Public Goods For Economic Development - Sale - 0
Public Goods For Economic Development - Sale - 0
Public Goods For Economic Development - Sale - 0
B36
V.08-57150—November 2008—1,000 ISBN 978-92-1-106444-5
UNIDO Publication
Sales No. E.08.II.B36
ISBN 978-92-1-106444-5
The designations employed, descriptions and classifications of countries, and the presentation of the material
in this document do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Secretariat of the
United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO) concerning the legal status of any country, terri-
tory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries, or its eco-
nomic system or degree of development. The responsibility for opinions expressed rests solely with the authors,
and publication does not constitute an endorsement by UNIDO of the opinions expressed. Although great care
has been taken to maintain the accuracy of information herein, neither UNIDO nor its Member States assume
any responsibility for consequences which may arise from the use of the material. This document may be freely
quoted or reprinted but acknowledgement is requested. This document has been produced without formal United
Nations editing. The views expressed in this document do not necessarily reflect the views of the Secretariat of
the United Nations Industrial Development Organization. Terms such as “developed, “industrialized” and “devel-
oping” are intended for statistical convenience and do not necessarily express a judgment. Any indication of,
or reference to, a country, institution or other legal entity does not constitute an endorsement.
PREFACE
S
ince the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) published its first
book on global public goods in 1999, the global public goods approach has
been on the agenda of multilateral agencies such as the International Monetary
Fund, World Bank, Food and Agriculture Organization, World Trade Organization
and United Nations Industrial Development Organization; non-governmental organi-
zations; and donor countries. Donor countries have also begun examining the role of
public goods in the development process. France and Sweden created the International
Task Force on Global Public Goods in December 2003 to “assess and prioritize inter-
national public goods, global and regional, and make recommendations to policy
makers and other stakeholders on how to improve and expand their provision.” There
has also been growing interest in the academic community in the transnational public
goods approach.
Because global public goods tend to be underfunded and undersupplied, par-
ticularly those that would benefit the economic development of developing countries,
this UNIDO publication aims to enrich and complement the international public de-
bate by examining in more detail the relationship between such market failures as
public goods and externalities and the economic development in developing countries.
The focus is on four core areas:
1. Addressing the financial instability that threatens development and may lead to
distortions in the allocation of resources, curbing productivity and income growth.
Addressing financial instability is an integral part of effective development and
institutional capacity building and requires national and international action.
2. Enhancing market integration, because trade is vital for poverty elimination.
3. Creating developmentally relevant knowledge. Diffusion of technology is the key
to productivity convergence, but severe structural barriers impede the process. It is
thus essential to ensure the provision of the public goods required to foster the in-
ternational diffusion of technical knowledge and to enable developing countries to
overcome market failures.
4. Protecting the global economic environment by making environmental manage-
ment an integral component of poverty reduction, with major long-term impacts
on health and other key aspects of human development.
Institutional innovations are needed within the United Nations system to take
full advantage of the potential of the wealth of knowledge, skills, experience and re-
sources of institutions that have been working on these matters for the last 40 years.
This has implications for organizations concerned with economic development, like
UNIDO. Through internal restructuring, reorganization of its operations and substan-
tive improvements in its approach to research and technical cooperation UNIDO has
Preface iii
Acknowledgements vv
Introduction: Overcoming market failures for economic development 1
Chapter 1 The concept of international public goods 5
Global interdependence and international public goods 5
Need for cooperation and collective action 6
Externalities and public goods: conceptual clarifications 7
Explaining the incentives of public goods’ supply: aggregation 9
technologies
Geographic scope of spillover effects: cross-border, regional and global 12
public goods
Classifying international public goods 13
Institutional responses to the provision of public goods 13
International public goods governance and global citizenship 21
Multilateral framework for the provision of international public goods 22
Financing mechanisms for the provision of international public goods 27
Chapter 2 Financial stability as an international public good for development 39
Financial instability has high growth and distribution costs 40
Financial stability is an international public good 41
Resolving asymmetry internationally while preserving autonomy 42
nationally
Proposals for reform 43
Chapter 3 The international trade regime as a public good for development 55
The public dimension of the problem 56
Diagnosis of the institutional framework for regulation 62
The national framework for economic integration 74
Promotion and financing possibilities 78
Policy proposals 79
Chapter 4 Knowledge as a public good for development 83
Are knowledge and technology public goods? 83
Governments and the production and distribution of knowledge 85
The rationale for intellectual property rights 86
Knowledge across national boundaries 93
Successes and failures in technology transfer 97
Promotion possibilities 99
Policy implications 107
Chapter 5 Environment as a public good for development 109
Environment and development—converging towards sustainable 109
development
The environment as a public good 120
Montreal Protocol—the most successful international agreement 125
Kyoto Protocol: beyond 2012 127
Factors influencing the formation and operation of the multilateral 134
environmental regime
Policy issues 140
Boxes
Box 1 UN reform and the provision of public goods 3
Box 1.1 The Millennium Development Goals 6
Box 3.1 Core principles of the World Trade Organization 64
Box 5.1 The Asia-Pacific countries’ approach to sustainable development: 110
green growth
Box 5.2 The role of international organizations in the provision of 115
environmental public goods
Box 5.3 The EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) 133
Figures
Figure 1.1 Institutional cluster in economic integration 26
Figure 2.1 Evolution of reserves by region, 1996–2003 51
Tables
Table 1 Industrial development, market failures and responses 2
Table 1.1 The characteristics and typology of public goods 8
Table 1.2 Supply prognosis for international public goods and role of 11
supranational institutions
Table 1.3 Geographic scope of the public goods 13
Table 1.4 International public goods classification 14
Table 1.5 Some examples of institutional responses for the provision of 16
international public goods
Table 1.6 Some self-enforcement mechanisms for international public goods 20
provision
Table 1.7 Financing mechanisms for global public goods 27
Table 2.1 Comparative output loss for each country in a financial crisis, 1997– 40
2002
Table 2.2 Codes and standards 44
Table 3.1 Share of merchandise and service exports 58
Table 3.2 Trade rounds under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 62
Table 3.3 Tariff escalation in leather products 67
Table 5.1 Major international conferences and agreements on environmental 122
concerns
Table 5.2 Carbon dioxide emissions of countries with emissions higher than 1 129
percent of world emissions in 2002
Table 5.3 World carbon dioxide emissions by region, 2002 130
Table 5.4 Factors influencing the success of the environmental regime 136
Viewpoints
Viewpoint 1.1 Recent developments in aid financing of international public 17
goods
Viewpoint 1.2 Global public goods and global governance 28
S trong links between public goods provision and economic development make the
case for the provision of public goods at national, regional and international lev-
els. The provision of public goods is a key element of the quality of life and envi-
ronmental sustainability. Their undersupply may affect prospects for economic devel-
opment, threatening global economic stability, peace and prosperity.
Mechanisms for the effective delivery of public goods and services should there-
fore be central to any poverty eradication strategy. However, the role of public goods in
economic development has been neglected in the mainstream literature. Current views
of economic development (macroeconomic stability, market-oriented reforms, good
governance) need to be enriched and complemented by considerations of global public
goods to achieve sustained high-quality economic growth and to ensure that growth
translates effectively into poverty eradication. This is essential to achieve the Millen-
nium Development Goals.
Several categories of public goods identified in the public goods literature are
closely related to five of the Millennium Development Goals: the environment, health,
knowledge, security and governance (Kanbur, Sandler and Morrison 1999; Morrissey,
te Velde and Hewitt 2002). Three (environment, health and security) are associated
largely with benefits derived from reducing risks. Two (knowledge and governance) are
associated primarily with enhancing capacity. The environment, knowledge and govern-
ance public goods are most closely related to the work of the United Nations Industrial
Development Organization (UNIDO) while the other two are more ancillary. The pro-
vision of health public goods improves the health of the workforce, but it is the quality
of life, rather than of the workforce, that motivates the provision of health public goods.
Similarly, while security may benefit the economy and industry, that benefit does not
motivate the provision of security public goods. The provision of security public goods
is motivated by a fear that instability will either spread to other countries or create nega-
tive spillovers (refugees, blocked supply lines, reduced growth) for neighbouring and
other countries.
Various market failures can constrain industrial development (table 1) (Rodrik
2004, 2006; Hausmann and Rodrik 2006). Some government responses to market fail-
ures are providing public goods and addressing positive and negative externalities
through industrial policy. Capacity to efficiently deal with these market failures is related
to governance institutions for coordination or support of technology development. The
most extensive market failures relate to coordination failures, which tend to be most
severe in poor countries. National economic and industrial strategies are required to
identify complementarities and to identify and support the creation of linkages. This is
particularly important for developing countries striving to diversify from traditional to
non-traditional products and activities, for which markets are not yet formed. Institu-
Type
(sources of Examples of market Responses: poli- Relevant public
failure) failures cies and activities goods
In the international effort to address the undersupply of public goods facing de-
veloping countries and economies in transition, the multilateral institutions are working
largely in isolation. The international community is still learning how best to address
these challenges and to deal with their interdependencies. The diversity of institutional
arrangements needed to address the variety of global public goods underscores the im-
portance of effective collaboration across the multilateral system. Better coordinated
and more substantive and effective international programs are needed in this area, with
collaboration focusing on areas of comparative advantage and value added (see box 1
on United Nations reform initiative). With the diversity of institutions working in eco-
O
ne of the most striking trends at the beginning of this century is the clear drive
towards global integration. With the increasing importance of the international
exchange of goods, services and factors, and the seemingly limitless possibili-
ties offered by new communication technologies, the degree of interdependence of
countries and the influences beyond national borders are reaching new levels. National
problems have ramifications over ever larger areas, so that no place, however remote, is
immune to the risk of contagion. At the same time, governments are seeing their free-
dom to manoeuvre reduced, so that they are forced to consider the conditions imposed
on their decisions by the international framework. National spaces, previously frag-
mented, are being integrated on a global scale. There is an increased prevalence of in-
terdependencies and cross-border spillovers in the international arena.
The effects of this interdependence vary: positive in some cases (expansion of interna-
tional trade), negative in others (the risks of contagion in cases of financial crisis), but
often mixed. The greater the international mobility of people, the higher the risk of in-
fection from diseases previously thought to be foreign, but also the faster the spread of
new knowledge about medical treatments. The international integration of communica-
tion systems not only promotes the circulation of information around the world, but it
also increases the harmful impacts of computer viruses. The integration of capital mar-
kets improves the efficiency of international savings allocation, but it also increases the
risk of financial instability.
Globalization therefore involves very different types of externalities and interna-
tional interdependencies. From them emerges the specific domain of international pub-
lic goods, whose benefits spread beyond the providing country’s borders. Public goods
possess non-rival benefits and non-excludable benefits. Benefits are non-rival when
consumption by one user does not diminish the benefits still available to others. Once
the public good is provided, benefits are non-excludable if they are received by payers
and non-payers alike. Public bads can be discussed in an equivalent, although inverse
way: the corresponding public goods would be the promotion of activities that manage
to prevent, avoid, or mitigate the harmful effects of public bads. Public goods are very
diverse. Some—such as a justice system, multilateral organizations or an international
regulatory framework—are essential for organizing coexistence. Others—such as safety in
health matters or environmental protection—are minimum safety requirements for sus-
taining life. Finally, some—such as financial stability, commercial integration or knowl-
edge promotion—improve the possibilities for progress throughout the world. Together,
they form a collection of goods, services and regulatory frameworks that, along with the
private goods that people can acquire, condition the level of well-being of the world’s
population.
Because of the characteristics of public goods the market alone is often unable to en-
sure their efficient provision. Some form of collective action (planned effort by two or
more agents to act together for a particular result thought desirable for all) becomes
necessary to supply them, through coordination, cooperation or coercion. Within each
country, that response is directed through the available institutional framework, with the
nation state at the centre. At the supranational level, there is no institution similar to the
state, so the response has to be initiated through various forms of voluntary coordina-
tion and cooperation, generally among countries.
The recourse to international cooperation is driven by different factors. Activi-
ties once the exclusive responsibility of states, such as security, financial stability, envi-
ronmental management or public health, can no longer be efficiently tackled except
through international cooperation. And such coordination is obligatory for new goods
or activities that, because of their effects or their impact sphere, have had an interna-
tional status from the start, such as management of geostationary orbits, control of cli-
mate change or development of the Internet.
As interdependencies grow among countries in fields where it is crucial to or-
ganize coexistence, promote security and stimulate progress, managing these interde-
pendencies requires defining the framework of incentives in which agents operate and
appropriate institutions engage in effective collective cooperation. The future level of
world development and social well-being depends, to a large extent, on the ability to
supply international public goods.
This becomes all the more important at a time when the international commu-
nity seeks to accomplish the Millennium Development Goals, a set of shared goals for
development (box 1.1). Although these goals are not necessarily public goods by nature,
attaining them requires investments in international public goods. Finding a new vaccine
against malaria or developing an accessible treatment for AIDS, preserving the peace or
creating easier access to knowledge, promoting financial stability or establishing a more
open and fair trading system could have a greater impact on poverty than could interna-
tional aid.
Providing international public goods takes more than financial resources. It also
takes the proper regulatory framework and institutional responses to ensure their sup-
ply. And that is where the greatest shortcomings remain. The world has made enor-
mous strides in communications and interdependence between countries, yet we have
not developed the policies or institutions needed to manage that process. This asymme-
Source: Adapted from Sandler 2002: 86; Kaul, Grunberg and Stern 1999: 5.
