pp. 54–5; see as well the detailed breakdown of the parlous state of
the Habsburg finances from 1618 to 1634 in Oberleitner, ‘Beiträge zur
Geschichte’, pp. 1–13.
111. On the French fiscal system, see Bonney, The King’s Debts, and J. Dent, Crisis
in Finance. Crown, Financiers and Society in Seventeenth-Century France
(Newton Abbot, 1973).
112. Thompson, War and Government, p. 96; Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 262–6.
113. A. Judges, ‘Philip Burlamachi: a Financier of the Thirty Years War’,
Economica, 16 (1926), 285–300.
376 Notes to pages 228–34
114. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 258–9; for corruption in the quantity and
quality of bread provisioning in the Netherlands, see Parker, Army of
Flanders, pp. 137–8.
115. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, p. 257; Kroener, ‘Heereslieferanten’, pp. 481–4.
116. B. Stadler, Pappenheim und die Zeit des Dreißigjährigen Krieges (Winterthur,
1991), p. 693.
117. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, pp. 86–97.
118. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, pp. 160–212: ‘Europas Krieg, Europas Geld’;
see F. Redlich, ‘Military Entrepreneurship and the Credit System in the
sixteenth and seventeenth Centuries’, Kyklos, 10 (1957), 186–93,
pp. 189–91 for a more sceptical view of de Witte’s achievements.
119. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, pp. 368–87.
120. Redlich, I, pp. 247–8; F.J. Schöningh, Die Rehlinger von Augsburg. Ein
Beitrag zur deutschen Wirtschaftsgeschichte des 16. und 17. Jahrhunderts
(Paderborn, 1927), pp. 43–54, 92–6.
121. C. Badalo-Dulong, Banquier du roi, Barthélemi Hervart, 1606–76 (Paris,
1951), pp. 11–18.
122. Gonzenbach, Erlach, III, 362–8; Badalo-Dulong, Hervart, pp. 28–32.
123. H. L. Landberg, Ekholm, R. Nordlund and S. Nilsson (eds.), Det kontinen-
tala krigets ekonomie. Studier i krigsfinansierung under svensk stormaktstid
(Kristianstad, 1971), 470–71.
124. For dealings with Heffing: Krebs, Hatzfeld I, p. 213; H. Salm,
Armeefinanzierung im Dreißigjährigen Krieg (Münster, 1990), pp. 115–16.
125. Accounts of campaigns make this evident time and again: for military
commanders deploying their capital to keep their troops supplied, see, for
one example, the report that Holzapfel had dispensed 20,000 talers to the
troops under his command in 1645 to make good provisioning shortfalls:
E. Höfer, Das Ende des Dreißigjährigen Krieges. Strategie und Kriegsbild
(Cologne-Weimar and Vienna, 1997), pp. 47–8; for support given by finan-
ciers/suppliers, see Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, passim.
126. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, p. 237; Valentinitisch, ‘Suhler Waffenhändler’,
pp. 684–5, 687.
127. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, pp. 238–40.
128. The well-supported view of Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, pp. 231–6.
129. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, pp. 242–5.
130. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, p. 246 – see table.
131. J. Kunisch, ‘Wallenstein als Kriegsunternehmer. Auf dem Wege zum abso-
lutischen Steuerstaat’, in U. Schultz (ed.), Mit dem Zehnten fing es an. Eine
Kulturgeschichte der Steuer (Munich, 1986), pp. 153–61, p. 157;
Hummelsberger, ‘Kriegswirtschaft und Versorgungswesen’, p. 63.
132. A. Ernstberger, Wallenstein als Volkswirt im Herzogtum Friedland
(Reichenberg, 1929), passim; Ernstberger, ‘Wallenstein’s Heeressabotage’,
in Ernstberger, Franken – Böhmen – Europa: Gesammelte Aufsätze (2 vols.,
Kallmünz, 1959), I, pp. 269–85; G. Mann, Wallenstein. His Life Narrated,
trans. C. Kessler (London, 1976), pp. 226–52.
133. In 1627–8 the duchy of Friedland was to produce the colossal total of
60,000–70,000 strich of grain to support the army’s needs in return for not
Notes to pages 234–40 377
quartering Imperial troops over the winter. The target was only met by
squeezing the productive capacity of the duchy to the utmost: Ernstberger,
Wallenstein, pp. 32–3.
134. On the planning of Reichenberg as a ‘model’ town, see J. Mohr,
‘Bauaktivitäten in Reichenberg unter Albrecht von Waldstein: Das erste
planmäßig errichtete Stadtviertel’, in E. Fučiková and L. Čepička (eds.),
Albrecht von Waldstein. Inter arma silent musae? (Exhibition catalogue;
Prague, 2007), pp. 249–53.
135. Ernstberger, Wallenstein, pp. 67–83.
136. Ernstberger, Wallenstein, pp. 67–73, 75–7.
137. M. Roberts, Gustavus Adolphus. A History of Sweden, 1611–1632 (2 vols.,
London, 1958), II, pp. 109–11; E. Dahlgren, Louis de Geer, 1587–1652. Hans
lif och verk (2 vols., Uppsala, 1923), I, pp. 108–16.
138. Roberts, Gustavus Adolphus, II, pp. 111–13; Dahlgren, Louis de Geer,
I, pp. 190–2.
139. Klein, ‘Trip Family’, p. 197.
140. Dahlgren, Louis de Geer, I, pp. 143–4.
141. Dahlgren, Louis de Geer, I, pp. 134–43; F. Breedevelt van Veen, Louis de
Geer, 1587–1652 (Amsterdam, 1935).
142. Roberts, Gustavus Adolphus, II, pp. 113–17.
143. Klein, ‘Trip Family’, p. 198; useful information on the activities of the two
families and cannon production in Sweden in C. Cipolla, Guns and Sails in
the Early Phase of European Expansion, 1400–1700 (London, 1965), pp. 55–8,
154–8.
144. Klein, ‘Trip Family’, pp. 198–9.
145. A painting by Allart van Everdingen, now in the Rijksmuseum, Amsterdam.
146. W. Großhaupt, ‘Kaufleute, Waren, Geldhandel und Nachrichtenübermittlung
in der Neuzeit’, in A. Dietz (ed.), Frankfurter Handelsgeschichte (4 vols.,
Frankfurt am Main, 1910–25; repr. 1970), I, pp. 219–47, p. 234.
147. J. Schneider, ‘The Significance of Large Fairs, Money Markets and Precious
Metals in the Evolution of a World Market’, in H. Kellenbenz and
E. Schmitt (eds.), The Emergence of a World Economy, 1500–1914 (2 vols.,
Wiesbaden, 1986), I, pp. 15–36, pp. 18–20.
148. Landberg et al. (eds.), Krigets ekonomie, p. 470.
149. S. Schröder, ‘Hamburg und Schweden im Dreißigjährigen Krieg – vom
potentiellen Bündnispartner zum Zentrum der Kriegsfinanzierung’,
Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte, 79 (1989), 305–31,
pp. 318–27; Landberg et al. (eds.), Krigets ekonomie, p. 477.
150. In the context of financing the Thirty Years War, the most important of these
was Frankfurt am Main: R. Hildebrandt, ‘Handel und Kapitalverkehr um
1630. Außenwirtschaftliche Beziehungen Deutschlands im Dreißigjährigen
Krieg’, in J. Schneider (ed.), Wirtschaftskräfte und Wirtschaftswege V
(Stuttgart, 1981), pp. 135–59, p. 140.
151. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, pp. 366–7.
152. Höfer, Ende, pp. 2–3. The view is echoed for the French economy by the
work of Daniel Dessert, who points to the staggeringly high percentage of
specie held by a narrow group of financiers/merchants: Argent, pouvoir et
378 Notes to pages 240–6
société au Grand Siècle (Paris, 1984), pp. 172–8. The entire Spanish credit
system down to the 1630s was dominated by the Genoese – Kirk, Genoa,
p. 88: from seventy financial contracts made by Philip III between 1598 and
1609, nearly 33 million ducats (88 per cent of all loans) were borrowed from
Genoese financiers.
153. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, p. 227.
154. Redlich, I, p. 242.
155. Redlich, I, pp. 74–5, 88–9; R. Baumann, Georg von Frundsberg (Munich,
1991), pp. 260–1.
156. Redlich, I, p. 408.
157. Redlich, I, p. 409.
158. G. Droysen, Bernhard von Weimar (2 vols., Leipzig, 1885), I, pp. 22–3.
159. T. Lorentzen, Die Schwedische Armee im Dreißigjährigen Kriege (Leipzig,
1894), p. 15.
160. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, p. 46.
161. Redlich, I, p. 408.
162. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, pp. 111–12: Krebs points out that these substantial profits
did not stop Hatzfeld asking for a loan from his colonel a few months later in
1629 to meet some of the expenses of the regiment.
163. Heilmann, Kriegswesen, pp. 190–7.
164. Redlich, I, p. 361; Redlich, De Praede Militare. Looting and Booty, 1500–1815.
Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 39 (Wiesbaden,1956),
pp. 38–57.
165. R. Rebitsch, Matthias Gallas (1588–1647) (Munster, 2006), pp. 399–401;
for a detailed account of the booty from the sack, see R. Quazza, La guerra
per la successione di Mantova e del Monferrato (2 vols., Mantua, 1926), II,
pp. 146–62.
166. Rebitsch, Gallas, pp. 392–9.
167. P. Broucek, Die Eroberung von Bregenz am 4. Jänner 1647 (Vienna, 1971),
pp. 9–12.
168. Redlich, Looting and Booty, pp. 55–7.
169. Redlich, I, pp. 402–8. An especially interesting section in E. Lund, War for
the Every Day. Generals, Knowledge, and Warfare in Early Modern Europe,
1680–1740 (Westport, CT and London, 1999), p. 41, draws attention to the
close links established between credit, wealth, honour and nobility in these
military societies, and the extent to which ‘creditworthiness’ could be based
on this mixture of interlocking aspects of the military commander’s role.
170. Lorentzen, Schwedische Armee, pp. 117–31: the final figure was whittled down
to 5 million, but at the price of territorial concessions in north Germany which
left a large number of the senior officers as permanent beneficiaries of lands
and revenues in Pomerania, Bremen, Verden and Wismar.