The way the supply of public goods is created by the individual efforts of different
community members is known as public goods aggregation technologies (Hirshleifer
1983; Cornes and Sandler 1984; 1996; Kanbur, Sandler and Morrison 1999; Kanbur
2001; Sandler 1997; 1998). An aggregation technology classification scheme of public
goods gives an important perspective on contributors’ incentives and so helps to explain
how individual contributions determine the overall supply of a public good (Sandler
2005: 60–61; 81). Although a more complete aggregation technology taxonomy of pub-
lic goods is possible, the following categories are commonly considered:
• Simple summation goods. In this, the most common option, the contributions of
each agent determine by simple addition the aggregate levels of provision of the
public good. For example, the level of damage to the atmosphere caused by a con-
taminating gas (such as carbon dioxide) is calculated by adding each country’s indi-
vidual emissions.
In this case, the level of public good provision is indifferent to any change in in-
come distribution among contributors (Bergstrom, Blume and Varian 1986; Cornes
and Sandler 1984). So, when voluntary contributions are positive, the neutrality
theorem applies: the amount supplied by one agent is a perfect substitute for the
amount provided by another (Kanbur, Sandler and Morrison 1999: 65). When in-
Table 1.2. Supply prognosis for international public goods and role of supranational institutions
Undersupply
Overuse/undersuppy
Efficient supply
Role for supranational institutions and
Simple summa- treaties Role for supranational insti-
Transnational parks
tion tutions and treaties
Deterring terrorism
Curbing ozone shield depleters Continental fishing
The international range of a public good may differ depending on the geographic scope
of its spillover effects (table 1.3). With cross-border public goods, effects spill over to
surrounding countries (management of a shared hydrographic basin, upkeep of a
To sum up, in addition to their aggregation technology, public goods may be classified
according to three complementary criteria: the good’s public (pure or impure) nature,
the geographic coverage area of its benefits (cross-border, regional and global) and the
generational dimension of its effects (inter- and intra-generational). This classification is
useful in considering the most suitable institutional framework for managing each good
(table 1.4).
Because of the supranational nature of the externalities of all these types of
goods, they need an international institutional and regulatory framework to manage
them. But several factors encourage opportunistic behaviour in the international arena,
including limited world regulation in the public domain, lack of executive supranational
power and the weakening of collective controls caused by the large size of the affected
community (Olson 1965).
Public goods and externalities are instances that call for a coordinated social response
and collective action to provide a good. However, the presence of mutually beneficial
goals is not enough to ensure the voluntary participation of agents involved, especially if
there is no possibility of excluding access to collective benefits. In these cases, there
Intragenerational
Waterways
Forest fire prevention Electric grid Medical aid
Rivers
Cross-border Groundwater pollution Information networks Technical assistance
Highways
cleanup Peacekeeping Internet connectivity
Local parks
Electromagnetic
spectrum allocation Air corridors
Ocean pollution cleanup Foreign aid
Satellite transmis- Internet
Global Monitoring station Disaster relief
sions Shipping lanes
World Court Drug interdiction
Postal service Financial stability
Disease control
Intergenerational
Reduction in emis-
Lead emissions reduc-
sions of volatile or- Transnational parks Cultural norms
Regional tion
ganic compounds Barrier reefs Bioprospecting
Forest conservation
Agricultural research
Table 1.5. Some examples of institutional responses for the provision of international
public goods
Activity Jurisdictional coverage
coverage
Regional Global
World Bank
Wide
Regional Development Banks United Nations Development Pro-
(diversified)
gramme
While this classification gives some notion of the diversity of institutional re-
sponses according to the sectoral scope required for supplying a public good and on the
jurisdictional level, it would be a mistake to have just one institution responsible for the
provision of each international public good. Managing international public goods is
complex enough to involve multiple institutions at different levels. Some may supply
core activities aimed at the production of public goods and others may focus on com-
plementary activities that help to generate conditions for the good’s provision and con-
sumption (see viewpoint 1.1 on aid financing of international public goods); some may
supply final public goods, and others intermediate public goods, needed in order to
supply final public goods. Therefore, clusters of institutions should be considered for
each international public good, institutions with different missions and tasks that to-
gether provide the institutional infrastructure necessary for supplying the good. To
avoid overlap it would be crucial to define the specific task specialization in the cluster
core, assigning coordination and leadership functions to institutions according to the
tasks that the supply of the good requires.
Should aid finance international public goods? Who should provide international public
The current consensus is that aid should go to goods?
financing activities to achieve the Millennium De-
Three arguments make the case for aid financ-
velopment Goals, so any aid to international pub-
ing of international public goods. First, the private
lic goods would need to be justified by addressing
sector will not provide a sufficient amount of public
the Millennium Development Goals. However,
goods, because it will consider private rather than
there are other resources for financing interna-
social benefits. This calls for some public sector
tional public goods (taxes, private resources, non-
engagement. Second, individual countries have
aid public resources and combinations of these),
insufficient incentives to make an optimal contri-
so an argument needs to be made for the role of
bution to international public goods, given that not
aid, not only that the provision of public goods
all benefits accrue nationally. This calls for some
helps countries achieve the Millennium Develop-
form of cooperation among countries. Third, poor
ment Goals.
countries lack the resources to make a full contri-
Providing public goods to achieve the Millen- bution to the provision of international public
nium Development Goals goods. This justifies aid finance of international
The categories or sectors identified in the public public goods in poor countries.
goods literature relate quite well to the types of However, the argument is more complex in
Millennium Development Goals, at least in name. practice. Aid financing does not necessarily imply
Typically, five public goods sectors are consid- actual provision by donor agencies. Provision of
ered—the environment, health, knowledge, secu- international public goods can involve coordina-
rity and governance. Three of these sectors— tion with other actors, such as the private sector.
environment, health and security—are largely And even if a pure public good could be identified,
associated with benefits derived from reducing it is almost impossible to verify exactly how much
risks. The other two—knowledge and govern- current financing contributes to the provision of
ance—are associated primarily with enhancing the good and by how much the good is underpro-
capacity. vided. Certain financing mechanisms (Global En-
There are at least three related ways to think vironmental Facility) try to finance provision up to
about aid financing for the international public the point at which the private sector would stop.
goods needed to achieve the Millennium Devel- But in practice this point is difficult to identify,
• Assessing the aid financing needs to meet The share of aid allocated to international public
the Millennium Development Goals, many of goods has risen since the early 1980s (Raffer
which correspond to some degree with the 1998; World Bank 2001a; te Velde, Morrisey and
provision of international public goods. Hewitt 2002). Te Velde, Morrisey and Hewitt
(2002) estimate the share of aid allocated to inter-
• Analyzing the costs and benefits of over-
national and national public goods since the
coming major challenges in development,
1980s, in total and by individual donors, and show
some of which might be overcome though
that by the late 1990s donors allocated at least
the provision of international public goods.
10% of aid to international public goods and at
least 30% to national public goods. They also
show that using the Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development’s Creditor Report-
in developing countries should not come from administrative systems in aid transmission and
further increasing the share of aid allocated to this greater coordination between donors and recipi-
purpose. So, either the value of aid should be ents (Rogerson, Hewitt and Waldenburg 2004).
increased or sources of non-aid funding will be Measurable and monitorable targets have been
required to increase support for international pub- agreed. Once set in motion, the aim is to secure
lic goods. In encouraging donors to increase the these changes in donor behaviour towards a more
amount of aid allocated to public goods, especially balanced international aid delivery system. Much
international public goods, attention should be international reform may still be needed. Many
given to the form of aid (grants or loans) and co- issues of international accountability remain, and
operation between donors. donors still have to loosen the bonds of aid policy
conditionality (Rogerson 2005), but the donor-
Mascarenhas and Sandler (2005) provide an
recipient relationship system does seem to be on
empirical analysis of the use of aid to support the
track for qualifying as an international public good.
provision of public goods, although their focus is
on the balance between grants and loans. They However, the proliferation of special funds (as
argue that grants are the most appropriate form of for HIV/AIDS), unless genuinely additional, may
aid for financing spillovers associated with interna- divert resources from other genuine development
tional or regional public goods and that therefore priorities, hampering the delivery of real interna-
multilateral agencies and regional development tional public goods. There is also the issue of
banks should give a higher proportion of aid in the substitution, with donors sometimes claiming in-
form of grants. ternational public good status in their development
spending for activities that do not qualify.
Mascarenhas and Sandler (2005) considered
the broader question of whether the total amount Policy issues
of aid spent by a donor reflects what other donors There are some interesting policy implications
are doing. In general the results suggest that a for international organizations such as the United
donor’s decisions on how much aid to allocate, Nations Industrial Organization (UNIDO).
overall or to particular regions, are independent of
• What is the rationale for providing the good
the actions of other donors. They suggest that
(that is, what is the market failure, what is
donors are not making cooperative decisions on
For UNIDO, it seems clear that knowledge tained internationally but transferred to
fecting industrial development and environ- among donors or organizations but concen-
ment (effects of industrialization) are key in- trated to reach critical mass and economies
ternational public goods. The rationale for of scale and scope. For instance, UNIDO
UNIDO in providing such goods seems will have an advantage in building knowl-
tion strategies, and UNIDO can aspire to be • How does provision of an international pub-
the world’s main body of knowledge on in- lic good sit with the Paris declaration aims of
dustrialization. harmonisation, alignment and ownership?
Another opportunity lies in recent aid for To take the aid for trade example, financing
trade initiatives, which can be used to im- trade rules will depend on how aid for trade
plement international trade rules and stan- fits with the strategies of receiving countries.
dards for production processes, contributing Financing trade rules must be coordinated
to international public goods related to gov- with other players, because coordination re-
ernance. The provision of trade-related pub- lates to the debate on aid effectiveness.
lic goods tends to have a favourable cost- Alignment with developing countries’ priorities
benefit ratio. needs to be safeguarded. To support economic
Addressing climate change may require a development, technical assistance activities in a
different approach towards supporting the country should build on international knowledge
development and diffusion of new energy- and be aligned with other activities. This means
and carbon dioxide-saving technologies. linking with national working groups on trade or
UNIDO is already doing similar things under private sector development. Funding for knowl-
the implementation of the Montreal Protocol, edge-related public goods may occur at the na-
so it could extend these efforts to try to un- tional level, though executing agencies could be
derpin the implementation of the Kyoto Pro- international players building knowledge interna-
tocol in a way that is more cost-effective. tionally and helping coordinate. The existence of
• What type of international organization demand for knowledge-related public goods at the
should provide the international public country level and continued interaction between
good? If the good is aid, should it be bilat- global institutions and beneficiaries of knowledge
eral or multilateral donor agencies? transfer both seem key to reducing the gap be-
tween global initiatives on knowledge activities
Knowledge of industrialization or implemen-
and the harmonization, alignment and ownership
tation of international rules and energy-
agenda.
efficient technologies is necessary for eco-
nomic development and is associated with Source: Drawn from a background paper by te
Velde, Hewitt and Morrissey (2006).
Table 1.6. Some self-enforcement mechanisms for international public goods provision
Aggregation
Pure public goods Impure public goods Club goods
technology
The efficiency associated with a club mechanism can be obtained for most ag-
gregation technologies, with the exception of weakest link. For that, there are potential
externalities that may not be fully addressed by the individual suppliers. In the case of
air traffic control, one country’s less reliable control infrastructure can disrupt the flow
of the entire network when the component system malfunctions. Uniform tolls to air
carriers for using the network are unlikely to adjust for differential reliabilities. More-
over, the suppliers may have little incentive to bring their component system up to the
standard of the rest of the network unless pressured to do so or subsidized by other
club good providers. The Quality of Service Fund of the Universal Postal Union is a
mechanism of this kind; it aims to improve the quality of postal services in developing
countries through the financial support of developed countries.
For impure public goods the market leads to the good’s undersupply (or over-
use). Correcting this situation depends on the type of aggregation technology consid-
Globalization has increased the sphere of international public goods. This process en-
tails a double challenge: one political and one economic. The political challenge refers
to the fact that globalization is displacing basic principles on which democracy is
founded, such as symmetry and coherence among decision-makers and the people af-
fected by those decisions (Held 1997). Both citizens’ control over their representatives,
through electoral processes, and public and institutional accountability rest on these
principles. These basic principles have been undermined through a set of decisions af-
fecting citizenship that were taken in contexts or by institutions beyond the scrutiny or
control of those who are finally affected by them.
Today, national communities are no longer the only source of decisions that in-
fluence their members’ lives, nor are the effects of government decisions limited to the
strict domain of the citizens themselves (Offe 1985). Some international institutions—
such as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF)—make decisions
with limited effective participation from the citizens affected, and national decisions in-
creasingly have impacts beyond their borders. There is a growing mismatch between the
scope of the problems, which is increasingly supranational, and the scope of political
processes, which is still largely national. The greater that mismatch, the greater the diffi-
culties that states will encounter in erecting a predictable environment for their citizens
The range of problems facing the world’s governing powers urges the increasing promi-
nence of multilateral responses, such as consultative and international action forums.
The current system is inadequate to the task. As Sutherland (1998a) put it in his Per
Jacobsson Lecture at the annual meetings of the IMF and the World Bank, “globalisa-
tion is imposing new pressures on key international institutions. It is also exposing
weaknesses in the current system of global leadership.”
This judgement seems validated by repeated efforts over the years to renew the
United Nations system, with numerous proposals for reform. Yet, as Smouts (1999: 29)
Dealing with the jurisdictional gap requires a more appropriate institutional definition
for the management of the new interdependencies that globalization entails. The roles,
missions and coordination among multilateral institutions may all need to be revised.
Doing so exposes one of the main problems of the multilateral system: its lim-
ited internal coherence. The largely disordered process by which the United Nations
institutions were created did not favour an ordered system. There is considerable over-
lap in the activities of institutions, without any clear specialization. For example, the
fields of rights and reproductive health are treated by the United Nations Children’s
Fund (UNICEF), United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), United Nations
Population Fund (UNFPA) and the World Health Organization (WHO). UNICEF,
the UNDP, the International Labour Organization (ILO) and the United Nations Edu-
cational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) are all involved in education
and human resources training. The Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO), ILO,
World Food Programme (WFP), United Nations Industrial Development Organization
(UNIDO), and the World Bank all focus on promoting employment and supporting
small enterprises. The UNDP, World Bank and UNIDO all promote private sector
development. The FAO, United Nations Refugee Agency (UNHCR), United Nations
Relief and Works Agency (UNRWA) and WFP, among others, carry out emergency
and humanitarian aid tasks. Overlapping also occurs among financial and non-financial
institutions, such as the UNDP and the World Bank, in technical assistance tasks. How
can the system be better structured to achieve synergies and avoid overlaps?
While such competition among institutions might be thought to encourage mu-
tually positive stimulation, in most cases this overlap of activities is due to a lack of co-
ordination. This situation not only impedes the institutions’ effectiveness, but also seri-
ously damages their international image.
Establishing order is not a simple matter of assigning the tasks of the supply of
each international public good to just one multilateral institution, however. That would
be both naive, considering the degree of institutional overlap, and clearly inefficient,
because of the diverse nature and different functional level at which international public
goods must be supplied. Promoting an international public good requires both estab-
lishing an incentives framework at an international level (core activities) and implement-
ing policies aimed at strengthening countries’ ability to produce complementary na-
tional public goods and to benefit from international public goods (complementary
activities). Each of these tasks could be the responsibility of a different institution, oper-
ating at a different level, with a different scope. With this interpretation, the problem is
not to find the responsible institution (“anchor institution”, to use the term of the Inter-
national Task Force on Global Public Goods), but to define each institution’s speciali-
zation inside a cluster of institutions within the system of international public goods
supply.
Proposals for an issue-driven and network approach are based on this under-
standing. It is based on clustering various institutions to work jointly on adding value in
providing a public good according to their respective comparative advantages and fields
of excellence (UNIDO 2005; Magariños 2005: 36; Rischard 2002). Coordination func-
tions would be given according to each specific task, taking into account each institu-
tion’s specialization, rather than through one bureaucratic command centre. An exam-
United Nations
Development G
World Bank Core activities Programme
L
O
Domain of the global
Regime on trade and capi- B
tal relations United Nations
A
United Nations Indus- Conference on L
trial Development Trade and Devel-
Organization/World opment
Trade Organization Domain of the
networks
R
Regional
E
institutions of G
Regional
development banks Domain of the local
integration I
National regime O
N
Complementary activities A
L
N
A
T
I
National O
government N
A
L
Source: Adapted from Sagasti and Bezanson (2001)
There are four basic mechanisms for supporting public goods supply: correcting the
effect of externalities by creating a quasi-market or applying taxes or fees; turning to
voluntary private resources from individuals, businesses or foundations; claiming public
resources from national contributions or international funds and combining any of
these three mechanisms (table 1.7). The relevance of each mechanism depends on in-
centives and government structures that are internationally established for the provision
of these goods (Sagasti and Bezanson 2001).
National sources
Relying on public sources
International sources
Forming partnerships Combination of various different sources
Why does sound economic theory with impor- cal questions about the appropriate manner in
tant policy implications such as that advanced in which policy is made, decisions are taken and
international discussions on global public goods implemented and resources are distributed. This
so often prove difficult to implement in practice? is an issue for the theorist as much as the practi-
Frequently, such economic theory demonstrates tioner. Indeed, a problem with the much of the
little or no appreciation of the political constraints contemporary analysis of the demand for govern-
likely to work against policy implementation. While ance, beyond the confines of the state, is that it is
economic assumptions about what constitutes often posed as a technical and managerial prob-
good governance in the twenty-first century are lem. This approach removes any notion of politics
becoming increasingly sophisticated technically, or ethics from problem solving.
especially for the provision of public goods, they But actors in this process are not ethically neu-
often remain oblivious to the nature of the politics tral and dispassionate. They are players with po-
that can derail them, no matter how theoretically litical agendas. This is so whether the relevant
sound and policy relevant. international institutions are included (United Na-
In short: economics, even the emerging subdis- tions and alliances in the security domain, the
cipline of political economy, is not comfortable International Monetary Fund in the international
with politics. Political economy, as what might be financial arena; the World Trade Organization and
called a theory of choice under constraint using regional and bilateral institutional arrangements in
game theoretic models, may offer important in- the trade arena; the World Bank in the context of
sights into issues such as scarcity and the role of development) or those ever more visible non-state
institutions in the policy process. It is less com- actors (such as multinational corporations and
fortable with questions of ideological contest, non-governmental organizations) and various
power, political struggle, representation, legiti- advocacy coalitions and global public policy net-
macy and accountability, all of which can make or works such as the Davos Forum or the emerging
break the implementation and acceptance of a counter-voices at the Global and European Social
given policy. Forums or what is generically thought of as the
That discomfort sets the stage for discussing alternative globalization movement.
global governance, an overused and underspeci- The financial crises of the late 1990s generated
fied concept. The demand for research on global precisely the sorts of distrust and animosity that
governance has followed the recognition that sov- detract from the possibilities for mutually benefi-
ereignty is more a relational and relative question cial cooperation at the international level. The
of responsibility. The result is a dramatic change rhetoric in industrialized countries about burden
in the role of international law. sharing—the implication being that developing
countries did not share the burdens of global pub-
More than a technical and managerial problem
lic goods—was more than countered by percep-
The demand for global and regional governance tions in developing countries that the burdens of
has become increasingly complex. And the role of moral hazard, social dislocation and the impact of
multilevel governance structures in key policy unfettered competition had been unloaded on
areas has grown dramatically. precisely the economies and societies that were
Yet in some key areas of the global cooperative least equipped to deal with them. In an era of
agenda, in both the economic and the security deregulated capital movement and the processes
domain, collective governance capacity appears of financial change that brought hedge funds,
to be deteriorating and resistance to its enhance- pegged exchange rates and precipitous currency
ment to be growing. For an increasing number of collapses, the notion of global burden sharing
actors global governance questions resist the adopted by the developed world was thought by
technocratic fix and pose major political and ethi-
Since the private benefits of public goods are lower than the social benefits, markets
lead to underproduction compared with the socially desirable level. This difficulty can
be overcome by defining property rights more precisely, to strengthen the market
mechanism, or by levying a tax or fee, to internalize social costs. Both methods internal-
ize externalities by making marginal social benefits coincide with marginal social costs.
Informational difficulties have to be overcome, however, since those who bear the ex-
ternal costs tend to exaggerate the harm while those who gain the external benefits tend
to underplay them.
Markets for public goods do not arise spontaneously—the conditions for appro-
priating the good are absent, and agents fail to express preferences that would lead to
the setting of prices. For a market to exist, those factors need to be created through in-
stitutional change. Property rights have to be defined (through setting quotas, for exam-
ple), an information system has to be created and a transparent regulatory framework
has to be established to ensure exchange operations. With an association established
between preferences and costs, agents can exchange the good’s access rights for pay-
ment. However, there are costs involved in creating a market, associated with establish-
ing the legal framework and the enforcement mechanisms, and these costs are often
borne by public institutions (Sagasti and Bezanson 2001: 41).
Under the Kyoto Protocol, for example, this part of the market is being created
to control greenhouse gas emissions. Once the maximum quantity of emissions consid-
ered internationally acceptable is set, that total will be allocated to countries through
quotas. Later, countries could exchange quotas with each other, so that the most envi-
ronmentally efficient countries could sell a part of their emissions rights to countries
that need to exceed their emissions quotas. Internationally established emissions limits
can be met, while countries that make an extra effort to reduce emissions will be re-
warded by countries that are unable or unwilling to reduce their emissions to the agreed
level. Such mechanisms could be used to manage scarce basic resources (common
goods) such as water or fishing, where it is necessary to fix a maximum consumption
level in order to share the good among different agents.
The main drawback is the difficulty of achieving agreement on overall limits and
quotas among participants. Reaching agreement is easier at the national level, where the
state’s legal authority can be brought to bear.
Another way to internalize externalities is to establish a tax, fee or contribution
related to the consumption of the public good. A common procedure for national pub-
lic goods, it too presents greater difficulties at the international level since there is no
equivalent fiscal authority. This procedure seems especially suitable for club goods,
such as irrigation systems, access to communication networks or the use of certain
shared resources (satellites, for example), or for common goods, with their discrepancy
between the immediate interest of each agent (to pursue the highest exploitation) and
the collective or intergenerational interest (to maintain the resource’s sustainability).
Payment of a tax or fee is expected to bring private behaviour closer to the conduct
demanded by collective interests, avoiding congestion, instability or overexploitation of
the resource.
Proposals to use taxes to manage specific international problems have a long
history in development thinking. The Brandt Commission (1980) suggested drawing aid
International public goods can also be supplied through voluntary contributions from
individuals, independent foundations, non-profit institutions, businesses and
individuals.
The Rockefeller and Ford Foundations have promoted research and technolo-
gies related to the green revolution that were later taken up by international institutions
and the governments of developing countries. The Rockefeller Foundation has also
supported vaccine development for “forgotten diseases” through the Great Neglected
Diseases of Mankind Programme and more recently, along with the Ford Foundation,
has supported AIDS research. The MacArthur Foundation supports biodiversity pro-
grammes, while the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation promotes childhood health pro-
grammes and AIDS research.
Non-profit institutions also make a substantial contribution to international pub-
lic goods. Non-governmental networks, such as Oxfam, CARE, Save the Children,
Greenpeace, Human Rights Watch and Amnesty International contribute to interna-
tional public goods supply partly through direct interventions and through their pres-
sure on governments to make a more effective commitment to social needs. Even with
limited resources NGOs contribute by mobilizing public opinion, demanding that gov-
ernments become more aware of international public goods management, and by
agenda setting. Academic and research institutions also contribute to the supply of some
international public goods, especially in research, the spread of information and statisti-
cal data and the consolidation of cognitive communities.
Businesses have also contributed to the supply of international public goods by
sponsoring funds and programmes related to public goods or by making decisions and
assuming costs. Examples are Astra-Zeneca’s efforts in developing a drug to cure tuber-
culosis and Novartis’s work developing products against Dengue fever. Shell and British
Petroleum have adopted agreements to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. That these
actions are motivated by profits or the desire to improve corporate image does not de-
ter from the beneficial results they have for the international community.
Individual contributions also play a part, whether channelled through NGOs or
the United Nations system or contributed directly to specific causes. Examples are Ted
Turner’s donation to the United Nations, Live Aid concerts to collect funds for AIDS
in Africa and Elton John’s donation of royalties on his CD tribute to Princess Diana to
finance the campaign against anti-personnel mines.
These are donations arising from personal initiative. There are also proposals to
institutionalize the collection of private contributions for certain international public
goods. An initiative with the longest tradition may be the creation of a United Nations
lottery, initially proposed in the UN General Assembly in 1970 and recently revived by
A third option for the provision of international public goods is to turn to public funds,
either through direct contributions by developed countries or through the budgets of
international organizations.
Development assistance. Development aid is the dominant source of international pub-
lic resources from developed countries. Developed country contributions include bilat-
eral programmes and contributions to international institutions, including those with a
clear mission to tackle common problems on a global scale.
While a great part of official development assistance is already used to finance
activities related to the supply of international public goods, international aid and global
public goods supply are not identical. Kaul and Le Goulven (2003) identify several dif-
ferences between the two. A key difference is that aid refers to international equity
problems and its purpose is to eradicate poverty; therefore, its actions are directed at
distribution. By contrast, public goods supply refers to the correction of market failure,
seeking to arrive at better efficiency levels by focusing on economic allocation. Aid
works mainly through unilateral transfers of resources (from donor to recipient coun-
tries). Public goods management appeals to a wider variety of political means (including
changes in legal frameworks to promote cooperative action) and is directed mainly at
goods rather than countries. And while aid is directed to developing countries, all coun-
tries potentially benefit from public goods supply.
New objectives are emerging for international cooperation related to common
problems, but the traditional goals of aid—poverty eradication and meeting basic
needs—still have not been achieved. For that reason, even with closely related policies
for aid and public goods supply, it might be wise to maintain a certain autonomy of
policies and equally diverse sources of finance (see viewpoint 1.1 on aid finance of in-
ternational public goods).
Other international activity by government agencies. Developed countries also contrib-
ute to the provision of public goods through other kinds of activities that are not strictly
valued as official development assistance, such as those generated by the international
activity of various government departments. Examples are the financing of international
cooperation in environmental management, international security, financial coordina-
tion, transport regulation, postal traffic and management matters. The scope given to
activity that is part of international cooperation in fields of shared interest is quite wide.