171. R. Stradling, Th Armada of Flanders. Spanish Maritime Policy and European
War, 1568–1668 (Cambridge, 1992), p. 227; H. Malo, Les corsaires dunker-
quois et Jean Bart (2 vols., Paris, 1912/13), I, pp. 333–5.
172. Stradling, Armada of Flanders, pp. 205–9.
173. P. Villiers, Les corsaires du Littoral. Dunkerque, Calais, Boulogne de Philip II à
Louis XIV (1568–1713) (Lille, 2000), p. 131.
Notes to pages 246–50 379
174. Villiers, Les corsaires, pp. 132–3; see also J.S. Bromley, ‘The Trade and
Privateering of Saint-Malo during the War of the Spanish Succession’, and
the detailed calculations in ‘Duguay Trouin: the Financial Background’, both
in Bromley, Corsairs and Navies, 1660–1760 (London, 1987), pp. 279–323.
175. L. Welti, Graf Kaspar von Hohenems, 1573–1640 (Innsbruck, 1963),
pp. 228–30.
176. A. de Villermont, Ernest de Mansfeldt (2 vols., Brussels, 1865), II, pp. 189–91.
The same arrangements were made by the French crown with Saxe-Weimar,
for whom a large pension and cash gratifications were part of the package:
A. de Noailles, Bernhard de Saxe-Weimar (Paris, 1908), pp. 481–6.
177. C. Leestmans, Charles IV de Lorraine. Une errance baroque (Lasne, 2003),
pp. 107–29.
178. Parrott, Richelieu’s Army, pp. 306–11.
179. See, for example, the arrangements made between Oxenstierna and
Lieutenant Colonel Douglas in 1631, in which Douglas agreed to raise 500
men at his own expense, but received 2,000 riksdalers in ready cash and was
promised the rest of the muster money when he arrived in the spring with the
new recruits: J. Fallon, ‘Scottish Mercenaries in the Service of Denmark and
Sweden, 1626–32’ (Ph.D. thesis, University of Glasgow, 1972), p. 266.
Similar arrangement with Ludovick Leslie, p. 281, and throughout the
period 1637–40 – p. 302.
180. D. Stevenson, ‘Monro, Robert (d. 1675?)’, in Oxford Dictionary of National
Biography (Oxford, 2004).
181. Ramsay is presented in Lorentzen, Schwedische Armee, p. 15, as one of the
great winners from Swedish military operations, but see article by
A. Grosjean in the new Dictionary of National Biography, and Fallon,
‘Scottish Mercenaries’, pp. 261–74.
182. The numbers of those killed in action are even more striking when second-
level corps commanders are added.
183. J. Peters (ed.), Ein Söldnerleben im Dreißigjährigen Krieg (Berlin, 1993),
pp. 187–8 for his disbandment and final pay.
184. Redlich, I, 228–9; the same question is asked explicitly of Václav Eusebius
Z. Lobkovic in T.M. Barker, ‘Military Entrepreneurship, Patronage and
Grace’, in Barker, Army, Aristocracy, Monarchy. Essays on War, Society and
Government in Austria, 1618–1780 (New York, 1982), pp. 118–19.
185. Wallenstein had at least one precedent in the Liechtenstein family, who
provided substantial levels of financial and military support for the
Habsburgs during the Long Turkish War for which they had received their
princely title and office of Landeshauptmann of Moravia in 1606: J. von Falke,
Geschichte des fürstlichen Hauses Liechtenstein (2 vols., Vienna, 1877), II,
pp. 138–54.
186. J. Polišenský and J. Kollmann, Wallenstein. Feldherr des Dreißigjährigen
Krieges (Cologne, 1997), pp. 146–9.
187. D. Maffi, Il Baluardo della Corona. Guerra, esercito, finanze e società nella
Lombardia seicentesca (1630–60) (Florence, 2007), pp. 176–91.
188. On Jan de Werth’s social ascent: Lahrkamp, Jan von Werth, pp. 3–13, 214–25;
on Holzapfel: W. Hofmann, Peter Melander, Reichsgraf zu Holzappel. Ein
380 Notes to pages 250–4
Charakterbild aus der Zeit des Dreißigjährigen Krieges (Munich, 1882); Salm,
Armeefinanzierung, pp. 69–72.
189. Villiers, Les corsaires, p. 77.
190. The general conclusion of G. Schmidt, ‘Voraussetzung oder Legitimation?
Kriegsdienst und Adel im Dreißigjährigen Krieg’, in G. Oexle and
W. Paravicini (eds.), Nobilitas. Funktion und Repräsentation des Adels in
Alteuropa (Göttingen, 1997), pp. 431–51.
191. Rebitsch, Gallas, pp. 373–84.
192. Another excellent example is provided by the career of Raimondo
Montecuccoli, who drew on his military services in the last years of the
Thirty Years War to secure Imperial favour, a series of important diplomatic
missions and eventual promotion to field marshal and the presidency of the
Imperial War Council: see T. Barker, The Military Intellectual and Battle.
Raimondo Montecuccoli and the Thirty Years War (Albany, NY, 1975),
pp. 43–7.
193. Phillips, Six Galleons, p. 89.
194. Ernstberger, Hans de Witte, pp. 325–59.
195. J. Kraus, Das Militärwesen der Reichsstadt Augsburg, 1548–1806 (Augsburg,
1980), p. 236.
196. Redlich, I, p. 304.
197. The apparent incompatibility of ‘aristocratic’ military virtue and the trades-
man’s pursuit of financial gain is clearly emphasized in D. Trim, ‘Fighting
“Jacob’s Wars”. The Employment of English and Welsh Mercenaries in the
European Wars of Religion: France and the Netherlands, 1562–1610’
(Ph.D. thesis, King’s College London, 2002), pp. 81–6.
198. A. Devyver, Le sang épurée. Les préjugés de race chez les gentilshommes français de
l’Ancien Régime, 1560–1720 (Brussels, 1973), pp. 88–108; A. Jouanna, ‘La
noblesse et les valeurs guerrières au XVIe siècle’, in G.-A. Pérousse,
A. Thierry and A. Tournon (eds.), L’homme de guerre au XVIe siècle (Saint-
Etienne, 1992), pp. 205–17.
199. J.-P. Labatut, Les ducs et pairs de France au XVIIe siècle (Paris, 1972), pp. 122–34.
200. G. Oestreich, Neostoicism and the Early Modern State (Cambridge, 1982),
pp. 76–89.
201. D. Trim, ‘Chivalry and Professionalism in the French Armies of the
Renaissance’, in Trim (ed.), The Chivalric Ethos and the Development of
Military Professionalism (Brill, 2003), pp. 149–82; M. Fantoni, ‘Il “perfetto
capitano”: storia e mitografia’, in Fantoni (ed.), ‘Il perfetto capitano’.
Immagini e realtà (secoli XV–XVII) (Rome, 2001), pp. 15–66.
202. J. Dewald, Aristocratic Experience and the Origins of Modern Culture. France,
1570–1715 (Berkeley and Los Angeles, 1993), pp. 45–68.
203. François de Betstein, Marshal Bassompierre, Mémoires (4 vols., Paris,
1870–7), I, pp. 98–9 (1603).
204. Fantoni (ed.), ‘Perfetto capitano’.
205. T. Barker, ‘Ottavio Piccolomini (1599–1659)’, in Barker, Army, Aristocracy,
Monarchy, pp. 72–3.
206. Stadler, Pappenheim, pp. 773–7.
207. Krebs, Hatzfeld I, p. 249.
Notes to pages 254–62 381
NOTES TO CHAPTER 6
1. Historia della Vita d’Alberto Valstain, Duca di Fritland (Lyon, 1643).
2. For a discussion of the characteristics of this genre, see M. Fantoni (ed.), Il
‘perfetto capitano’. Immagine e realtà (secoli XV–XVII) (Rome, 2001), and
F. González de León, ‘“Doctors of the Military Discipline”. Technical
Expertise and the Paradigm of the Spanish Soldier in the Early Modern
Period’, Sixteenth Century Journal, 27 (1996), pp. 61–85.
3. Comte G. Gualdo Priorato, Historia della Vita d’Alberto Valstain, Duca di
Fritland (Lyon, 1643), p. 11r.
4. The bibliography of printed manuals on the art of war is vast: a good starting
point is the handlist of mainly Italian and Spanish treatises printed in Fantoni,
‘Perfetto capitano’, pp. 491–508. Printed manuals would need to be set against
what is probably an even larger body of works existing only in manuscript and
spread across European libraries and archives. My reading of extensive printed
manuals indicates the very large degree of convention and consensus in what is
and is not discussed in military treatises.
382 Notes to pages 262–9
35. For example: M. Potter, Corps and Clienteles. Public Finance and Political Change
in France, 1688–1715, (Aldershot, 2003), pp. 3–25; Potter, ‘War Finance and
Absolutist State Development in Early Modern Europe. An Examination of
French Venality in the Seventeenth Century’, Journal of Early Modern History, 7
(2003), 120–47; D. Bien, ‘Property in Office under the Ancien Régime. The
Case of the Stockbrokers’, in J. Brewer and S. Staves (eds.), Early Modern
Conceptions of Property (London and New York, 1995), pp. 481–94.
36. Rowlands, Dynastic State, pp. 166–71; H. Drévillon, L’impôt du sang: Le métier
des armes sous Louis XIV (Paris, 2005), pp. 179–211; J. Chagniot, Paris et
l’armée au XVIIIe siècle. Étude politique et sociale (Paris, 1985), pp. 255–77;
C. Opitz-Belakhal, Militärreformen zwischen Bürokratisierung und Adelsreaktion
(Sigmaringen, 1994), pp. 30–41.
37. See, for example, Rousset, Louvois, I, pp. 179–81; L. André, Michel Le Tellier
et Louvois (Paris, 1942), pp. 315–17.
38. E. Léonard, L’armée et ses problèmes au XVIIIe siècle (Paris, 1958), pp. 163–76.
39. Louis XIV, Memoirs, p. 126.
40. J. Chagniot, ‘La rationalisation de l’armée française après 1660’, in Armées et
diplomatie dans l’Europe du XVIIe siècle. Actes du Colloque des Association des
Historiens Modernistes (Paris, 1991), p. 105; similar additional expenditure
was undertaken by Austrian colonel-proprietors: M. Hochedlinger, Austria’s
Wars of Emergence, 1683–1797 (London, 2003), p. 130.