Developing country financing. In developing countries, most resources for the provi-
sion of public goods come from the national budget, through allocations to core activi-
ties of a good’s supply or to complementary activities to generate conditions for the
good’s provision and consumption (see viewpoint 1.3 on Sub-Saharan Africa). Public
resources are extremely limited in developing countries, and financing for global public
goods faces competition from demands for improving national public goods’ provi-
sion—security, health, education and infrastructure. India has made progress in the de-
velopment of a vaccine against hepatitis B, Viet Nam in the vaccine against meningitis B
and Brazil and India in the production of generic drugs for AIDS treatment. There is
no shortage of such innovative efforts as the Millennium Network for Tuberculoses
R&D organized by the Brazilian government or the Coalition for R&D in TB Endemic
FORMING PARTNERSHIPS
These mechanisms are not mutually exclusive. They can be combined to enable diverse
agents to work together. This occurs in programmes to develop drugs and vaccines for
specific diseases, such as the International AIDS Vaccine Initiative, the International
Microbicides Partnership in developing vaccines against Dengue fever, the Pediatric
Dengue Vaccine Initiative, the Global Alliance for TB Drug Development, the Medi-
cines for Malaria Venture and the Onchocerciasis Control Partnership.
The Global Fund to Fight AIDS, Tuberculosis and Malaria, created in 2002, includes
international institutions (the World Bank, UNDP and WHO) and bilateral donors,
and private contributions are possible as well. The fund was created as a financial in-
strument to collect, manage and finance actions to fight the three diseases worldwide.
The many weaknesses of African economies production of international public goods, but there
and political systems shape Africa’s access to is still a wide shortfall in the provision of such
international public goods and the capacity to transfers. One reason may be that the harm po-
participate in the provision of such goods, in sev- tentially inflicted on the world system by the
eral ways. weakest link nature of Sub-Saharan Africa is
somewhat mitigated by its de-linking from the rest
Implications of Sub-Saharan Africa’s delinking of the world.
from the global economy This de-linking implies that Sub-Saharan Africa
has little responsibility for the global crises asso-
First, an international public good may be avail-
ciated with the underprovision of international
able in the world economy without being available
public goods. This is true for best shot public
everywhere. This may be because complemen-
goods and for public goods whose aggregation
tary activities are needed to consume the public
technology is linear, in that the contribution of
good in addition to the core activities required to
each actor depends on its economic size. Interna-
produce it (World Bank 2001b). A classic example
tional public goods such as macroeconomic and
is scientific and technical knowledge (see chapter
financial stability and the protection of global envi-
5). Even though in most cases the complementary
ronmental resources are of this sort. Since their
activities are private rather than public goods, an
production does not depend much on African
optimal scheme of provision of international public
countries’ contributions, there is a risk that the
goods must provide for the measures necessary
specific needs of Sub-Saharan Africa will be ig-
for the international public good to be consumed
nored in the global deals struck to produce such
globally as well as produced.
international public goods.
This issue is particularly relevant for Sub-
Thus Africa faces problems based on an ab-
Saharan Africa, where countries often lack the
sence of complementary activities, public goods
capacity to take advantage of international public
with weakest link aggregation technologies and
goods. An example is the international trade re-
the near exclusion of its needs from discussions
gime (see chapter 3). Even if the World Trade
of international public goods production. Lack of
Organization (WTO) were able to fully enforce
complementary activities affects three areas in
free trade rules, poor countries in Sub-Saharan
particular: the international trade regime, global
Africa and elsewhere would not necessarily be
financial stability and knowledge diffusion and
able to increase their participation in the world
adaptation. The weakest link public goods aggre-
trading system. Lack of capacity to consume in-
gation technology is particularly relevant to health
ternational public goods is a major contributor to
and peace and security, areas in which Africa has
the “de-linking” of Africa from the rest of the
been dramatically absent from progresses
world—and from its inability to participate fully in
achieved or attempted worldwide. The near exclu-
globalization (Collier 1995).
sion of African needs in international public goods
Second, for many international public goods discussions concerns principally the conservation
Sub-Saharan Africa is the weakest link in the of global environmental resources.
world economic system. In case of weakest link
Much of the recent international debate on the
aggregation technologies, improving the capacity
Millennium Development Goals has focused on
of African countries to participate effectively in the
the objective of worldwide poverty eradication as
production of such international public goods is
an international public good. While there have
critical. Examples are global health and control of
been some opposing arguments, there are at
communicable diseases.
least two reasons to consider poverty eradication
Economic theory calls for in-kind transfers to the as an international public good: first, growing
weakest agents, to help them contribute to the numbers of people around the world view the
cess for Sub-Saharan African economies, few Although the weakest link aggregation technol-
countries have been able to benefit. Certainly, ogy appears to apply as well to peace and secu-
there is a need for fairer trade rules, especially in rity, its relevance there is less straightforward.
agriculture, but the international trading system African security crises have so far been limited to
alone cannot be blamed for Africa’s trade failures. the continent. This does not mean that security
There is now ample recognition that African coun- crises in Sub-Saharan Africa are not serious. Con-
tries need to invest in trade capacity building if flicts in the region are responsible for half of all
they want to participate fully in international trade. global battle deaths, and these conflicts have set
Both African governments and donors have re- back development efforts in many countries. Re-
sponsibilities in this area. solving conflicts is largely the responsibility of
In the financial arena, the de-linking of Sub- Africans, but the international community can
Saharan Africa has tended to protect it from the assist, through rules and regulations that contrib-
turbulences of global financial markets. But Africa ute to improved governance and, in some cases,
has not been immune to external shocks. The through military intervention.
extreme volatility of terms of trade has inflicted Finally, the de-linking of Sub-Saharan Africa
heavy damage on African economies, and the from the world economy means that it has virtually
international community could do more to cushion no negotiating power in preventing global envi-
these shocks. Avoiding procyclical aid flows would ronmental damages that create special harm to
be a small, painless step in the right direction for the region, such as climate change and depletion
donors. of natural resources. Such damages are costly for
In the area of knowledge, the de-linking of Sub- the world system as a whole, but are particularly
Saharan Africa is harmful. The core issue here is harmful for Sub-Saharan Africa.
base for African development in some domains, doubling official development assistance, how-
particularly in agricultural research, but corre- ever. It also requires dealing with several other
sponding efforts are needed on the African side to international public goods–related issues, such as
make use of such research investments. vulnerability to shocks, food insecurity, illnesses,
conflicts and environmental damages. Therefore,
Concerning health, international efforts to de-
considerations of the more traditional international
velop vaccines and find cures for diseases that
public goods are also considerations of the over-
are concentrated in Sub-Saharan Africa, such as
arching objective of poverty reduction. The in-
HIV/AIDS and malaria, have been insufficient,
come dimension of poverty certainly plays an
though work is intensifying. Again, international
important role—and improving the ability of Sub-
Feasibility is related to debates on the objec- incentives is more complex. At the microeconomic
tives of official development assistance. On bilat- level, aid may trigger rent-seeking behaviour.
eral aid, the empirical evidence suggests that the Progresses cannot be achieved without improve-
self-interest of donors is a major motive for their ments in governance. At the more macroeco-
assistance. In particular, aid allocation is strongly nomic level, free-riding by recipient countries
influenced by trade linkages with aid recipients, so could happen if poverty alleviation were consid-
that there is a significant negative aid bias against ered purely as an international public good. This
Sub-Saharan Africa. A clear debate on the inter- can be avoided only if it is clear ex ante that do-
national aid architecture would be necessary if nors and recipients have the same objectives. The
more aid is to be allocated on the basis of the Millennium Development Goals are an answer to
global objective of poverty eradication rather than this issue, but it remains to be seen whether all
the particular objectives of donor countries. governments adhere to these objectives. Again,
this is principally a matter of good governance.
The desirability of more assistance to Africa de-
pends on the absorptive capacity of Sub-Saharan Source: Drawn from a background paper by Ber-
Use of public budgets to fund the supply of international public goods, while seemingly
the simplest option, is clearly limited. The difficulties of increasing official development
assistance, despite repeated international commitments to do so, clearly illustrate this
point. That is what motivates the search for new sources of funding for the provision of
international public goods. At the request of the Department of Economic and Social
Affairs of the United Nations Secretariat, the United Nations University–World Insti-
tute for Development Economics Research convened an international commission to
study new sources of development finance (Atkinson 2005). The commission did not
examine all possible financing sources and excluded several proposals for global taxes.
But several well known proposals were explored, including global environmental taxes,
the Tobin tax, special drawing rights for development, the International Finance Facil-
ity, private donations, global lottery and global premium bond and remittances by emi-
grants. The study highlighted four conclusions:
• Not one proposal for global funding is free of criticism. Some new sources of fund-
ing could crowd out existing mechanisms, and so their introduction should be stud-
ied carefully.
• Only two of the mechanisms considered (carbon tax and Tobin tax) would provide
sufficient resources to be considered relevant for funding international public
goods, although other global funding proposals could make substantial contribu-
tions, such as the International Finance Facility, which would use securitization to
secure funding for development, or the establishment of a global lottery or a global
premium bond to encourage private contributions.
• The partial and imperfect nature of all of the mechanisms suggests the need to
maximize the advantages of their implementation. This becomes easier the fewer
the number of actors required for their implementation (which works against global
taxation proposals).
• The advantages of a proposal increases when it promotes an allocation correction
and penalizes the production of a public bad in addition to raising funds—a “double
dividend”.
But even though some of the proposals establish a double dividend, none is free
of costs. This means that besides their fundraising capacity, their economic implica-
tions—and the distortions they generate—must also be considered.
T
he financial storms that hit international markets during the 1990s made it clear
that regulatory and institutional frameworks were inadequate to promote finan-
cial stability or to respond to crises and their effects at an international level. A
well-known study (Dobson and Hufbauer 2001) estimates that since 1975 financial in-
stability has reduced the incomes of developing countries by roughly 25%. Financial
instability cost Latin America alone some 2.2 percentage points of growth a year in the
1980s and 0.7 percentage points in the 1990s.
Financial markets are becoming increasingly integrated internationally, with the
liberalization of capital flows, rapid financial innovation (futures, forwards, options and
swaps), the development of telecommunications technology and its capacity to complete
orders and transactions in real time and the growth of strong institutional investors with
highly leveraged hedge operations.
But the international financial arena has only a limited normative framework for
preventive regulation, supervision and intervention. There are no mechanisms to en-
sure control of externalities derived from national decisions. This regulatory asymmetry
facilitated the development of international transactions, but it also increased the risk of
instability and negative effects connected with growing market interdependence.
While the institutional framework for international financial cooperation was
formed some 50 years ago, the participants and interactions that are the target of regula-
tions have changed considerably in recent decades. Several emerging economies are
active on the international scene, including some potential economic giants with the ca-
pacity to affect international financial markets. The range of matters requiring interna-
tional cooperation has widened: balance of payment adjustments, financial regulation
and supervision, debt management and financial crisis resolution—new matters requir-
ing new institutional and normative responses.
But as the global economy has moved further away from the harsh effects of the
last financial crisis, ambitious proposals for a new international financial architecture are
losing their appeal, and discussion now focuses on the technical requirements for im-
proving information and the levels of preventive regulation and supervision of national
markets. These issues are also important, of course, and can lead to improvements in
market efficiency at a microeconomic level. But it is doubtful whether these methods
alone can reduce systematic risks, such as economic volatility or contagiousness.
The current configuration of the financial system is doubly costly for developing
economies. First, it increases the risk and vulnerability of economies integrating in in-
ternational capital markets through the high volatility of capital flows and recurrent fi-
nancial crises. And second, the market configuration restricts developing countries’
possibilities of accessing public and private financing. Financial markets thus present a
double stability and efficiency problem that severely affects developing country growth
prospects.
A growing body of literature documents the costs of instability and financial cri-
ses (IMF 1998; Asís, Camarazza and Salgado 2000; Dobson and Hufbauer 2001; Ca-
prio and Klingebiel 2002) to economic growth (Obstfeld 1998; Reisen and Soto 2000;
Fernández-Arias and Hausmann 2000; World Bank 2001a). Griffith-Jones and
Gottschalk (2004) estimate the costs of the financial crises of 1995–2002, deliberately
restricting their study to financial crises (excluding bank crises) and countries directly
involved (Argentina, Brazil, Indonesia, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Thailand
and Turkey). Comparing the evolution of potential and real GDP over at least six years,
they estimate the cost of the crises at $1.2 trillion ($150 billion a year) (table 2.1).
Table 2.1. Comparative output loss for each country in a financial crisis, 1997–2002
Output loss
The results are only slightly higher than those of Mendoza (2002), who focuses
on bank crises more than currency crises, and are similar to the more recent results of
Dobson and Hufbauer (2001), who estimate average annual GDP losses of 0.7% for
Latin American economies and 1.4% for Asian economies. Bordo et al. (2001), in a
wide sample, find that the loss from an average crisis approaches 9% of GDP or close
to an average annual output loss of 1% and that the probability of a randomly selected
country experiencing a crisis is roughly 8%. And Eichengreen (2004), in a broad survey
of the literature, concludes that the cost of a financial crisis is roughly 1% of GDP
growth a year, meaning that the financial crises of the last 25 years reduced the income
of developing countries by a cumulative 25%.
Financial crises often generate high costs in economies far away from the economy that
was initially involved. This ability of financial markets to create systemic effects, which
are difficult to contain locally, makes financial stability a public good.
Financial stability presents the typical features of a global public good. It affects
not only countries, but also the global economy. The regulatory and institutional re-
sponse should have a similar reach, even if some complementary activities are under-
taken in countries and some regulatory frameworks have a defined regional coverage.
Internationally, efforts to limit the risks of financial instability focus on improving the
strength of macroeconomic policies, applying financial codes and standards, and
strengthening prudential and supervisory mechanisms in each country. Regionally, it
may be effective to coordinate macroeconomic policies and set up regulatory frame-
works that permit the establishing of more stable financial environments. The Euro-
pean Monetary System and later the European Monetary Union demonstrate how to
improve financial security in a regional ambit.
Beyond such activities, however, financial markets are primarily global. Finan-
cial stability, because of its scope, is a global public good. It shares the features of a pub-
lic good and a club good. Its institutional and regulatory framework is a pure public
good. Any country can benefit from the rules and the logistic infrastructure for transac-
tions within financial markets, such as those of the Society for Worldwide International
Financial Telecommunications for managing transactions in convertible currencies. Yet
the financial framework also operates as a club good, since some transactions (for ex-
ample, access to loans) are excludable and subject to user fees (tolls) based on a coun-
try’s borrowing level. Countries that engage in more borrowing will pay more fees. The
less a country is involved in international financial markets, the less it will be affected by
financial market instability. This explains why emerging markets, which are highly inte-
grated into international financial markets and have a high degree of internal fragility,
suffer most financial crises.
The provision of financial stability is a weakest link aggregation technology: the
integrity of the financial system is dependent, in part, on its weakest component finan-
cial market, where crises can begin and affect other markets. Countries with greater
economic difficulties and a weak financial system are where a crisis will start that may
subsequently affect countries with sound macroeconomic fundamentals. As Eichen-
green (2004: 250) notes: “countries without financial markets cannot have financial cri-
ses.” At times, financial stability is a weaker link public good in which the smallest pro-
vision level has the greatest impact on the level of the good. The second smallest
provision level has the next greatest impact, and so on. With a weaker link public good,
Advances in financial security require effective treatment of the asymmetry and ine-
qualities between countries and markets at the international level. In an increasingly
globalized world, the weakness of one part affects the entire system. The main problem
is the diverse capacity of countries to access international capital markets and the con-
sequences for these countries’ effective autonomy in economic policy.
The combination of volatile capital markets and high debt to GDP ratios creates
an important systemic issue for international financial markets. Emerging market
economies are attractive destinations for foreign investment, so that in periods of
growth they register large capital inputs. As a consequence, their exchange rate appreci-
ates and the debt to GDP ratio falls, provided a significant part of their debt is in foreign
currency. Although interest rates fall during the expansion period, that does not relieve
the debt burden. Nor does it affect the profitability of foreign investors, due to the ap-
preciation of the exchange rate, thus boosting new capital inputs.
However, the high debt ratios (more than 50% of GDP) and the limited matur-
ity of these debts force a continuous renewal of the debt, rendering these countries
highly vulnerable to any internal event (growth reduction or a political crisis, for exam-
ple) or external shocks (terms of trade shock or financial contagion). In the event of a
shock, the currency may depreciate, forcing interest rates to rise, reducing growth pros-
pects and further raising the debt to GDP ratio. During the crisis, multilateral debt will
replace private capital leaving the country. If the stabilization is successful, the deprecia-
tion of the currency will stop and a new cycle of private debt with short maturity will
start up. If the stabilization fails, the country will plunge into financial crisis of variable
duration and effects.
Fiscal policy in countries with high debt accumulation tends to be procyclical.
Periods of recession worsen the debt to GDP ratio, increasing the risk of a debt event,
thus requiring a tighter fiscal policy. During periods of expansion, fears of a debt event
decrease and governments tend to expand. Anticyclical use of fiscal policy is lost.
The only way to deal with a high debt to GDP ratio is to keep GDP growth high
and to accumulate large primary surpluses. Such objectives are difficult to achieve,
however, and are to some extent contradictory. Large primary surpluses require lower-
ing investment, worsening the character of public spending and slowing economic
growth, and thus make reduction of the debt to GDP ratio harder. A combination of
episodes of adjustment fatigue, as a result of which primary surpluses appear, and weak
growth performance, due partly to the limited capacity of investment, ends up launching
these countries into a permanent debt trap (Derviç and Özer 2005).
Two objectives should spur reform of the international financial system: stability and
efficiency. Increasing stability is desirable to prevent further financial crises and reduce
contagion. Providing adequate supplies of capital, public and private, to developing
countries, including the poorest, is important for economic growth. With these objec-
tives in mind, six aspects appear particularly important in reform of the international
financial system. (For a more radical proposal for a world currency, see viewpoint 2.1.)
3 Nevertheless, it is possible to admit the existence of a threshold above which the removal of
capital controls is advantageous (Edwards and Gaventa 2001; Klein 2003).
Considerable progress has taken place in defining codes and standards for financial sec-
tor regulation. Codes and standards aim at improving the information available to credi-
tors, increasing the transparency and efficiency of markets and reducing the risks of cri-
sis and contagion. The Financial Stability Forum points out 12 areas thought to be most
important for improvement (table 2.2).
The International Monetary Fund (IMF), in its Reports on Observance of Stan-
dards and Codes, follows up on implementation. It finds that the most important im-
provements have been in data dissemination, fiscal transparency, mon etary and finan-
cial policy transparency and banking supervision. Many developing countries favour
implementation of the regulatory frameworks to improve their access to international
capital markets, but most codes and standards are promoted by developed countries
with little participation by developing countries (Rojas-Suárez 2005).
The idea of a world currency is by no means count, prices would be quoted in pairs. If there
new, but it has not had much attention in recent were n commodities, there would be 1/2 n(n − l)
discussions of reform of what many call—rather relative prices. If n = 100, then the number of rela-
too optimistically—the international monetary tive prices is RP = 4,950.
“system”. Of course, even some barter communities would
This system includes 184 members of the Inter- catch on and realize that with price relations such
national Monetary Fund (IMF) representing about as aX = bY = cZ they could find a common unit of
170 currencies. Looking at the complete disor- account, such as X, so that the relative prices
ganization of currency markets and the recurrent quoted in a unit of X is equal to X = b/aY = c/aZ,
currency and debt crises, one might well wonder giving birth to a numeraire and eventually a full-
why more than one currency is needed to conduct fledged unit of account. In a barter economy, the
international trade and payments in a world that unit of account would be a commodity.
has prided itself, since the end of the Cold War, And not just any commodity. By a process of
on globalization and has aspired to a high degree natural selection, the chosen unit of value or nu-
of free trade and international interdependence. meraire commodity would be the most familiar,
“Money-of-Account”, Keynes wrote in the open- reliable and stable: familiar because people have
ing lines of his Treatise on Money, “is the primary to know its value to relate other values to it; reli-
concept of a Theory of Money.” A money of ac- able because it must not be ephemeral and sub-
count comes into existence along with debt and ject to the vicissitudes of weather, harvests and
price-lists, which can be expressed only in terms political changes; and stable because it must re-
of a money of account. The money of account is a side in memory.
public good in the most precise sense of the term, International monetary systems have attributes
in that one person can use it without that good of public goods in the sense that one country can
detracting from the utility of money enjoyed by benefit from them without detracting from the
other users. benefits derived by other countries and can even
Even more than a public good as classically increase them. Monetary unions and currency
conceived, money as unit of account is a “super areas (fixed exchange rate zones) are examples
public” good or “magical good” in the sense that of monetary systems that produce welfare gains in
an individual’s utility is generally enhanced by the the form of reduced transaction costs, enhanced
participation of more users. To be more precise, transparency of pricing and elimination of balance
money as a unit of account is a “network external- of payments problems and uncertainty about ex-
ity,” where benefits increase to each user as more change rates. Larger monetary unions and cur-
agents recognize the same money account rency areas are more stable than smaller ones
measure. A lonely but rational Robinson Crusoe because the marginal utility of money declines at
would need an internal numeraire for economizing a slower rate, making the liquidity preference
on thought in making personal choices, but he schedule flatter.
would have no need for a social unit of account. In
Narrowing currency fluctuations: a basket of
a complex economy, however, it is indispensable
three currencies
and the more so the larger the economy. For this
reason the nation state, with hardly a single ex- How can a world currency be defined? One ap-
ception, has always evolved into a common proach would define it in terms of gold, the historic
monetary area. Not a single country today uses monetary metal. Gold has the sanction of history,
more than one domestically officially created including the Bretton Woods Agreement in 1944,
money within its territory. which settled on gold as the basis for currency
parities. A return to the system applied before
The public good nature of a currency, looked at
1971, in which the United States fixed the price of
from its primary concept of unit of account, hardly
gold in dollars and other countries used that “con-
requires explanation. Imagine a barter society
without a unit of account. Without a unit of ac-
But the same factors that brought down the 1998—at once eliminating speculative capital
Bretton Woods arrangements would render it diffi- movements—they could do the same with the
cult, if not impossible, to make the dollar converti- dollar-euro exchange rate. A similar procedure
ble on demand into gold today. No price of gold could be conducted between the European Cen-
anywhere near current levels would make it plau- tral Bank and the Bank of Japan, and the Federal
sible to convert the trillions of outstanding dollar Reserve Board and the Bank of Japan.
claims into the precious metal. A monetary union of the Group of Three
Nor would the world’s second most important Make a leap of the imagination and consider the
currency area, the euro, want to take on the bur- possibilities of a monetary union of the three cen-
den of convertibility—despite the fact that the tral banks of the Group of Three (G-3). Of course,
European System of Central Banks holds half the the argument will be made that these areas are
world’s monetary gold reserves. Gold may find a too different to have a monetary union. But in
useful role in a future international monetary sys- terms of economic reality, they are much more
tem, but the possibility of a system involving the similar than the 12 countries that now make up
convertibility of dollar or euro claims into gold the European Monetary Union and far more simi-
seems unrealistic. lar than the 25 countries that now make up the
A better approach to creating a world currency European Union and that at some future date will
is to start with arrangements for stabilizing ex- probably all be members of the same currency
change rates and gradually move from there. The area.
three most important currencies in the world, the This G-3 monetary union would not be a single-
dollar, euro and yen, could be made into a basket currency monetary union. The United States
of currencies, called, let us say, the dey. Because would not give up the dollar, Europe give up the
there is no important inflation in the dey area, it euro or Japan give up the yen. It would be a mul-
should be possible for the three dey central banks ticurrency monetary union, a fixed exchange rate
to minimize currency fluctuations using a combi- area with a common monetary policy.
nation of unsterilized currency intervention and
Formation of a monetary union for members of
monetary policies. The dey could then become
either a closed economy or an open economy with
the platform on which to build a global currency—
flexible exchange rates requires five conditions:
let us call that the intor.
1. Consensus on an inflation target (for exam-
If the proposal were to be considered today, ac-
ple, 1%–3%).
tivity would start with a plan to prevent excessive
depreciation of the dollar, euro or yen. There 2. A common index for measuring inflation (for
would be a period of tâtonnement for the central example, the euro area’s Harmonized Index
banks to get a feel for the market and sustainable of Consumer Prices).
exchange rates. A look at the dollar-euro ex- 3. Locking of exchange rates, as the European
change rate over time shows that it would have Monetary Union did in July 1, 1998.
been fairly easy for the central bank to have put a
4. A dey central bank to determine monetary
floor for the euro at $0.90, or at least $0.85, when
policy, as the European Central Bank did for
market participants and officials asserted that the
the euro in 1999–2002.
euro had fallen too low. This could have estab-
5. A mechanism for distributing seigniorage (in
lished a precedent that would subsequently have
the European Monetary Union it is propor-
allowed establishing a ceiling for the euro.
tionate to equity in the European Central
Today, one might start with the European Cen-
Bank).
tral Bank and Federal Reserve Board establishing
A prime requisite for the stability of either a sin-
a $1.30 ceiling for the euro. No doubt that ceiling
gle-currency monetary union or a multicurrency
would be tested by speculators, but, provided the
monetary union with a fixed exchange rate is fis-
principles alluded to above are considered, the
cal discipline, whether voluntarily imposed by
victory of officials in maintaining the ceiling cannot
The duty of the dey central bank would be to stable in terms of the main world currencies.
pursue monetary stability in the dey area, which The process could start bilaterally between the
represents nearly two-thirds of the world econ- United States and Europe, Europe and Japan or
omy. Successful monetary unions need some the United States and Japan, or simultaneously
arrangement to prevent free-rider fiscal policies. with all three. The core basket of the three dey
The problems should not be insurmountable in an currencies could be altered at the discretion of the
arrangement with three central banks. There Board of Governors. As the economies behind the
would be a great increase in efficiency in ex- currencies in the basket expand or contract in
change and payments once the huge gyrations of relative terms, weights assigned to the currencies
exchange rates were removed and an enormous in the basket would be adjusted. Consideration
gain to the rest of the world. The dey unit should could also be given to changes in the currencies
become the platform on which to base a multilat- in the basket.
eral world currency in which every country would The basic plan for the world currency could be
have a share. implemented in three stages:
Creation of the intor • Stage 1 Transition to stable exchange rates.
A strong case can be made for widening, ex- Involving steps preparatory to the G-3
tending and generalizing the monetary union to monetary union. A gradual process could
other countries. Other countries would benefit start with ceilings and floors on the G-3 cur-
from stability of exchange rates among the three rencies.
largest currency areas because it would become a • Stage 2 G-3 monetary union based on the
more stable anchor for their own currencies. All dey. Fixing an inflation target and defining
countries would benefit from the adoption of a the price level in terms of the dey, locking
global unit of account. Countries outside the G-3 exchange rates, establishing the joint mone-
(especially larger countries) might resent trilateral tary policy committee and arranging for the
dominance in money matters in which they have division of seigniorage.
no voice. And a world currency is in the nature of
• Stage 3 Creation of the intor. Selecting a
a social contract in which every country has a
definitive name and value for the currency,
juridical stake in proportion to its economic size.
the mechanism and agency for introducing
The Board of Governors of the IMF, composed it, the system and criteria for controlling its
of the finance ministers or central bank governors quantity, its backing in terms of currency or
of all member countries, represents a broad- commodity reserves and the location of its
based international monetary authority in which all central authority.
countries have votes. Its sanction of the adoption
A world currency would level the playing field for
of an international currency such as the intor,
big and small countries alike. As Paul Volcker
freely convertible into dollars, euros, yen and dey,
aptly put it, "in a globalized world, we should have
would mark a great advance in the creation of an
an international currency.” Why not make one?
international financial architecture.