41. Some excellent statistics, taken from Dangeau’s Journal, in Lynn, Giant,
pp. 230–1.
42. Chagniot, ‘L’armée française’, pp. 103–4; A. Corvisier, Louvois (Paris, 1983),
pp. 335–6.
43. Chagniot, Paris et l’Armée, p. 260; Redlich, II, p. 51.
44. Redlich, II, pp. 53–4.
45. Drévillon, L’impôt du sang, pp. 169–73.
46. Rowlands, Dynastic State, pp. 343–53; Drevillon, L’impôt du sang, pp. 68–79.
47. Drevillon, L’impôt du sang, pp. 117–41.
48. Corvisier, Louvois, pp. 78–94, 326–43; Lynn, Giant, pp. 241–7.
49. Chagniot, ‘L’armée française’, pp. 98–9.
50. Chagniot, Paris et l’armée, pp. 266–70; V. Belhomme, L’armée française en 1690
(Paris, 1895), pp. 154–6. For a short-lived and unsuccessful experiment with
direct administration of army supply in the crisis years of 1709–10, see chapter
10 of J. Iung, ‘Service de vivres et munitionnaires sous l’ancien régime: la
fourniture de pain de munition aux troupes de Flandre et d’Allemagne de
1701–1710’ (Thèse de l’École Nationale des Chartes, Paris, 1983).
51. Chagniot, Paris et l’armée, pp. 270–3; Drévillon, L’impôt du sang, pp. 112–16.
52. F.-M. le Tellier, Marquis de Louvois, Lettres de Louvois à Louis XIV, ed.
N. Salat and T. Sarmant (Paris, 2007); see, for example, pp. 119–21, letter
of 2 July 1682 concerning work on the fortifications of Valenciennes.
53. Dessert, La Royale, pp. 61–73.
54. Dessert, La Royale, p. 74.
55. A process which continued for the French royal navy through the eighteenth
century: J. Pritchard, Louis XV’s Navy, 1748–1762. A Study of Organization
and Administration (Kingston, Canada, 1987), pp. 143–205.
Notes to pages 279–84 385
119. Redlich, II, p. 64, on the Great Elector; Duffy, Instrument of War, pp. 164,
179–80.
120. Redlich, II, pp. 154–5; H. Scott and C. Storrs, ‘The Military Revolution and
the European Nobility, c. 1600–1800’, War in History, 3 (1996), 1–41,
pp. 15–23; C. Duffy, The Military Experience in the Age of Reason (London,
1987), pp. 35–42.
121. Redlich, II, pp. 114, 154–7.
122. The title of this section is borrowed from R. Knight and M. Wilcox,
Sustaining the Fleet, 1793–1815. War, the British Navy and the Contractor
State (Woodbridge, 2010), the latest in a series of works which has reap-
praised in far more positive terms the involvement and contribution of
supply contractors to the military operations of the early modern state.
123. L. Kennett, The French Armies in the Seven Years War (Durham, NC, 1967),
pp. 99–102.
124. Kennett, French Armies, pp. 100, 107: though sharing the typical assumption
that it should be the private, contractual area of supply that proved corrupt
and inefficient, Kennett elides this account of the comprehensive failure of
the direct administration of forage with a general criticism of the contract
system: p. 108.
125. Kennett, French Armies, pp. 121–8.
126. Redlich, II, p. 23, notes that the business of clothing the soldiers was
gradually removed from the individual colonels, then captains, in the later
seventeenth century, and placed in the hands of merchants operating on
much larger contracts.
127. J. Bérenger, Finances et absolutisme autrichienne dans la seconde moitié du
XVIIème siècle (2 vols., Lille, 1975), II, pp. 361–2, 571–5; Hochedlinger,
Austria’s Wars, p. 143.
128. Hochedlinger, Austria’s Wars, p. 127.
129. Knight and Wilcox, Sustaining the Fleet, p. 6.
130. R.T. Sánchez, ‘The Triumph of the Fiscal-Military State in the Eighteenth
Century. War and Mercantilism’, in Sánchez (ed.), War, State and
Development. Fiscal-Military States in the Eighteenth Century (Pamplona,
2007), suggests that there may have been substantial benefits for the
Spanish military-fiscal state in deliberately reducing large numbers of mili-
tary contractors to a narrow monopoly made up of large-scale, native con-
tractors, pp. 30–1.
131. M. Grunwald, Samuel Oppenheimer und sein Kreis. Ein Kapitel aus der
Finanzgeschichte Österreichs (Vienna, 1913), pp. 137–42.
132. Grunwald, Oppenheimer, pp. 150–62.
133. Pritchard, Navy, pp. 150–4.
134. Knight and Wilcox, Sustaining the Fleet, pp. 37–43.
135. For scepticism about the efficiency of the British excise administration, see
L. Stone, ‘Introduction’, in Stone (ed.), An Imperial State at War. Britain
from 1689–1815 (London, 1994), pp. 9–21; for challenges to the
Weberian model of Prussian military-fiscal bureaucracy, see R. Vierhaus
‘The Prussian Bureaucracy Reconsidered’, in J. Brewer and E. Hellmuth
(eds.), Rethinking Leviathan. The Eighteenth-Century State in Britain and
Notes to pages 302–8 389
15. C. Duffy, The Army of Frederick the Great (Newton Abbot, 1974), pp. 189–91;
D. Showalter, The Wars of Frederick the Great (London, 1996), pp. 260–2.
16. T. Hippler, Citizen, Soldiers and National Armies. Military Service in France and
Germany, 1789–1830 (London, 2008), pp. 62–9.
17. P. Paret, ‘Conscription and the End of the Ancien Régime in France and
Prussia’, in Paret, Understanding War. Essays on Clausewitz and the History of
Military Power (Princeton, 1992), pp. 53–74, p. 58; S. Percy, Mercenaries. The
History of a Norm in International Relations (Oxford, 2007), p. 100.
18. See, for example, S.P. MacKenzie, Revolutionary Armies in the Modern Era.
A Revisionist Approach (London, 1997), pp. 41–2.
19. G. Rothenberg, The Art of Warfare in the Age of Napoleon (London, 1977),
p. 101.
20. Knight and Wilcox, Sustaining the Fleet, p. 5.
21. Percy, Mercenaries, pp. 132–3.
22. N. Steensgard, ‘The Dutch East India Company as an Institutional
Innovation’, in M. Aymard (ed.), Dutch Capitalism and World Capitalism
(Cambridge, 1982), pp. 235–57, p. 246.
23. Steensgard, ‘Dutch East India Company’, pp. 247–51.
24. J. Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 1585–1740 (Oxford, 1989),
pp. 156–70.
25. Israel, Dutch Primacy, p. 162.
26. Israel, Dutch Primacy, p. 170.
27. P.W. Singer, Corporate Warriors. The Rise of the Privatized Military Industry
(Ithaca, 2003), pp. 136–48.
28. F. Bayard, Le monde des financiers au XVIIe siècle (Paris, 1988), pp. 375–89;
J. Dent, Crisis in Finance. Crown, Financiers and Society in Seventeenth-Century
France (Newton Abbot, 1973), pp. 138–41.
29. Singer, Corporate Warriors, pp. 138–40.
30. For Mazarin’s opportunist provisioning of the armies and manipulation of the
military budget, see C. Dulong, La fortune de Mazarin (Paris, 1990), pp. 47–9,
67–70; D. Dessert, La Royale. Vaisseaux et marins du Roi-Soleil (Paris, 1996),
pp. 61–77; B. Pâris de Bollardière, Joseph Pâris Duverney et ses frères. Financiers
dauphinois à la cour de Louis XV (Toulon, 2006).
31. For Spain see R.T. Sánchez, ‘The Triumph of the Fiscal-Military State in the
Eighteenth Century. War and Mercantilism’, in Sánchez (ed.), War, State and
Development, pp. 30–1.
32. G. Bannerman, Merchants and the Military in Eighteenth-Century Britain
(London, 2008), p. 140.
33. Knight and Wilcox, Sustaining the Fleet, pp. 1–2.
34. Percy, Mercenaries, pp. 152–3; P. Wilson, ‘The German “Soldier Trade” of
the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries: a Reassessment’, International
History Review, 18 (1996), 757–92, pp. 761–6, emphasizes the ambiguities
and vested interests involved in contemporary criticism of the hiring out of
mercenaries, but points to its more widespread and vocal character.
35. Knight and Wilcox, Sustaining the Fleet, pp. 1–2; Bannerman, Merchants and
the Military, p. 141.
392 Notes to page 326
36. H. Scott, ‘The Fiscal-Military State and International Rivalry during the Long
Eighteenth Century’, in Storrs (ed.), The Fiscal-Military State, pp. 23–33.
37. Remark by Isaac de Pinto in 1771, quoted in Scott, ‘Fiscal-Military State’,
p. 29. For an extended discussion of this transformation as seen by French
political theorists and commentators, see M. Sonenscher, Before the Deluge.
Public Debt, Inequality and the Origins of the French Revolution (Princeton,
2007).
Bibliography
Acerra, M. and G. Martinière (eds.), Coligny, les Protestants et la mer (Paris, 1997).
Affò, I., Vita di Vespasiano Gonzaga (1780; repr. Mantua, 1975).
Ágoston, G., Guns for the Sultan. Military Power and the Weapons Industry in the
Ottoman Empire (Cambridge, 2005).
Alba y Viamont, D. de, El Perfeto Capitan, instruido en la diciplina militar, y nueva
ciencia de la artilleria (Madrid, 1590).
Albrecht, D., Maximilian I von Bayern, 1573–1651 (Munich, 1998).
Allmayer-Beck, J. C., ‘Die Träger der staatlichen Macht: Adel, Armee und
Bürokratie’, in P. Broucek (ed.), Militär, Geschichte und Politsche Bildung
(Vienna, 2003).
Amadè, L., Il duca di Sabbioneta (Milan, 1990).
Anderson, R. C., Naval Wars in the Baltic, 1522–1850 (1910; repr. London, 1969).
André, L., Michel Le Tellier et l’organisation de l’armée monarchique (Paris, 1906).
Michel Le Tellier et Louvois (Paris, 1942).