Source: Drawn from a background paper by Mun-
The Board of Governors could make whatever
dell (2005).
changes are necessary in the IMF Articles of
Agreement. Instead of emphasizing to its clients
The advances in codes and standards have not been paralleled by similar advances in
regulatory standards for international investors, required for markets to perform prop-
erly (Kaufman 1998; Eatwell and Taylor 2000). There have been some improvements
in the exchange of information and coordination between regulators. The three Basel
committees began to work on common regulatory standards for application by the regu-
latory authorities of participating countries. The expectation was that these standards
would eventually spread to developing countries through international emulation, mar-
ket pressure and the persuasive capacity of the Bretton Woods institutions.
However, the limited participation of developing countries in the decision-
making processes of the Basel committees may have important costs in terms not only
of institutional legitimacy but also of regulatory efficiency. Many developing countries
have criticized the new Basel Capital Accord (Basel II) for its restrictive effect on loans
from international banks and its possible procyclical impact (Griffith-Jones and Spratt
2001).
Developing countries also have a very limited role in another new institution,
the Financial Stability Forum, created after the Asian financial crisis to identify financial
vulnerability and sources of systemic risk. Through its working parties, the Financial
Stability Forum prepares reports on such aspects of financial markets as the establish-
ment of minimum standards and conduct codes and control of hedge funds and off-
shore centres. Its capacity for influencing decisions made by regulatory authorities in
developed countries is limited, however.
The most recent financial crises revealed the importance of institutions able to inject
liquidity into economies suffering from acute instability. After the Asian crisis, the IMF
created two new facilities for this purpose, the Supplementary Reserve Facility and the
Contingent Credit Line, and in 2002 it created a unit for special operations to deal with
financial contingencies in emerging market economies.
The Supplementary Reserve Facility provides resources to relieve exceptional
short-term difficulties in the balance of payments caused by sudden changes in the mar-
ket affecting the capital account or the availability of reserves. The Contingent Credit
Line, a preventive financial instrument, is used to help countries with heavy pressure on
their capital accounts.
Though a step in the right direction, these responses are insufficient. The Sup-
plementary Reserve Facility’s effectiveness at time of crisis is limited by the small scale
of available credits. Adequate funds are needed to defeat speculative pressure—before
an affected country’s reserves are depleted. The IMF has traditionally been seen as a
catalyser or coordinator of other financial resources, an appropriate role in times of sta-
bility, but clearly insufficient in times of crisis.
However, the rescue operations of the Supplementary Reserve Facility may
function as a security mechanism against crises, helping to avoid problems of moral
hazard by preventing irresponsible or incautious behaviour by creditors and debtors.
The IMF needs to achieve a balance between its security-providing function of limiting
PUBLIC DEBT
The HIPC Initiative was a positive step in dealing with the foreign debt of developing
countries. However, severe problems remain, including how to define debt sustainabil-
ity. The established criteria (debt stock of 150% of exports and annual debt service of
15% of exports) are questionable in both theory and practice. Of the 42 countries po-
tentially eligible for the HIPC Initiative, 15 have received substantial debt reductions,
but only 7 have managed to maintain their debt at a level that is considered sustainable.
High variability in export prices and volatility in growth make keeping debt below the
established parameters a difficult task. Debtor countries must constantly revise the
amount due and subject to cancellation by recurrently topping up to maintain sustain-
ability. The World Bank has proposed a new composite index, and the UN Millen-
nium Project has recommended defining sustainability according to a country’s capacity
to achieve the Millennium Development Goals.
Another problem is the eligibility of debt for cancellation under the HIPC Ini-
tiative, which many believe to be too restrictive. Some have proposed applying the cut-
off date for bilateral debts considered at the Paris Club.
A third problem is the need to prevent debt relief activities from impeding other
activities of the IMF. Some have suggested revalorisation of IMF gold reserves, cur-
rently valued at $8 billion, although their real market price could reach as high as $40
billion if sales were managed so as not to depress the market.
Dealing with “sovereign bankruptcy” presents yet another challenge. Various
academic researchers and the IMF (Krueger 2002a,b) have proposed creating an arbi-
trage mechanism, a sovereign debt restructuring mechanism to avoid both collective
action problems derived from the existence of a plurality of creditors and the asymmet-
ric distribution of costs in credit agreements. The positive effect would come from a
quick, quasi-judicial process that considered all the interests involved, including those of
the populations of the debtor countries, which could have a positive effect at the inter-
national level. Against this statutory approach, other creditors (led by the US Treasury)
defend the advantages of reliance on collective action clauses in debt contracts, which is
a more decentralized and market-oriented approach.
Developing countries, even very poor ones, keep high reserve levels as a preventive
mechanism against internal adjustments, external shocks or currency crises (figure 2.1).
However, accumulating reserves as a self-insurance mechanism has high costs. The re-
Community of Independent
States
Africa
Central and Eastern Europe
Billion Dollars
Middle East
Western hemisphere
China
There have been repeated proposals to use special drawing rights (SDRs) as
more neutral reserve assets and as an international financial contribution to rescue
packages in cases of financial crises. New issues of SDRs could be temporary, during
periods of crisis only (Meltzer 2000), giving this instrument a clearly cyclical character,
or permanent, linking SDRs to the provision of reserve assets and to the financing of
activities connected with the provision of international public good (Zedillo 2001; Soros
2002; Stiglitz 2002). Resorting to SDRs would provide a source of finance at no cost, to
developed or developing countries, and would have clear positive effects on developing
countries if used correctly.
A traditional argument against resorting to new issues of SDRs is their inflation-
ary effect. However, the evidence suggests that the additional liquidity from the SDRs
would be unlikely to have even a slight effect on levels of international inflation, particu-
larly at a time when those levels are historically low.
I
nternational trade has grown rapidly in recent decades, creating many potential
benefits and becoming central to any development strategy. But the benefits do not
materialize automatically as a country opens its economy to the rest of the world.
There is no clear-cut relationship between openness and development.
Arguments for free trade have their roots in comparative advantage theory,
which maintains that trade enhances every country’s welfare given the initial resource
base, because of relative differences in countries’ productivity across activities they un-
dertake (static mutual gains from trade). Dynamic gains from trade are often related to
increasing returns to scale, product differentiation and technological differences. The
modern theory of endogenous growth is ambiguous with regard to whether trade liber-
alization alone fosters growth, as this depends on different forces of dynamic compara-
tive advantage and whether they push the economy in the direction of activities that con-
tribute to long-run growth through externalities in research and development, process
and product innovations, value chain innovations and so on, or divert the economy
away from such activities (Rodrik 2001: 26). Thus, in assessing the benefits from the
trade regime, static and dynamic gains from trade need to be taken into account.
Empirical analysis is not conclusive either. For instance, while Dollar (1992),
Sachs and Warner (1995), Edwards (1998) and Frankel and Romer (1999) find that
trade increases income, Rodriguez and Rodrik (1999), in a review of these studies,
question the robustness of the relationship,4 and Wolff (2000) finds empirical support
for models defending the creation of comparative advantage. If anything, as Rodrik
(2001) observes, the only systematic relationship uncovered by empirical research is
that countries dismantle trade restrictions as they get richer, indicating that today’s rich
countries embarked on modern economic growth behind protective barriers. Despite
continuing claims of a relationship between openness and economic growth, Helleiner
(2000: 5) notes that “it isn’t at all obvious either (1) that further external liberalisation
(‘openness’) is now in every country’s interest and in all dimensions or (2) that in the
overarching sweep of global economic history what the world now most requires is a set
of global rules that promote or ease the path to greater freedom for global market ac-
tors, and are universal in application.”
In other words, since trade liberalization alone cannot be relied on to deliver
high rates of economic growth, it does not receive the same priority at the national level
as it typically receives in the development policies advocated by multilateral organiza-
tions. Mendoza and Bahadur (2002: 3) therefore argue that more attention should be
paid to whether the international trade regime is coherent or consistent with the devel-
opment goals of the countries it is supposed to benefit.
4 Rodriguez and Rodrik (1999) argued that the fragility of the trade and income link may stem
from the assumption of a linear relationship between openness and growth. Noguer and Siscart
(2004) reexamined the issue and found that open trade does raise income and found the results
to be robust to the Rodriguez and Rodrik assumptions.
Global trade liberalization provides a global public good, an international trade regime
with full reciprocity and non-discrimination among trading partners (Zedillo 2006). The
international trade regime is a joint-product activity that yields outputs that vary in their
degree of publicness. As such, the regime has both private and public outputs (Birdsall
and Lawrence 1999; Mendoza 2003) with excludable benefits from the associated pri-
vate good (for example, most favoured nation status) and non-excludable benefits from
the associated public good (for example, efficiency gains to the traders). The presence
of country-specific private gains from the trade regime facilitates its provision, insofar as
countries are forced to reveal their preferences for these private goods and, thus, for the
jointly produced public good. If the component private and public outputs are com-
plementary (better when consumed together), then preference revelation will be fuller.
This follows because the desire for the public good increases with greater consumption
of the associated private good. An increase in the share of jointly produced excludable
to total outputs augments preference revelation.
Since membership may be restricted, the international trade regime may be a
club good. When, however, network externalities are present so that members’ benefits
5 As had been the case for today’s advanced industrial countries as well (Scherer and Watal
2001).
Merchandise
Developing countries 24.5 19.2 29.5 24.3 31.6 33.5
South-East Europe and Common- 5.7 5.8 5.3 3.7 2.7 3.5
wealth of Independent States
Developed countries 69.7 75.0 65.3 72.0 65.7 63.1
Services
Developing countries na na 19 19 23 23
South-East Europe and Common- na na 2 1 2 2
wealth of Independent States
Developed countries na na 79 80 75 75
Trade liberalization presents two problems for that in high-income, high-productivity economies.
low-income economies (UNDP 2002; Mendoza Much of the labour force in low-income economies
2003). The first is that many of them operate in an is either unemployed or works at very low produc-
asymmetrical trade environment: they are forced tivity, often in the informal sector. In many devel-
to liberalize their markets to incoming manufac- oping countries the effective rate of unemploy-
tures, but their access to external markets for raw ment is high—more than 30% in some countries.
and semi-processed commodities is limited by In China, and to a lesser extent India, the num-
protectionism. This has led to widespread calls for bers are startling. Of China’s labour force of some
a “level playing field”. The second is the insistence 770 million, 100–150 million people currently work
that low-income economies do more to define the at very low levels of productivity and are waiting to
global trading system, so that these inequities are be absorbed into the global economy. This sur-
not sustained. plus is equivalent to more than one-quarter of the
Both these policy-related concerns derive from total labour force in all high-income economies.
an intellectual architecture that, while mindful of The absorption of the reserve labour force will
the redistributions deriving from trade policy re- take a very long time, particularly as technology
form and renewed patterns of specialization and becomes increasingly labour saving. But many
trade, is built on the premise of mutual gains from developing economies have invested substantially
trade. But this architecture is flawed: many trading in skill development. The consequence: the re-
partners are structurally excluded from the bene- serve army of labour is no longer confined to un-
fits of trade and suffer from the extension of a skilled workers.
liberalized trading system as a global public good. Questioning the assumption of capital immobil-
Questioning the case for openness ity. Much of the capacity expansion in low-income
The theoretical case for trade liberalization is economies, particularly in China, was financed
based on three key assumptions: full employment, domestically. But a considerable proportion was
the immobility of capital and resource transfers to sourced externally, through a combination of indi-
facilitate restructuring and dynamic comparative rect private portfolio investments into stock mar-
advantage. Each assumption defies reality, par- kets and direct foreign investment into enter-
ticularly with China’s increasing participation in the prises. Following the 1997 Asian financial crisis,
global economy. the developing world’s share of foreign direct in-
vestment (FDI) fell. But these reduced investment
Questioning the assumption of full employment. flows were concentrated: Asia accounted for more
Macroeconomic policies see unemployment as a than half of FDI into developing countries.
manageable, temporary departure from a world of
full employment. But an alternative body of think- Questioning income transfers to fund restructur-
ing argues that there is a systemic tendency to- ing. Dynamic comparative advantage must be a
wards a reserve army of labour: as global barriers central component of development strategies for
are reduced, either migrant labour saturates the sustainable income growth. It requires the capac-
market in countries formerly near full employment ity to develop processes of upgrading by building
or imports from labour-surplus economies do the dynamic capabilities in production. This upgrading
same. The net effect depresses the incomes of all targets not just products and process technology,
whose livelihoods depend on the work that can be but also positioning within value chains and the
performed by this surplus labour force, either be- capacity to move from highly competitive chains to
cause wages in a formerly tight labour market are chains with higher barriers to entry.
depressed or because the global labour pool Achieving dynamic comparative advantage and
forces widespread unemployment. systemic capacity to upgrade requires a strategic
This is precisely what is happening in the cur- and policy framework that includes the develop-
rent phase of globalization. The spectre of a ment of a stable macroeconomic operating envi-
global reserve army of labour is emerging to affect ronment with currency stability, affordable invest-
medium- and long-term employment and wage ment and low rates of inflation. It also requires
rates as the large labour surplus in China, India resources to cope with market failures across a
and elsewhere is made available to support global range of sectors. Underlying these industrial and
production networks. technology policies to promote restructuring—
particularly in the poorest countries—must be a
The long-term prognosis: The number of people pool of restructuring funds that governments can
available to work in low-income economies dwarfs
At the global level the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), both as a
treaty and an institution, has been one of the most important international public goods
available to the world economy for the last five decades. After the Second World War,
to end the unilateral trade retaliation seen in the interwar period and establish rule-
based international trade, 23 countries created the GATT. The creation of the World
Trade Organization (WTO) in 1995 as an independent multilateral institution offering
its 149 members (as of 2004) a level playing field for trade negotiations and dispute set-
tlements is an extension of the work of the GATT and a testimony to the ever-growing
importance of global trade in world affairs. As an institution, GATT served as the nego-
tiating forum for a series of rounds aimed at liberalizing trade among the major econo-
mies of the world. As a treaty, it provided a set of multilateral rules for the smooth flow
of global trade.