Andrews, K. R., Elizabethan Privateering. English Privateering during the Spanish
War, 1585–1603 (Cambridge, 1964).
Aristide, I., La fortune de Sully (Paris, 1990).
Arnould, J.-C., ‘Pillage, Profit, Promotion: l’homme de guerre d’après les
Commentaires de Monluc’, in G.-A. Pérousse, A. Thierry and A. Tournon
(eds.), L’homme de guerre au XVIe siècle (St Etienne, 1992), pp. 167–76.
Asch, R., ‘“Wo der soldat hinkömbt, da ist alles sein”: Military Violence and
Atrocities in the Thirty Years War Re-examined’, German History, 18 (2000),
291–309.
Augeron, M., ‘Coligny et les Espagnols à travers la course’, in Acerra and
Martinière (eds.), Coligny, pp. 155–76.
Aumale, H. d’Orléans, duc d’, Histoire des princes de Condé pendant les XVIe et
XVIIe siècles (7 vols., Paris, 1893–6).
Avant, D., The Market for Force. The Consequences of Privatizing Security
(Cambridge, 2005).
‘Mercenaries’, Foreign Policy, 143 (2004), 20–8.
Bächtiger, F., ‘Andreaskreuz und Schweizerkreuz: zur Feindschaft zwischen
Landsknechten und Eidgenossen’, Jahrbuch des Bernischen Historischen
Museums, 51/52 (1971–2), 205–70.
Badalo-Dulong, C., Banquier du roi, Barthélemi Hervart, 1606–76 (Paris, 1951).
Baetens, R., ‘The Organization and Effects of Flemish Privateering in the
Seventeenth Century’, in Glete (ed.), Naval History, pp. 453–80.
393
394 Bibliography
Bak, J. and B. Király (eds.), From Hunyadi to Rákóczi. War and Society in Late
Medieval and Early Modern Hungary (New York, 1982).
Bannerman, G., Merchants and the Military in Eighteenth-Century Britain. British
Army Contracts and Domestic Supply, 1739–1763 (London, 2008).
Baran, A. and G. Gajecky, The Cossacks in the Thirty Years War (2 vols., Rome,
1983).
Barker, T. M., Army, Aristocracy, Monarchy. Essays on War, Society and Government
in Austria, 1618–1780 (New York, 1982).
Barker, T. M., ‘Military Entrepreneurship, Patronage and Grace’, in Barker,
Army, Aristocracy, Monarchy, pp. 112–27.
Barker, T., The Military Intellectual and Battle. Raimondo Montecuccoli and the
Thirty Years War (Albany, NY, 1975).
‘Ottavio Piccolomini (1599–1659)’, in Barker, Army, Aristocracy, Monarchy,
pp. 61–111.
Barthold, F., Geschichte des großen deutschen Krieges, vom Tode Gustav Adolfs ab, mit
besonderer Rücksicht auf Frankreich (2 vols., Stuttgart, 1842/3).
Bassompierre, François de Betstein, Marshal, Mémoires (4 vols., Paris, 1870–7).
Baudart, G., Les guerres de Nassau (2 vols., Amsterdam, 1616).
Baudson, E., Charles de Gonzague. Duc de Nevers, de Rethel et de Mantoue,
1580–1637 (Paris, 1947).
Baumann, R., Georg von Frundsberg. Vater der Landsknechte (Munich, 1991).
Landsknechte. Ihre Geschichte und Kultur vom späten Mittelalter bis zum
Dreißigjährigen Krieg (Munich, 1994).
Das Söldnerwesen im 16. Jahrhundert im bayerischen und süddeutschen Beispiel. Eine
gesellschaftsgeschichtliche Untersuchung (Munich, 1978).
Baumgartner, F., Henry II, King of France, 1547–1559 (Durham, NC and London,
1988).
Bayard, F., Le monde des financiers au XVIIe siècle (Paris, 1988).
Bean, R., ‘War and the Birth of the Nation State’, Journal of Economic History,
33 (1973), 203–21.
Bei der Wieden, B., ‘Niederdeutsche Söldner vor dem Dreißigjährigen Krieg.
Geistige und mentale Grenzen eines sozialen Raums’, in B. Kroener and
R. Pröve (eds.), Krieg und Frieden. Militär und Gesellschaft in der Frühen Neuzeit
(Paderborn, 1996), pp. 85–107.
Beik, W., ‘Absolutism as Social Collaboration in Louis XIV’s France’, Past and
Present, 188 (2005), 195–224.
Absolutism and Society in Seventeenth-Century France. State Power and Provincial
Aristocracy in Languedoc (Cambridge, 1985).
Belhomme, V., L’armée française en 1690 (Paris, 1895).
Bellamy, M., Christian IV and his Navy (Brill, 2006).
Belli, P., De Re Militari et Bello Tractatus (Venice, 1563).
Bérenger, J., Finances et absolutisme autrichienne dans la seconde moitié du XVIIème
siècle (2 vols., Lille, 1975).
‘Fiscalité et économie en Autriche XVIe–XVIIe siècles’, in J. Bouvier and
J. C. Perrot, États, fiscalités, économies. Actes du cinquième congrès de
l’Association Française des Historiens Économistes (Paris, 1983), pp. 13–25.
Turenne (Paris, 1987).
Bibliography 395
Bien, D., ‘Property in Office under the Ancien Régime. The Case of the
Stockbrokers’, in J. Brewer and S. Staves (eds.), Early Modern Conceptions of
Property (London and New York, 1995), pp. 481–94.
Björlin, J. G., Johan Banér (3 vols., Stockholm, 1908–10).
Blanning, T. C. W., The French Revolutionary Wars, 1787–1802 (London, 1996).
Blastenbrei, P., Die Sforza und ihr Heer. Studien zur Strukture-, Wirtschafts- und
Sozialgeschichte des Söldnerwesens in der italienischen Frührenaissance
(Heidelberg, 1987).
Blau, F., Die deutschen Landsknechte. Ein Kulturbild (Görlitz, 1882).
Blendinger, F., ‘Augsburger Handel im Dreißigjährigen Krieg’, in J. Schneider
(ed.), Wirtschaftskräfte und Wirtschaftswege II. Festschrift für Hermann
Kellenbenz (Stuttgart, 1978), pp. 287–323.
Block, W., Die Condottieri. Studien über die sogenannten ‘unblutigen Schlachten’
(Berlin, 1913).
Bog, I., ‘Krieg und Wirtschaft im 16 Jahrhundert: ein Essay über Kriegswirkungen
and Kriegsfolgen’, in O. Pickl (ed.), Krieg, Militärausgaben und
Wirtschaftlicher Wandel (Graz, 1980), pp. 11–36.
‘Türkenkrieg und Agrarwirtschaft. Einführung in die Probleme der
Heeresversorgung und der Kriegsfinanzierung vor allem in Österreich unter
der Enns und seinen Grenzlandschaften im 16. und 17. Jahrhundert’, in
O. Pickl (ed.), Die wirtschaftlichen Auswirkungen der Türkenkriege (Graz,
1971), pp. 13–26.
Bogucka, M., ‘Saltpeter Production and Saltpeter Trade between Gdansk and
Amsterdam in the First Half of the Seventeenth Century’, in W. G. Heeres
(ed.), From Dunkirk to Danzig. Shipping and Trade in the North Sea and the
Baltic (Amsterdam, 1988), pp. 167–70.
Böhme, K.-L., ‘Geld für die schwedischen Armeen nach 1640’, Scandia, 33
(1967), 54–95.
Bonney, R., The King’s Debts. Finance and Politics in France, 1589–1661 (Oxford,
1981).
Bonney, R. (ed.), Economic Systems and State Finance (Oxford, 1995).
Bracewell, C. W., The Uskoks of Senj. Piracy, Banditry and Holy War in the
Sixteenth-Century Adriatic (Ithaca and London, 1992).
Braddick, M., The Nerves of State. Taxation and the Financing of the English State,
1588–1714 (Manchester, 1996).
State Formation in Early Modern England, c.1550–1700 (Cambridge, 2000).
Brambilla, M., Ludovico Gonzaga, Duca di Nevers, 1539–1595 (Udine, 1905).
Braun, R., ‘Staying on Top: Socio-cultural Reproduction of European Power
Elites’, in W. Reinhard (ed.), Power Elites and State Building (Oxford, 1996),
pp. 235–59.
Breedevelt van Veen, F., Louis de Geer, 1587–1652 (Amsterdam, 1935).
Brewer, J., The Sinews of Power. War, Money and the English State, 1688–1783
(London, 1989).
Bromley, J., Corsairs and Navies, 1660–1760 (London, 1987).
Broucek, P., Die Eroberung von Bregenz am 4. Jänner 1647 (Vienna, 1971).
Der Schwedenfeldzug nach Niederösterreich, 1645–46 (Vienna, 1967).
Bruce, A., The Purchase System in the British Army, 1660–1871 (London, 1980).
396 Bibliography
Bruijn, J., The Dutch Navy of the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries (Columbia,
SC, 1993).
Burin de Roziers, M., ‘Les capitulations militaires entre la Suisse et la France’
(Doctoral thesis, University of Paris, 1902).
Burschel, P., ‘Himmelreich und Hölle. Ein Söldner, sein Tagebuch und die
Ordnungen des Krieges’, in B. von Krusenstjern and H. Medick (eds.),
Zwischen Alltag und Katastrophe. Der Dreißigjährige Krieg aus der Nähe
(Göttingen, 2001), pp. 181–94.
Söldner im Nordwestdeutschland des 16. und 17. Jahrhunderts. Sozialgeschichtliche
Studien (Göttingen, 1994).
Büsch, O., Military System and Social Life in Old Regime Prussia, 1713–1807, trans.
J. Gagliardo (Atlantic Highlands, NJ, 1997).
Caferro, W., ‘Continuity, Long-Term Service, and Permanent Forces: a
Reassessment of the Florentine Army in the Fourteenth Century’, Journal of
Modern History, 80 (2008), 219–51.
John Hawkwood. An English Mercenary in Fourteenth-Century Italy (Baltimore,
2006).
Mercenary Companies and the Decline of Siena (Baltimore, 1998).
Cardini, F., ‘Condottiere e uomini d’arme nell’Italia del Renascimento’, in
M. Del Treppo (ed.), Condottiere e uomini d’arme nell’Italia del Renascimento
(Naples, 2001), pp. 1–10.
Carter, F. W., Dubrovnik (Ragusa). A Classic City State (London, 1972).
Chagniot, J., Paris et l’armée au XVIIIe siècle. Étude politique et sociale (Paris, 1985).
‘La rationalisation de l’armée française après 1660’, in Armées et diplomatie dans
l’Europe du XVIIe Siècle. Actes du Colloque des Association des Historiens
Modernistes (Paris, 1991), pp. 97–108.
Chaline, O., La bataille de la Montagne Blanche. Un mystique chez les guerriers (Paris,
2000).
Chastenet de Puységur, J., Les guerres de Louis XIII et Louis XIV (Amsterdam,
1690).
Chemnitz, B. P. von, Königlichen Schwedischen in Teutschland geführten Kriegs
(4 vol., 2 only extant; Riderholm, 1855).
Childs, J., Armies and Warfare in Europe, 1648–1789 (London, 1982).
Cipolla, C., Guns and Sails in the Early Phase of European Expansion, 1400–1700
(London, 1965).
Clendinnen, I., ‘The Cost of Courage in Aztec Society’, Past and Present,
94 (1982), 44–89.
Collins, J., Fiscal Limits of Absolutism. Direct Taxation in Early Seventeenth-Century
France (Berkeley, CA, 1988).
Concina, E., L’Arsenale della Repubblica di Venezia (Milan, 1984).
Contamine, P., ‘Introduction’, in Contamine (ed.), War and Competition between
States (Oxford, 2000), pp. 1–7.
Cornette, J., ‘La révolution militaire et l’état moderne’, Revue d’histoire moderne et
contemporaine, 41 (1994), 698–709.
Le roi de guerre. Essai sur la souveraineté dans la France du Grand Siècle (Paris, 1993).
Covini, M., L’Esercito del Duca. Organizzazione militare e istitutioni al tempi degli
Sforza (1450–1480) (Rome, 1998).
Bibliography 397
Doucet, R., ‘Le Grand Parti de Lyon au XVIe siècle’, Revue historique, 171 and 172
(1933 and 1934), pp. 473–513, 1–41.
Downing, B., The Military Revolution and Political Change. Origins of Democracy
and Autocracy in Early Modern Europe (Princeton, 1992).
Drévillon, H., L’impôt du sang. Le métier des armes sous Louis XIV (Paris, 2005).
Droysen, G., Bernhard von Weimar (2 vols., Leipzig, 1885).
du Bellay, Guillaume, Instructions sur le faict de la Guerre, extraictes des livres de
Polybe, Frontin, Vegece, Cornazan, Machiavelle, & plusieurs autres bons autheurs
(Paris, 1553).
Duffy, C., The Army of Frederick the Great (Newton Abbot, 1974).
The Army of Maria Theresa (London, 1977).
Instrument of War. The Austrian Army in the Seven Years War (Rosemont, IL,
2000).
The Military Experience in the Age of Reason (London, 1987).
Siege Warfare. The Fortress in the Early Modern World, 1494–1660 (London,
1979).
Duffy, M., ‘The Foundations of British Naval Power’, in Duffy (ed.), The Military
Revolution, pp. 49–85.
(ed.) The Military Revolution and the State (Exeter, 1980).
Dull, J., The French Navy and the Seven Years War (Lincoln, NE, 2005).
Dulong, C., La fortune de Mazarin (Paris, 1990).
Dürr, E., ‘La principauté de Habsbourg et la formation de la Confédération des
VIII cantons, 1315–1379’, in Feldmann and Wirz (eds.), Histoire militaire, II,
pp. 23–64.
Durrer, R., ‘Premier combats de la Suisse primitive’, in Feldmann and Wirz
(eds.), Histoire militaire, I, 29–107.
Earle, P., Corsairs of Malta and Barbary (London, 1970).
Edmundson, G., ‘Louis de Geer’, English Historical Review, 6 (1891), 685–712.
Edwards, P., Dealing in Death. The Arms Trade and the British Civil Wars, 1638–52
(Thrupp, 2000).
Ehrenberg, R., Das Zeitalter der Fugger: Geldkapital und Creditverkehr im 16.
Jahrhundert (2 vols., Jena, 1896).
Elgger, C. von, Kriegswesen und Kriegskunst der schweizerischen Eidgenossen im XIV,
XV und XVI Jahrhundert (Lucerne, 1873).
Engerisser, P., Von Kronach nach Nördlingen (Weißenstadt, 2004).
Engerisser, P. and P. Hrnčiřík, Nördlingen 1634. Die Schlacht bei Nördlingen –
Wendepunkt des Dreißigjährigen Krieges (Weißenstadt, 2009).
Englund, P., Der Verwüstung Deutschlands. Eine Geschichte des Dreißigjährigen
Krieges (Stuttgart, 1998).
Erben, W., ‘Maximilian I. und die Landsknechte’, Historische Zeitschrift, 116
(1916), 48–68.
Ernst, H., ‘Spanische Subsidien für den Kaiser, 1632–42’, in K. Repgen (ed.),
Krieg und Politik (Munich, 1988), pp. 299–302.
Ernstberger, A., Hans de Witte – Finanzmann Wallensteins (Wiesbaden, 1954).
Wallenstein als Volkswirt im Herzogtum Friedland (Reichenberg, 1929).
‘Wallenstein’s Heeressabotage’, in A. Ernstberger, Franken – Böhmen – Europa:
Gesammelte Aufsätze (2 vols., Kallmünz, 1959), I, 269–85.
Bibliography 399
Ertman, T., Birth of the Leviathan. Building States and Regimes in Early Modern
Europe (Cambridge, 1997).
Estríngana, A. E., ‘La ejecución del gasto militar y la gestión de los suministros. El
abastecimiento de pan de munición en el ejército de Flandes durante la
primera mitad des siglo XVII’, in M. Rizzo, J. Ibáñez and G. Sabatini
(eds.), Le forze del principe (2 vols., Murcia, 2004), I, 411–63.
Guerra y finanzas en los Países Bajos católicos. De Farnesio a Spinola (1592–1630)
(Madrid, 2002).
Evans, P., D. Rueschemeyer and T. Skocpol (eds.), Bringing the State Back In
(Cambridge, 1985).
Falke, J. von, Geschichte des fürstlichen Hauses Liechtenstein (2 vols., Vienna, 1877).
Fallon, J., ‘Scottish Mercenaries in the Service of Denmark and Sweden,
1626–1632’ (Ph.D. thesis, University of Glasgow, 1972).
Fantoni, M. (ed.), ‘Il perfetto capitano’. Immagini e realtà (secoli XV–XVII) (Rome,
2001).
Feld, M., ‘Middle Class Society and the Rise of Military Professionalism: the
Dutch Army, 1589–1609’, Armed Forces and Society, 1 (1975), 419–42.
Feldmann, M. and H. Wirz (eds.), Histoire militaire de la Suisse (4 vols., Berne,
1915–35).
Ferrier-Caverivière, N., L’image de Louis XIV dans la littérature française, de 1660 à
1715 (Paris, 1981).
Ffoulkes, C., The Gun Founders of England (London, 1969).
Fiedler, S., Kriegswesen und Kriegführung im Zeitalter der Landsknechte (Koblenz,
1985).
Fieffé, E., Histoire des troupes étrangères au service de la France (2 vols., Paris, 1854).
Fieger, M., Der kriegerische Ereignisse in der Oberpfalz. Vom Einfalle Baners 1641 bis
zum Westfälischen Frieden (Dillingen, 1909–10).
Finkel, C., The Administration of Warfare. The Ottoman Military Campaigns in
Hungary, 1593–1606 (Vienna, 1988).
Fischer, R. von, ‘Les Guerres de Bourgogne (1474–77)’, in Feldmann and Wirz
(eds.), Histoire militaire, II, pp. 155–201.
Fogel, M., Les cérémonies de l’information dans la France du XVI au milieu du XVIII
siècle (Paris, 1989).
Forrest, A., ‘La patrie en danger. The French Revolution and the first Levée en
masse’, in D. Moran and A. Waldron (eds.), The People in Arms: Military Myth
and National Mobilization since the French Revolution (Cambridge, 2003),
pp. 8–32.
Förster, S., C. Jansen and G. Kronenbitter (eds.), Rückkehr der Condottieri? Krieg
und Militär zwischen staatlichem Monopol und Privatisierung: Von der Antike bis
zur Gegenwart (Paderborn, 2010).
Fowler, K., Medieval Mercenaries, Vol. I: The Great Companies (Oxford, 2001).
Frachetta, G., Il Prencipe, nel quale si considera il Prencipe, & quanto al governo dello
Stato, & quanto al maneggio della Guerra (Venice, 1599).
France, J., Mercenaries and Paid Men. The Mercenary Identity in the Middle Ages
(Brill, 2008).
Frauenholz, E. von, Entwicklungsgeschichte des deutschen Heerwesens (5 vols.,
Munich, 1935–41).
400 Bibliography
Lazarus von Schwendi. Der Erste Deutsche Verkünder der allgemeinen Wehrpflicht
(Hamburg, 1939).
Freytag, G., Der Dreißigjährigen Krieg, 1618–1648. Das Heer. Soldatenleben und
Sitten (3 vols., 1859; repr. Bad Langensalza, 2003).
Friday, K., Hired Swords. The Rise of Private Warrior Power in Early Japan
(Stanford, CA, 1992).
Friedlaender, E., ‘Protokoll über die Kontributionen und Kriegskosten des Ober-
Barnimschen Kreises aus den Jahren 1630–1634’, Märkische Forschungen,
17 (1882), 139–428.
Fronsperger, L., Kriegsordnung und Regiment, sampt derselbigen befehl, statt und
Ampter zu Roß und zu Fuß . . . (Frankfurt, 1564).
Frost, R., The Northern Wars, 1558–1721 (London, 2000).
Fučiková, E. and L. Čepička (eds.), Albrecht von Waldstein. Inter arma silent musae?
(Exhibition catalogue; Prague, 2007).
Fusero, C., I Doria (Milan, 1973).
Gaier, C., Four Centuries of Liège Gunmaking, trans F. J. Norris (Liège, 1976).