Up to the early 1960s, the GATT remained a small group of largely developed
countries. Much has changed since then. Successive rounds of trade negotiations have
increased the number of participants and the range of areas under its discipline (table
3.2). Today, 149 countries accounting for more than 90% of the world trade in goods
and services are members of the WTO.
The Tokyo Round (1973–79) and the Uruguay Round (1986–94) led to the
single undertaking approach (see box 3.1 on core principles of the WTO) for accepting
obligations under the GATT. Member countries could no longer choose which parts of
the agreement they would sign up for but had to accept all the obligations under the
GATT, although the time frame for implementing them could vary from country to
country. At the 1994 Ministerial Conference in Marrakech, four main agreements were
brought under WTO administration: the updated version of the old GATT (GATT
94), the Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS), the General
Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) and the Dispute Settlement Understanding.
Membership in the WTO entails accepting all the agreements without exception.
Table 3.2. Trade rounds under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
Number of
Year Place/name Subjects covered countries
Three core principles guide the way decisions are made within the multilateral trade regime.
From its inception in 1948 the multilateral trade regime adopted a strong non-discrimination
principle embodied in the most favoured nation clause. While overridden in practice by pref-
erential trade agreements, this clause remains the most basic principle of multilateralism.
The second principle is national treatment. It implies that once imported goods pay customs
duties (are nationalized), they have to be treated in the same way as national products, par-
ticularly with respect to domestic taxes.
The third core principle is single undertaking. Before the Uruguay Round, it was possible for a
subset of member countries to reach so-called “plurilateral” agreements or “codes”. These
were usually subscribed to by developed countries and were non-binding for developing
countries, which could adhere voluntarily. After the Uruguay Round, however, this practice
was abandoned. Now, once a decision is made, all members acquire the same obligations,
although the time frame for implementing agreements may vary from country to country.
Finally, a corollary of single undertaking is full consensus. To protect the weaker nations from
being pushed by the stronger ones into adopting rules or codes they oppose, WTO negotia-
tions typically do not finish until a unanimous agreement is reached among all participating
members. In practice, this implies that any country, no matter how small, has veto power, with
two important clarifications. First, this is not a requirement but a practice to legitimize the
adopted rules (WTO articles allow simple majority voting). Second, countries that do not par-
ticipate in a negotiation because they are absent cannot veto.
In recent years, many participants in multilateral trade negotiations have been discouraged by
the lack of progress in trade liberalization. Because of the many exceptions, the most fa-
voured nation clause is no longer the rule of international trade but the exception. In addition,
regional agreements extend well beyond trade preferences to cover all sorts of regulations.
These facts account for a significant increase in the complexity of the rules, which burdens all
countries, especially the poor ones. The tremendous increase in the number of WTO mem-
bers has made negotiations more difficult and time consuming, calling into question the use of
the single undertaking and consensus principles.
Mendoza (2003) considers three aspects of fairness for evaluating the trade regime: neu-
trality, meaning that each country should be at least as well off with the trade regime as
without it; net benefit for all, implying that all countries should benefit from the regime;
and maximin rule, meaning, from the point of view of developing countries, increasing
net benefits from the trade regime. A trade regime built according to these fairness
measures would not harm the progress of developing countries. This is not the situation
of the current regime, however. For example, Harrison, Rutherford and Tarr (1996)
estimate that full implementation of the Uruguay Round would cause a net annual loss
of $16–$30 billion for developing countries, and Anderson et al. (2002) calculate that
the benefits to developing countries of removing trade barriers in merchandise trade
would reach about $108 billion a year.7
Even though the WTO is not a development agency, it plays a key role in im-
proving the economic well-being of the poorer countries by enhancing their opportuni-
ties to participate in international trade flows and thereby boosting their economic
growth. But in 60 years of combined existence, the GATT and the WTO have failed to
persuade the civil societies of developing and least developed countries of the impor-
7 Estimate based on the assumption that high-income countries fully implement the Agreement
on Textiles and Clothing. For a similar analysis, see Mendoza and Bahadur (2002); Ostry
(2002); McCalman (1999).
8 According to the World Bank (2001a: xvii), the cost of enforcement and administration to-
gether with high prices for drugs, agricultural inputs and other key technological inputs could
account for a significant share of public expenditure in many low-income countries.
9 For more on these issues, see Falvey and Foster (2005).
10 The Multi-Fibre Arrangement was designed to protect local producers and jobs in importing
developed countries. It laid down rules for imposing quotas through bilateral or unilateral ac-
tions when surges of imports caused disruptions in trade and production in the textile and cloth-
ing sector of importing developed countries. The quota system was applied differentially across
countries and products. The Agreement on Textiles and Clothing called for a gradual elimina-
tion of quota restrictions between 1995 and 2005.
11 The contingent protection rules were part of the protocol of China’s accession to the WTO.
They permitted other WTO members to use protectionist instruments against China for 15
years. Those instruments covered special anti-surge clauses for textile and clothing products for
four years (until 2008); general anti-surge clauses for 12 years; and initiation of antidumping
cases, allowing China to be treated as a non-market economy, for 15 years. Developed coun-
tries’ lobbies can also seek to use other protectionist devices such as eco-labelling schemes, la-
bour standards rules and other regulatory devices to control imports from China. The non-tariff
barriers and the technical barriers to trade may impose extra costs to suppliers.
12 The origin of the Multi-Fibre Arrangement dates back to 1961 and 1962, when the negotia-
tions for the Short-Term and the Long-Term Arrangements of International Trade in Cotton
Textiles started. The Long-Term Arrangement allowed developed countries to impose restric-
tions, unilaterally or through a negotiated voluntary restraint agreement, on imports from devel-
oping countries considered to be a source of actual or potential “market disruption.” The Long-
Term Arrangement meant breaking the non-discrimination principle of the GATT. Its provi-
sions were preferred to those of the GATT, which allowed safeguard action, retaliation and
proof of “serious injury” rather than “market disruption.” The developed countries considered
the Long-Term Arrangement to be more advantageous for developing countries as it offered a
transparent set of rules for market access, including a guaranteed increase in quotas (of 5% per
year in most cases) in place of a series of ad hoc, restrictive measures. The Long-Term Ar-
rangement also required developed countries to restructure their industries and return interna-
tional trade in textiles and clothing to GATT rules. The Long-Term Arrangement was ex-
tended twice, in 1967 and 1970. Extension of the arrangement in 1974 gave way to the Multi-
Fibre Arrangement.
Source: UNCTAD 2003. Note: Leather products include footwear, upholstery and general products. Tariffs are aver-
age values.
13 The so-called Singapore issues were introduced by the European Union at the 1996 Singa-
pore Ministerial Meeting and were received with little enthusiasm by the other members.
14 Trade facilitation means simplification and standardization of trade and customs procedures,
transport and other certifications, and information flows associated with the import and export
of goods.
Standards are part of the architecture of mar- weaknesses and thereby affect the competitive
kets. On the face of it, they are quintessentially positions of countries and certain market partici-
public goods and so may be undersupplied, espe- pants. They note that a few developing countries
cially if the costs of provision are borne in one have gained access to high-value markets in in-
market and some of the benefits fall elsewhere. dustrial countries despite the existence of exact-
Standards play important roles in the world econ- ing standards. This less pessimistic view of the
omy and in economic development. impact on international trade of sanitary and phy-
tosanitary-related standards suggests that it can-
Standards and regulations: threats or oppor-
not definitively be concluded that standards and
tunities?
regulations are either barriers or facilitators. It is
Standards and regulations can be seen as trade more important to consider the effects of such
barriers or trade facilitators. Those who see them standards in the context of wider capacity con-
as trade barriers suggest that standards and regu- straints and underlying supply chain trends.
lations are established and abused to protect do-
Governments can help by facilitating collective
mestic markets from imports (Athukorala and
action among stakeholders in addressing sanitary
Jayasuriya 2003). The costs of complying with
and phytosanitary standards. Collaboration
standards are exorbitant and unrealistic for both
among industries, governments, universities and
producers and exporters, especially in developing
research organizations is needed to attain collec-
countries. Even when imposed as health and
tive efficiency and upgrading (Humphrey and
safety requirements, standards (such as sanitary
Schmitz 2000, 2002). By leading domestic pro-
and phytosanitary standards) can impede trade
ducers to improve their product quality and pro-
because of additional compliance costs or be-
duction methods, in the long run this could make
cause they are set at a level that foreign produc-
producers more aware of changing standards and
ers cannot profitably meet, allowing domestic
regulations and therefore more proactive. Never-
producers to monopolize the domestic market
theless, despite efforts to strengthen sanitary and
(Mattoo 2001). As a result, developing countries
phytosanitary-related capacity, developing coun-
may not benefit from trade liberalization not only
tries still need technical assistance from industrial
by being unable to enter new markets, but also by
countries and donor organizations to expedite
having difficulty maintaining existing ones (Wilson
technological and organizational upgrading.
2002; Unnevehr 2003).
The most favoured nation principle is the cen- bling clause, adopted in 1970 as a 10-year excep-
trepiece of the General Agreement on Tariffs and tion to GATT Article I but rendered as a “decision”
Trade (GATT)/World Trade Organization (WTO) in 1979 without an expiration date, two or more
system. If a member nation grants another mem- developing countries may engage in virtually any
ber nation a tariff concession, it must extend that exchange of trade preferences.
concession to all other member nations. The out-
come is a uniform tariff across all trading partners, Preferential trade areas as a national public
without discrimination. bad
There are two key advantages of this principle.
Economic theory concludes that preferential
First, if discrimination were permitted, each mem-
trade areas that are largely trade diverting and
ber nation could subject a product to as many
welfare worsening will be endorsed while those
tariff rates as it had trading partners. A bureaucrat
that are trade creating and welfare improving will
would then decide the national origin of the prod-
be rejected. The underling reason is that produc-
uct and assess the duty accordingly. With thou-
ers rather than consumers are the key driving
sands of products and hundreds of tariff rates
force behind policy changes and they benefit from
applicable to each product, this would be a night-
trade diverting preferential trade areas while los-
mare for the businessman and a dream come true
ing from trade creating preferential trade areas.
for the bureaucrat. Moreover, with the compo-
nents of each good produced in different coun- Three devices are commonly applied to contain
tries, establishing the origin of a good would itself competition between member country firms and to
be subject to arbitrariness. The most favoured maximize the benefits to these firms at the ex-
nation principle cleans up this potential mess. pense of outside firms. First, insofar as preferen-
tial trade areas admit sectoral exceptions, they
Second, the most favoured nation principle
focus on excluding precisely the sectors in which
promotes efficiency. A product is imported from
trade creation would dominate. Second, countries
the nation that can deliver it the most cheaply. We
use stringent rules of origin to contain competition
buy automobiles from Japan if it can deliver them
in sectors that are subject to trade creation. Third,
more cheaply than all other trading partners.
liberalization in sectors subject to trade creation
Likewise, we buy shirts from China if it supplies
may also be back loaded.
them the most cheaply. Preferential tariffs, on the
other hand, introduce inefficiency by allowing
Preferential trade areas as an international
high-cost sellers to outcompete low-cost sellers by
public bad
taking advantage of the preference. Economists
refer to this phenomenon as trade diversion. While private producer interests can come to-
Thus, the most favoured nation principle repre- gether to forge preferential trade areas that are a
sents an important public good available to the national public bad and to thwart those that prom-
world economy. Preferential trade areas allow ise to be national public goods, from the viewpoint
their members to lower tariffs among themselves of the international trading system, the adverse
without lowering them against other WTO mem- effects of preferential trade areas on non-
bers. All preferential trade areas involve discrimi- members are even greater. If two or more coun-
nation against outsiders in favour of insiders and, tries enter an arrangement that hurts one or more
thus, violate the most favoured nation principle. of them, it is their business. In the design of the
Nevertheless, two key forms of preferential trade rules of international trade, it is the impact of such
agreements—free trade areas and customs un- arrangements on the rest of the world that should
ions, which eliminate internal trade barriers—have receive the highest priority. Preferential trade ar-
been accommodated within the GATT/WTO sys- eas can adversely affect outside countries and the
tem through an exception contained in GATT Arti- multilateral trading system through five major
cle XXIV. Additionally, under the so-called ena- channels: terms of trade, increased protection
POLICY PROPOSALS
Changes are needed in the international trade system for full provision of this interna-
tional public good. And while the WTO has not formally signed up to the Millennium
Development Goals, it did make clear in its preamble to the inaugural Marrakech
agreement its commitment to development. Thus the Millennium Development Goals
should be an important yardstick by which the WTO is assessed.