Gambiez, F., ‘Turenne et la renaissance du style indirect’, in Turenne et l’art
militaire. Actes de Colloque International, 2/3 Oct. 1975 (Paris, 1975),
pp. 15–21.
Gembruch, W., Staat und Heer. Ausgewählte historische Studien zum ancien régime,
zur Französischen Revolution und zu den Befreiungskriegen. Historische
Forschungen 40 (Berlin, 1990).
Geyso, F. von, ‘Beiträge zur Politik und Kriegsführung Hessens im Zeitalter des
Dreißigjährigen Krieges’, Zeitschrift für Hessische Geschichte, 53 (1921), 14–30.
Gindely, A., Waldstein während seines ersten Generalats, im Lichte der gleichzeitigen
Quellen, 1625–1630 (2 vols., Prague and Leipzig, 1886).
Glete, J., Navies and Nations. Warships, Navies and State-Building in Europe and
America, 1500–1860 (2 vols., Stockholm, 1993).
Swedish Naval Administration, 1521–1721 (Leiden, 2010).
War and the State in Early Modern Europe. Spain, the Dutch Republic and Sweden
as Fiscal-Military States, 1500–1660 (London, 2002).
Warfare at Sea, 1500–1650. Maritime Conflicts and the Transformation of Europe
(London, 2000).
Glete, J. (ed.), Naval History, 1500–1680 (Aldershot, 2005).
Glümer, H., ‘Die Braunschweigischen Söldnertruppen zu Fuß und Roß in den Jahren
1599–1615’, Jahrbuch des Braunschweigischen Geschichtsvereins, 8 (1936), 47–76.
Goldsworthy, A., The Roman Army at War, 100BC–AD200 (Oxford, 1996).
Gommans, J., Mughal Warfare (London, 2002).
González de León, F., ‘“Doctors of the Military Discipline”. Technical Expertise
and the Paradigm of the Spanish Soldier in the Early Modern Period’,
Sixteenth Century Journal, 27 (1996), 61–85.
The Road to Rocroi. Class, Culture and Command in the Spanish Army of Flanders,
1567–1659 (Brill, 2009).
Gonzenbach, A. von, Der General Hans Ludwig von Erlach von Castelen (3 vols.,
Berne, 1880–2).
Goodman, D., Spanish Naval Power, 1589–1665. Reconstruction and Defeat
(Cambridge, 1997).
Bibliography 401
Jarrys de La Roche, C., Die Dreißigjährige Krieg vom militärischen Standpunkte aus
beleuchtet (3 vols., Schaffhausen, 1848).
Jespersen, L., ‘The Machtstaat in Seventeenth-Century Denmark’, Scandinavian
Journal of History, 10 (1985), 271–304.
Jones, C., ‘The Military Revolution and the Professionalization of the French
Army under the Ancien Régime’, in M. Duffy (ed.), The Military Revolution
and the State, 1500–1800 (Exeter, 1980), pp. 29–48.
Jorgensen, J., ‘Denmark’s Relations with Lübeck and Hamburg in the
Seventeenth Century’, Scandinavian Economic History Review, 11 (1963),
73–116.
Jouanna, A., ‘La noblesse et les valeurs guerrières au XVIe siècle’, in G.-A.
Pérousse, A. Thierry and A. Tournon (eds.), L’homme de guerre au XVIe
siècle (Saint-Etienne, 1992), pp. 205–17.
Judges, A., ‘Philip Burlamachi: a Financier of the Thirty Years War’, Economica,
16 (1926), 285–300.
Junkelmann, M., ‘Feldherr Maximilians: Johann Tserclaes Graf von Tilly’, in Um
Glauben und Reich. Kurfürst Maximilian I (Exhibition catalogue, 3 vols.,
Munich, 1980), II (i), pp. 377–99.
Kaiser, D., Politics and War. European Conflict from Philip II to Hitler (London,
1990).
Kaiser, M., ‘Cuius exercitus, eius religio? Konfession und Heerwesen im Zeitalter
des Dreißigjährigen Kriegs’, Archiv für Reformationsgeschichte, 91 (2000),
316–53.
‘Die Lebenswelt der Söldner und das Phänomen der Desertion im
Dreißigjährigen Krieg’, Osnabrücker Mitteilungen, 103 (1998), 105–24.
Politik und Kriegsführung. Maximilian von Bayern, Tilly und die Katholische Liga
im Dreißigjährigen Krieg (Münster, 1999).
‘“Sed vincere sciebat Hanibal”. Pappenheim als empirischer Theoretiker des
Krieges’, in H. Neuhaus and B. Stollberg-Rilinger (eds.), Menschen und
Strukturen in der Geschichte Alteuropas (Berlin, 2002), pp. 201–27.
Kaiser, M. and S. Kroll, ‘Introduction’, in M. Kaiser and S. Kroll (eds.), Militär
und Religiosität in der Frühen Neuzeit (Münster, 2004), pp. 11–19.
Kapser, C., Die bayerische Kriegsorganisation in der zweiten Hälfte des Dreißigjährigen
Krieges, 1635–1648/49 (Münster, 1997).
‘Handel und Militär in Frankfurt zur Zeit des Dreißigjährigen Krieges’, in
R. Koch (ed.), Brücke zwischen den Völkern – Zur Geschichte der Frankfurter
Messe (3 vols., Frankfurt am Main, 1991), II, pp. 140–6.
Karner, H., ‘Unter dem Stern des Mars. Bildausstatung des Waldsteinspalais
zwischen Programm und Pragmatik’, in Fučiková, Čepička (eds.),
Waldstein, pp. 127–43.
Keep, J., Soldiers of the Tsar. Army and Society in Russia, 1462–1874 (Oxford,
1985).
Kellenbenz, H., Unternehmerkräfte im Hamburger Portugal- und Spanienhandel,
1590–1625 (Hamburg, 1954).
Kennedy, P., The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. Economic Change and Military
Conflict from 1500–2000 (London, 1988).
Kennett, L., The French Armies in the Seven Years War (Durham, NC, 1967).
Bibliography 405
Kiernan, V., ‘Foreign Mercenaries and Absolute Monarchy’, Past and Present,
11 (1956–7), 66–86.
Kinsey, C., Corporate Soldiers and International Security. The Rise of Private Military
Companies (London, 2006).
Kirk, T., Genoa and the Sea. Policy and Power in an Early Modern Maritime Republic,
1559–1684 (Baltimore and London, 2005).
Klein, P. W., ‘The Trip Family in the Seventeenth Century: a Study of the
Behaviour of the Entrepreneur on the Dutch Staple Market’, Acta Historiae
Neerlandica, 1 (1966), 187–211.
Klopp, O., Tilly im Dreißigjährigen Kriege (2 vols., Stuttgart, 1861).
Knecht, R. J., Renaissance Warrior and Patron. The Reign of Francis I (Cambridge,
1994).
Knight, R. and M. Wilcox, Sustaining the Fleet, 1793–1815. War, the British Navy
and the Contractor State (Woodbridge, 2010).
Kober, U., Eine Karriere im Krieg. Graf Adam von Schwarzenberg und die kurbran-
denburgische Politik von 1619 bis 1641 (Berlin, 2004).
Koch, K., ‘Wallenstein 1583–1625’ (Dissertation, Düsseldorf, 1908–9).
Koenigsberger, H., ‘The Organization of Revolutionary Parties in France and the
Netherlands during the Sixteenth Century’, in Koenigsberger, Estates and
Revolutions (Ithaca, 1971), pp. 224–52.
Koerner, M. H., ‘Der Einfluss der Europäischen Kriege auf die Struktur der
Schweizerischen Finanzen im 16 Jahrhundert’, in O. Pickl (ed.), Krieg,
Militärausgaben und Wirtschaftlicher Wandel (Graz, 1980), pp. 37–45.
Kolff, D., Naukar, Rajput and Sepoy. The Ethnohistory of the Military Labour Market
in Hindustan, 1450–1850 (Cambridge, 1990).
Konečnŷ, L., ‘Die gemalte Ausstattung des Waldsteinpalais in Prag: Versuch einer
(verfrühten) Synthese’, in Fučiková and Čepička (eds.), Waldstein,
pp. 144–57.
Konze, F., ‘Die Stärke, Zusammensetzung und Verteilung der Wallensteinischen
Armee während des Jahres 1633. Ein Beitrag zur Heeresgeschichte des 30
Jährigen Krieges’ (Dissertation, Frankfurt am Main, 1906).
Körner, M., ‘Zur eidgenössischen Solddienst- und Pensionendebatte im 16.
Jahrhundert’, in N. Furrer, L. Hubler, M. Stubenvoll and D. Tosato-Rigo
(eds.), Gente ferocissima. Mercenariat et société en Suisse (XV–XIX siècle) –
Festschrift für Alain Dubois (Zurich, 1997), pp. 193–203.
Kostic, V., Ragusa and the Spanish Armada (Belgrade, 1972).
Kraus, J., Das Militärwesen der Reichsstadt Augsburg, 1548–1806 (Augsburg,
1980).
Krebs, J., Aus dem Leben des kaiserlichen Feldmarschalls Grafen Melzior von Hatzfeld,
1593–1631 (Breslau, 1910).
Aus dem Leben des kaiserlichen Feldmarschalls Grafen Melchior von Hatzfeld,
1632–36. Ein Beitrag zur Geschichte des Dreißigjährigen Krieges (Breslau,
1926).
Kroener, B., ‘Vom “extraordinari Kriegsvolck” zum “miles perpetuus”. Zur Rolle
der bewaffneten Macht in der europäischen Gesellschaft der Frühen
Neuzeit’, in Kroener, Kriegerische Gewalt und militärische Pråsenz in der
Neuzeit (Paderborn, 2008), pp. 3–63.
406 Bibliography
Lana, E. O., Los corsarios espagñoles durante la decadencia de los Austrias. El corso
español del Atlántico peninsular en el siglo XVII (Madrid, 1992).
Landberg, H., L. Ekholm, R. Nordlund and S. Nilsson (eds.), Det kontinentala
krigets ekonomie. Studier i krigsfinansierung under svensk stormaktstid
(Kristianstad, 1971).
Lane, F., ‘Economic Consequences of Organized Violence’, Journal of Economic
History, 18 (1958), 401–17.
‘The Economic Meaning of War and Protection’, in Lane, Venice and History
(Baltimore, 1966).
Venetian Ships and Shipbuilders of the Renaissance (Baltimore and London, 1992).
Lane-Fox, R. (ed.), The Long March. Xenophon and the Ten Thousand (New Haven
and London, 2004).
Langer, H., ‘Army Finances, Production and Commerce’, in K. Bussmann and
H. Schilling (eds.), 1648. War and Peace in Europe (3 vols., Munich, 1998), I,
pp. 293–9.
La Noue, F. de, Discours politiques et militaires (Geneva, 1967).
La Roche, C. du Jarrys, Freiherr von, Der Dreißigjährige Krieg vom militärischen
Standpunkte aus beleuchtet (3 vols., Schaffhausen, 1848).
Leestmans, C., Charles IV de Lorraine, 1604–75. Une errance baroque (Lasne, 2003).
Lefèvre, J., Spinola et la Belgique (1601–1627) (Brussels, 1947).
Le Fur, D., Marignan, 13–14 septembre 1515 (Paris, 2004).
Léonard, E., L’armée et ses problèmes au XVIIIe siècle (Paris, 1958).
Leupold, E., ‘Journal der Armee des Herzogs Bernhard von Sachsen-Weimar aus
den Jahren 1637 und 1638’, Basler Zeitschrift für Geschichte und
Altertumskunde, 11 (1912), 253–362.
Lindegren J., ‘The Swedish Military State, 1560–1720’, Scandinavian Journal of
History, 10 (1985), 305–36.
Lipsius, J., Sixe Bookes of Politickes or Civil Doctrine (London, 1594; facsimile edn,
Amsterdam and New York, 1970).
Litta, P., Famiglie celebri italiane (18 vols., Milan, 1819–82).
Lockhart, P., Denmark in the Thirty Years War, 1618–48 (Selinsgrove, 1996).
Lonchay, H. (ed.), Commentario del Coronel Francisco Verdugo de la Guerra de Frisa
(Brussels, 1899).
Lorentzen, T., Die Schwedische Armee im Dreißigjährigen Kriege (Leipzig, 1894).
Losman, A., Carl Gustaf Wrangel och Europa. Studier i kulturförbindelser kring en
1600-talsmagnat (Stockholm, 1980).
Lot, F., Recherches sur les effectifs des armées françaises des Guerres d’Italie aux Guerres
de Religion, 1494–1562 (Paris, 1962).
Louis XIV, Memoirs for the Instruction of the Dauphin, ed. P. Sonnino (London, 1970).
Louvois, F.-M. le Tellier, marquis de, Lettres de Louvois à Louis XIV, ed. N. Salat
and T. Sarmant (Paris, 2007).
Luh, J., Kriegskunst in Europa, 1650–1800 (Cologne, 2004).
Lund, E., War for the Every Day. Generals, Knowledge, and Warfare in Early Modern
Europe, 1680–1740 (Westport, CT and London, 1999).
Lundkvist, S., ‘Schwedische Kriegsfinanzierung, 1630–35’, in H. Rudolf (ed.),
Der Dreißigjährigen Krieg: Perspectiven and Strukturen (Darmstadt, 1977),
pp. 298–303.
408 Bibliography
Orlandi, A., Le Grand Parti. Fiorentini a Lione e il debito pubblico Francese nel XVI
secolo (Florence, 2002).
Ostwald, J., ‘The “Decisive” Battle of Ramillies, 1706: Prerequisites for
Decisiveness in Early Modern Warfare’, Journal of Military History, 64
(2000), 649–77.
Vauban under Siege. Engineering Efficiency and Martial Vigor in the War of the
Spanish Succession (Brill, 2007).
Pablo, J. de, ‘L’armée huguenote entre 1562 et 1573’, Archiv für
Reformationsgeschichte, 48 (1957), 192–216.
Padrutt, C., Staat und Krieg im Alten Bünden (Zurich, 1965).
Palmer, M., ‘The “Military Revolution” Afloat. The Era of the Anglo-Dutch Wars
and the Transition to Modern Warfare at Sea’, War in History, 4 (1997),
123–49.
Papke, G., Handbuch zur deutschen Militärgeschichte, 1648–1939, Vol. I: Von der
Miliz zum Stehenden Heer. Wehrwesen im Absolutismus (Munich, 1979).
Paret, P., ‘Conscription and the End of the Ancien Régime in France and Prussia’,
in Paret, Understanding War. Essays on Clausewitz and the History of Military
Power (Princeton, 1992), pp. 53–74.
Pâris de Bollardière, B., Joseph Pâris Duverney et ses frères. Financiers dauphinois à la
cour de Louis XV (Toulon, 2006).
Parker, G., The Army of Flanders and the Spanish Road, 1567–1659 (2nd edn,
Cambridge, 2004).
‘The Dreadnought Revolution of the Sixteenth Century’, The Mariner’s Mirror,
82 (1996), 269–300.
The Dutch Revolt (London, 1977).
‘The Limits to Revolutions in Military Affairs: Maurice of Nassau, the Battle of
Nieuwpoort (1600) and the Legacy’, Journal of Military History, 71 (2007),
331–72.
The Military Revolution. Military Innovation and the Rise of the West, 1500–1800
(2nd edn, Cambridge, 1996).
Parker, Captain Robert, Memoirs, ed. D. Chandler (London, 1968).
Parrott, D., ‘A Prince Souverain and the French Crown: Charles de Nevers,
1580–1637’, in R. Oresko, G. Gibbs and H. Scott (eds.), Royal and
Republican Sovereignty in Early Modern Europe (Cambridge, 1997),
pp. 149–87.
‘Strategy and Tactics in the Thirty Years War: the “Military Revolution’’ ’, in
C. Rogers (ed.), The Military Revolution Debate (Boulder, CO, 1995), pp. 227–51.
Richelieu’s Army. War, Government and Society in France, 1624–42 (Cambridge,
2001).
‘Richelieu, the Grands and the French Army’, in J. Bergin and L. Brockliss
(eds.), Richelieu and his Age (Oxford, 1992), pp. 149–72.
Pepper, S. and N. Adams, Firearms and Fortifications: Military Architecture and
Siege Warfare in Sixteenth-Century Siena (Chicago, 1986).
Percy, S., Mercenaries. The History of a Norm in International Relations (Oxford,
2007).
‘Mercenaries: Strong Norm, Weak Law’, International Organization, 61 (2007),
367–97.
Bibliography 411
Perjes, G., ‘Army Provisioning, Logistics and Strategy in the Second Half of the
Seventeenth Century’, Acta Historica Scientiarum Hungaricae, 16 (1970),
1–51.
Peters, J. (ed.), Ein Söldnerleben im Dreißigjährigen Krieg (Berlin, 1993).
Petersen, L., ‘Defence, War and Finance: Christian IV and the Council of the
Realm, 1596–1629’, Scandinavian Journal of History, 7 (1982), 277–313.
Phillips, C., Six Galleons for the King of Spain (Baltimore, 1986).
Pohl, J., ‘Die Profiantirung der keyserlichen Armaden ahnbelangendt’. Studien zur
Versorgung der kaiserlichen Armee, 1634–35 (Vienna, 1994).
Polišenský, J. and J. Kollmann, Wallenstein. Feldherr des Dreißigjährigen Krieges
(Cologne, 1997).
Porter, B., War and the Rise of the State. The Military Foundations of Modern Politics
(New York, 1994).
Potter, D., ‘The International Mercenary Market in the Sixteenth Century:
Anglo-French Competition in Germany, 1543–50’, English Historical Review,
111 (1996), 24–58.
Renaissance France at War. Armies, Culture and Society, c. 1480–1560 (Woodbridge,
2008).
Potter, M., Corps and Clienteles. Public Finance and Political Change in France,
1688–1715 (Aldershot, 2003).
‘War Finance and Absolutist State Development in Early Modern Europe. An
Examination of French Venality in the Seventeenth Century’, Journal of Early
Modern History, 7 (2003), 120–47.
Pritchard, J., Louis XV’s Navy, 1748–1762. A Study of Organization and
Administration (Kingston, Canada, 1987).
Probst, N., ‘Naval Operations during the Torstensson War, 1643–45’, Revue
internationale d’histoire militaire, 84 (2004).
Puype, J. P., ‘Victory at Nieuwpoort, 2 July 1600’, in van der Hoeven (ed.),
Exercise of Arms, pp. 76–102.
Quatrefages, R., La revolución militar moderna. El crisol espanol (Madrid, 1996).
Los tercios españoles (1567–1577) (Madrid, 1979).
Quazza, R., La guerra per la successione di Mantova e del Monferrato (2 vols., Mantua,
1926).
Rambeaud, P., ‘L’admiral à La Rochelle: l’union du ciel et de la mer’, in Acerra
and Martinière, eds., Coligny, pp. 131–43.
Randa, A., Pro Republica Christiana. Die Walachei im ‘langen’ Türkenkrieg der
Katholischen Universalmächte 1593–1606 (Monachii, 1964).
Rebitsch, R., Matthias Gallas (1588–1647). Generalleutnant des Kaisers zur Zeit des
Dreißigjährigen Krieges (Münster, 2006).
Wallenstein. Biografie eines Machtmenschen (Vienna, 2010).
Redlich, F., ‘Contributions in the Thirty Years War’, Economic History Review,
2nd ser., 12 (1959–60), 247–54.
The German Military Enterpriser and his Work Force, 14th to 18th Centuries.
Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 47/48 (2 vols.,
Wiesbaden, 1964).
‘Die Marketender’, Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte, 41
(1954), 227–52.
412 Bibliography
‘Military Entrepreneurship and the Credit System in the sixteenth and seven-
teenth Centuries’, Kyklos, 10 (1957), 186–93.
‘Plan for the Establishment of a War Industry in the Imperial Dominions during
the Thirty Years War’, Business History Review, 38 (1964), 123–6.
De Praede Militari. Looting and Booty, 1500–1815, Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial-
und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 39 (Wiesbaden, 1956).
Reinhard, W., ‘Power Elites, State Servants, Ruling Classes and the Growth of
State Power’, in Reinhard (ed.), Power Elites and State Building (Oxford,
1996), pp. 1–18.
Revol, J., Turenne. Essai de psychologie militaire (Paris, 1910).
Ritter, M., ‘Das Kontributionssystem Wallensteins’, Historische Zeitschrift,
54 (1902–3), 193–249.
Roberts, M., ‘Gustav Adolf and the Art of War’, in Roberts, Essays in Swedish
History (London, 1967), pp. 56–81.
Gustavus Adolphus. A History of Sweden, 1611–1632 (2 vols., London, 1958).
‘The Military Revolution, 1560–1660’ (Belfast, 1956), repr. in Roberts, Essays
in Swedish History (London, 1967), pp. 195–225.
Rodger, N. A. M., The Command of the Ocean. A Naval History of Britain,
1649–1815 (London, 2004).
‘The Development of Broadside Gunnery, 1450–1650’, The Mariner’s Mirror,
82 (1996), 301–24.
The Wooden World. An Anatomy of the Georgian Navy (London, 1986).
The Safeguard of the Sea. A Naval History of Britain, 660–1649 (London, 1997).
Rodríguez-Salgado, M. J., The Changing Face of Empire. Charles V, Philip II and
Habsburg Authority, 1551–59 (Cambridge, 1988).
Rogg, M., Landsknechte und Reisläufer: Bilder vom Soldaten. Ein Stand in der Kunst
des 16. Jahrhunderts (Paderborn, 2002).
‘“Wol auff mit mir, du schoenes weyb”. Anmerkungen zur Konstruktion von
Männlichkeit im Soldatenbild des 16. Jahrhunderts’, in K. Hagemann and
R. Pröve (eds.), Landsknechte, Soldatenfrauen und Nationalkrieger (Frankurt
am Main, 1998), pp. 51–73.
‘“Zerhauen und zerschnitten, nach adelichen Sitten”. Herkunft, Entwicklung und
Funktion soldatischer Tracht des 16. Jahrhundert im Spiegel zeitgenössischer
Kunst’, in Kroener and Pröve (eds.), Krieg und Frieden, pp. 109–35.
Rohan, H. de, Le parfaict capitaine (Paris, 1636).
Romano, R., ‘Economic Aspects of the Construction of Warships in Venice in the
Sixteenth Century’, in Glete (ed.), Naval History, 1500–1680, pp. 129–57.
Root, H., The Fountain of Privilege. Political Foundations of Markets in Old Regime
France and England (Berkeley, CA, 1994).
Rothenberg, G., The Art of Warfare in the Age of Napoleon (London, 1977).
The Austrian Military Border in Croatia, 1522–1747 (Urbana, IL, 1960).
Rousset, C., Histoire de Louvois et de son administration politique et militaire (4 vols.,
Paris, 1879).
Rowlands, G., The Dynastic State and the Army under Louis XIV. Royal Service and
Private Interest, 1661–1701 (Cambridge, 2002).
Rudolf. H. (ed.), Der Dreißigjährige Krieg. Perspectiven und Strukturen (Darmstadt,
1977).
Bibliography 413
Ruppert, K., Die kaiserliche Politik auf dem Westfälischen Friedenskongreß, 1643–48
(Münster, 1979).
Ruscelli, G., Precetti della Militia Moderna, tanto per mare quanto per terra (Venice,
1583).
Sabatier, G., Versailles ou la figure du roi (Paris, 1999).
Salm, H., Armeefinanzierung im Dreißigjährigen Krieg. Die Niederrheinisch-
Westfälische Reichskreis, 1635–50 (Münster, 1990).
Sánchez, R. T. (ed.), War, State and Development. Fiscal-Military States in the
Eighteenth Century (Pamplona, 2007).
Savelli, R., ‘Giovanni (Gian) Andrea Doria’, in Dizionario Biografico degli Italiani
(Rome, 1960–), XLI, pp. 361–75.
Scahill, J., Blackwater. The Rise of the World’s Most Powerful Mercenary Army
(London, 2007).
Scarisbrick, J. J., Henry VIII (London, 1968).
Schaufelberger, W., Der Alte Schweizer und sein Krieg. Studien zur Kriegsführung
vornehmlich im 15. Jahrhundert (Zurich, 1952).
Schmidt, G., ‘Voraussetzung oder Legitimation? Kriegsdienst und Adel im
Dreißigjährigen Krieg’, in G. Oexle and W. Paravicini (eds.), Nobilitas.
Funktion und Repräsentation des Adels in Alteuropa (Göttingen, 1997),
pp. 431–51.
Schneider, J., ‘The Significance of Large Fairs, Money Markets and Precious
Metals in the Evolution of a World Market’, in H. Kellenbenz and
E. Schmitt (eds.), The Emergence of a World Economy, 1500–1914 (2 vols.,
Wiesbaden, 1986), I, pp. 15–36.
Schnitter, H., ‘Söldnerheer und Landesdefension. Militärische Alternativenent-
wicklungen im Verhältnis von Volk, Staat und Streitmacht im spätfeudalen
deutschen Reich in der Zeit des Übergangs vom Feudalismus zum
Kapitalismus (15 Jh. bis 1789)’, in H. Timmermann (ed.), Die Bildung des
frühmodernen Staates – Stände und Konfessionen (Saarbrücken, 1989),
pp. 405–20.
Volk und Landesdefension. Volksaufgebote, Defensionswerke, Landmilizen in den
Deutschen Territorien vom 15. bis zum 18. Jahrhundert (Berlin, 1977).
Schöningh, F. J., Die Rehlinger von Augsburg. Ein Beitrag zur deutschen
Wirtschaftsgeschichte des 16. und 17. Jahrhunderts (Paderborn, 1927).
Schröder, P., ‘The Constitution of the Holy Roman Empire after 1648: Samuel
Pufendorf’s Assessment in his Monzambano’, Historical Journal, 42 (1999),
961–83.
Schröder, S., ‘Hamburg und Schweden im Dreißigjährigen Krieg – vom poten-
tiellen Bündnispartner zum Zentrum der Kriegsfinanzierung’,
Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte, 79 (1989), 305–31.
Schulten, C., ‘Une nouvelle approche de Maurice de Nassau (1567–1625)’, in
P. Chaunu (ed.), Le soldat, la stratégie, la mort: mélanges André Corvisier (Paris,
1989), pp. 42–53.
Schulze, W., ‘Die Deutsche Landesdefensionen im 16. und 17. Jahrhundert’, in
B. Stolberg-Rilinger and J. Kunisch (eds.), Staatsverfassung und
Heeresverfassung in der europäischen Geschichte der frühen Neuzeit (Berlin,
1986), pp. 129–49.
414 Bibliography
419
420 Index
fortresses, 32, 74–5, 112, 148–9, 278, 290, fortune of, 244
304, 321 on Imperial garrisons, 189
prestige of capture, 195 and sack of Mantua, 244
provisioning of, 224 galleons, 75, 83, 85
Frachetta, Girolamo, 262 construction contracts, 222, 251
France galleys, 74, 75, 85
1636 invasion, 175, 179, 185 captains, 206
civil wars, 72, 87–8, 266, 269–70 contracting, 80–3
fiscal burdens on, 314 Genoese, 38, 206, 220, 229
military devolution, 22, 95, 266–7, 270 Order of St John, 37, 229
military underperformance, 1635–59, Order of Santo Stefano, 38
269 profits from management, 207–8
Revolutionary Wars, 10, 313, 319, 326 state administered, 80, 82, 83
rise of absolutism, 10, 271 Venetian Arsenale, 198, 200
François I, king of France, 27, 52, 57, 255 Venetian Republic, 74
Frankfurt am Main, 212, 240 Gardie, Magnus de La, 280
Frederick I, king of Prussia, 9 garrisons, 86, 112, 130, 139, 172
Frederick II (the Great), king of Prussia, 9 of captured places, 187
and mercenaries, 290 contracts for supply, 221–2
Frederick V, Palatine Elector, 106 feeding field armies, 184
Frederick Henry of Orange-Nassau, French, 179, 278
Stadholder, 112 negotiating supply contracts, 211
Freiburg, battle of (1644), 151, 187 in Silesia, 211
French army, 224–5, 285, 324 Swedish, 189, 229, 280
exploitation of officers, 268, 273 in Westphalia, 182
and central control, 269, 273 Gattamelata family, 43
of Germany, 186, 187, 189–91 Geer, Louis de, 86
lack of regimental longevity, 268 cannon manufacture, 201
and language of sovereignty, 271–2 and international arms trade, 213
and mercenaries, 87, 108–9, 247, 254, partnership with Trip family, 213
266, 267, 269, 273 saltpetre monopoly, 213–14
reforms of 1660s, 270–1, 286 Swedish interests, 236–9
size of, 12, 30, 74, 274, 276, 320 Geiger, Anton and Tobias (bankers), 210,
venality of military office, 275–7 232, 243
French navy, 278–9, 301, 306 general contractor, 23, 102, 105, 135,
and Colbert clientele, 271, 324 246–7
guerre de course, 305–6 Generalkriegskommissariat (Brandenburg),
shipbuilding, 198 290
size of, 274 Genoa, Republic of, 38, 85, 95, 212, 219,
Frey-Aldenhoven, Anton, 216 303
Friedland, duchy of, 176, 229, 233–6 defence in 1625, 214
Friedrich Wilhelm I, king in Prussia, 298 Great Council, 219
Friedrich Wilhelm, Elector of Brandenburg, Gentile, Marco Antonio, 221
281, 283, 296, 298 Gevierthaufe. See Haufe
Fritsch, Augustin von, 168 Gonzaga, Alfonso, marquis of Pomaro, 254
Frundsberg, Georg von, 57, 60, 241 Gonzaga, Annibale, 254
Fürstenberg, Wilhelm von, 59 Gonzaga, dukes of Mantua, 38, 46
Fugger family, 92, 128, 225, 251 Gonzaga, Federigo, 254
Fugger, Franz, Graf von Kirchberg, 225 Gonzaga, Vespasiano, duke of Sabbioneta,
46, 254
Galen, Christoph Bernhard von, bishop of Götz, Johann, 176
Münster, 281 Graffior, Antonio, 221
Gallas, Matthias, 122, 191 Grand Parti (Lyon bankers), 71, 72, 240
campaign of 1644, 175 Grandson, battle of (1476), 47
career of, 175, 250–1 Gray, Colin, 307
Index 423