Reforms should deal with the tensions that have emerged between developing
and developed countries from the Uruguay Round. The bargain struck at the Uruguay
Round entailed high costs of compliance and minimal benefits in terms of market ac-
cess for developing countries (Mendoza and Bahadur 2002; see also Finger and Schuler
2000; Oxfam International 2002; Page and Davenport 1994). The multilateral trade
regime is valuable only to the extent that it generates utility for its users. According to
Mendoza (2003), a better balance between free and fair trade is needed to fully provide
this public good.
Several changes are needed to rebalance the results of the Uruguay Round. The first is
liberalizing agriculture and textiles markets in industrial countries (Mendoza 2003; Fin-
ger and Schuknecht 2001; Hertel and Martin 2001; Ostry 2002). The second is restrict-
ing the use of antidumping measures by developed countries against developing coun-
tries (Rodrik 2001; UNCTAD 2000; Raghavan 1996; United Nations 2001). The third
is allowing greater international mobility of workers for trade in labour-intensive services
(Rodrik 2001). And the fourth is reducing tariff peaks and tariff escalation (United Na-
tions 2001; Mendoza 2003). As Hertel and Martin (2000) have argued, when weighted
by import volumes, manufacturing tariffs on developing countries’ exports to developed
countries average 3.4%, while developed countries face average tariffs of only 0.8% on
their exports to developing countries.
While caution is warranted in interpreting the quantitative results of empirical
research, further liberalization is important for reducing poverty. Cline (2004a) esti-
mates that 440 million people could be lifted out of poverty over 15 years if global free
trade were implemented. However, most of the poverty reduction would take place in
Asia, with more modest results in other regions.
Thus the benefits of trade depend not only on trade rules, but also on domestic
capabilities to exploit the potential benefits of international trade. Many developing
countries lack those capabilities. Therefore, not only a more development-oriented ap-
proach to trade rules is required, but also the financial and technical support to build
those capabilities.
Fostering development goals in the international trade regime requires building com-
parative advantages that diversify exports and generate robust growth (Shafaeddin 1994;
Gomory and Baumol 2000). Such strategies are difficult to implement in the current
trade regime (Mendoza 2003; Helleiner 2001; Hausmann and Rodrik 2002; Rodrik
2001). Trade rules with a development-oriented approach would ensure sufficient pol-
icy manoeuvrability for developing countries.
The WTO agreements contain a number of provisions for the “special and dif-
ferential” treatment of developing countries, allowing for granting developing countries
special rights and privileges and for preferential concessions like longer time periods to
implement their tariff commitments and the preferential access to the markets of devel-
oped countries under the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP).
The concept of special and differential treatment has changed over time, from
one providing a range of flexibilities and “spaces for development policy,” making trade
liberalization supportive of development (GATT), to one that is more an instrument for
helping developing countries build their legal and institutional capacities to undertake
trade liberalization (WTO) but limiting the space for economic policy. The provisions
included broad and largely unenforceable statements in favour of development, without
distinguishing among developing country members in terms of their development
needs.
Developing countries agreed to these changes and also to new commitments re-
lated to intellectual property protection, services and investment measures, in the expec-
tation that in turn they would benefit from better market access in agriculture, textiles
and clothing and from greater sensitivity in implementation from special and differential
provisions. But benefits from these changes have, for the most part, failed to material-
ise. This has led to developing countries requesting, in the Doha Declaration mandate,
that the special and differential provisions in specific WTO agreements be made more
precise, effective and operational.
One suggestion to resolve the tensions arising from the politization of discus-
sions of special and differential treatment is to define developing country access to spe-
cial and differential provisions as an integral part of the provisions themselves. This
could be done through a more differentiated approach using certain development-
15 When general agreements conflict with the “development needs” of developing countries,
WTO rules allow for exceptions to the most favoured nation clause under the Generalized Sys-
tem of Preferences (GSP). Begun as a system of unreciprocated concessions from developed to
developing countries to support the development of infant industries in developing countries,
the system has now become an instrument of pressure by developed countries to exert non-
trade concessions from developing countries (in areas such as intellectual property rights, hu-
man rights, and the environment). Increasingly complex trade rules and growing empirical evi-
dence that GSP has not benefited developing countries over the long run are directing increas-
ing attention to this issue.
As Mendoza and Bahadur (2002) state, these reforms are not only in the interests of
developing countries. Developed countries should benefit as well from the more stable
and legitimate trade regime, anchored in a more participatory WTO. Without such
changes, the global public good of an international trade regime will continue to be un-
derprovided.
Any reform of the international trade system must take into account three fac-
tors. First, developing countries are not a homogenous group, sharing the same inter-
ests. For example, according to some empirical research, most benefits from agriculture
liberalization would go to just two countries, Argentina and Brazil. Other developing
countries would be more interested in issues such as technical assistance or greater mo-
bility of workers. Second, empirical research also shows that developed countries would
benefit much more than developing countries from trade liberalization (Charlton and
Stiglitz 2004), so even for efficiency reasons the developed world should work harder to
reach a broader agreement on trade rules. And third, major problems will arise if the
WTO no longer serves the interests of the major trading nations (Kerr 2002). They
may begin to rely more on regional trade organizations or look for new clubs. Develop-
ing countries ought to benefit more from the WTO, but this will happen only if the ma-
jor trading countries remain committed to it. Any reform must avoid the withdrawal of
the developed countries from the system.
E
conomic and social development depends on the capacity to generate, absorb
and diffuse knowledge and technology. Knowledge and technology have the po-
tential to provide benefits to large numbers of users, and the benefit received by
any one user does not reduce the benefits received by others. Knowledge is often con-
sidered a public good (Stiglitz 1999), but it is more complex than it first appears. Several
important qualifications must be considered. These qualifications are crucial to the de-
sign of appropriate policies to increase the rate of innovation and to guide its direction,
at both the national and the international levels.16
Technology and knowledge are neither totally private nor totally public goods (Nelson
1992; Callon 1994). Seen through the public goods lens, knowledge is only partially
non-rival and non-excludable.
If someone develops a new method to stop headaches, and others buy, rent, imitate or
steal the new method, the inventor is still able to use it. More people now benefit from
the same method. While the transfer of a physical commodity (a pen, a car, a machine)
implies that the original proprietor loses control of the object, nothing like that happens
when knowledge is acquired or transferred to others. In this sense, knowledge has the
key characteristic of a non-rival good in consumption.
But if someone has invested massively to develop the new method, the way oth-
ers acquire the knowledge becomes important. To ensure some form of remuneration,
the developer of the new method will want some way to exclude individuals who do not
pay to use the method (excludability).
The prospective purchaser of knowledge also has to face a market that is highly
imperfect. Not everyone will be willing to pay for knowledge whose usefulness has not
already been demonstrated. But once the knowledge is disclosed, there is no longer a
need to pay for it. There is an additional characteristic that differentiates knowledge
from other goods: there are no limits to duplication, but variable costs are zero or very
16 This chapter defines knowledge as the human capacity to understand and make sense of
external reality and technology as the application of knowledge to practical purposes. This dis-
tinction reflects, in terms of stocks rather than flows, the old Schumpeterian insight about the
difference between invention (which does not necessarily have an economic impact) and inno-
vation (which is the application of new ideas and designs to new products and processes). Sci-
ence and technology are defined as the overall activities carried out by public and business ac-
tors inside and outside designated institutions. The most formalized part of science and
technology is classified as scientific research and experimental development, and statistical evi-
dence is regularly collected by national and international organizations.
There are other reasons why it is difficult to apply the standard framework of pure pub-
lic goods to technology. Even if the producers of a technology are willing to make the
knowledge entirely non-rival and are prepared to distribute it freely, not everyone will
be able to acquire it and benefit from it. The costs of imitating and acquiring the same
expertise can be higher for some people than for others (Mansfield, Schwartz and
Wagner 1981). Typical public goods, such as security and clean air, assume that the
economic agent does not have to make any additional effort to take advantage of them.
That is not the case with technology: even when producers of knowledge have the best
intentions of transferring their expertise, the economic agent has to invest time, efforts
and resources to acquire it—and even that may not be enough.
The literature on technology transfer from developed to developing countries
has convincingly shown that technology transfer, like the generation of new knowledge,
is an uncertain activity with successes and failures (Bell and Pavitt 1997; Lall 2001).
Technology cannot be equated with information (Pavitt 1987). Callon (1994) intro-
duced the relevant difference between knowledge and technology that is freely available
(not protected by legal or technical devices) and that can be used without incurring costs
Knowledge is so crucial for welfare and its public good characteristics are so peculiar
that public players have always taken an active role in its promotion and distribution.
To reward the producers of good ideas, to increase the investment in knowledge and to
induce inventors to reveal their discoveries, public policies and regulations are in place
in industrialized countries. Knowledge provides positive externalities that can potentially
benefit the whole community. From this springs the notion that it is in the interest of
the community to have public policies to foster knowledge. Governments have pro-
moted knowledge to win wars, to increase security, to safeguard public health, to ex-
plore the universe, to improve communications and to advance education and learning.
Public intervention and regulation has taken various forms. It can be subdivided into
four broad areas:
• In-house investment. The government develops knowledge through publicly funded
institutions such as research centres (examples are the National Aeronautics and
Space Administration and the European Organization for Nuclear Research) and
universities. This includes the training of qualified people under the assumption
that they will become a “creative class”. In principle, the results of government-
funded and performed research are in the public domain and freely available.
• Procurement. The government contracts with the business sector to develop the
knowledge it needs, whether embodied in final products or entirely disembodied.
In the first case, the government purchases products (for example, an aircraft with
given specifications) and the executing firm is required to develop the necessary
knowledge to build them. In the second case, the government asks the business sec-
tor to develop new disembodied knowledge (for example, the prototype of a new
vaccine). The government generally holds the property rights, although contracting
LESSONS ON APPROPRIABILITY
The current system of intellectual property rights is designed to treat all cases uniformly.
Thus, the length of patents is the same, whether an invention is a radical or a simple
refinement of previous inventions, and all scientific and technological fields are treated
the same, regardless of their significance for economic development and human wel-
fare.
It may well be too complex to design a system of intellectual property rights that
differentiates protection according to the significance of an invention. And it is also true
that the current system assumes that the economy will be able to provide some differen-
tiation of rewards, so that a significant invention will become successful and provide
substantial returns to its inventor, while inconsequential inventions may not be imple-
mented at all. And, in cases of controversies, it is left to the courts to assess compensa-
tion for infringement, which is proportional to the damage incurred.
17 In the United States the copyright to “Happy Birthday to You” will expire in 2030 (Gorman
2005).
Developed countries, with many potential inno- For middle-income countries with high imitative
vators, have tended to opt for relatively strong capacity, the evidence suggests that strengthen-
intellectual property rights systems, with the aim ing intellectual property rights has no effect on
of encouraging inventive and creative activities, growth overall. In combination with the evidence
which are seen as an important source of long-run that a stronger intellectual property rights regime
economic growth. In most developing countries, encourages technology diffusion through higher
however, genuinely innovative activities are lim- trade flows and increased foreign patenting, it
ited, and the majority provide only weak intellec- would appear that the gains to growth from higher
tual property rights protection, if any, as a way of technology diffusion are simply offsetting the
allowing the rapid diffusion of knowledge. For growth-enhancing benefits obtained from the imi-
many of these countries, imitation is an important tation now precluded by the stronger intellectual
source of technological development, and provid- property rights regime. These are countries whose
ing stronger intellectual property protection is intellectual property rights regimes will need to be
seen as shifting profits from domestic imitative strengthened to meet the TRIPS standards. For
firms to foreign firms and reducing output in the them the policy focus should be to encourage
domestic economy rather than encouraging do- domestic firms to shift from imitation to innovation
mestic innovative activity (Deardoff 1992). The and to facilitate other activities with growth-
counterargument is that stronger intellectual prop- enhancing technology spillovers.
erty protection can reward creativity and risk- For poor countries some evidence suggests that
taking even in developing economies, with coun- strengthening intellectual property rights encour-
tries that retain weak intellectual property protec- ages growth, but research sheds little light on the
tion remaining dependent on dynamically ineffi- channels through which this occurs. Stronger
cient firms that rely on counterfeiting and imitation. intellectual property rights appear to have no ef-
The Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of In- fect on domestic innovation. Moreover, the impact
tellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) was estab- of stronger intellectual property rights on the vari-
lished during the Uruguay Round of trade negotia- ous channels of technology diffusion for these
tions to strengthen the international intellectual countries is found to be ambiguous. But these
property rights regime. The first comprehensive countries will need to strengthen their intellectual
and global set of rules covering intellectual prop- property rights regimes to meet the TRIPS stan-
erty rights protection, TRIPS specifies minimum dards. Some of these countries may be con-
standards that should be attained by a designated cerned that TRIPS will inhibit their firms from
time. TRIPS covers copyrights and related rights, passing through the imitative stage that seems to
trademarks, geographical indications, industrial be the precursor to innovative capability in rela-
designs, patents, the layout designs of integrated tively high-technology industries. The TRIPS obli-
circuits and undisclosed information, including gations may make WTO membership less attrac-
trade secrets and test data. tive for countries with imitative aspirations.
spillovers through inward FDI, at the economy- • Intellectual property rights–related policies.
wide, industry or firm level. Policies related to patent fees, the scope of
A further important source of technology transfer patentability and the novelty requirement in
for some countries is likely to be foreign patenting, patents can all contribute to the develop-
with a country’s market size potentially being im- ment of a domestic innovative sector and to
portant in determining whether increased foreign the international diffusion of knowledge.
patenting encourages or inhibits growth. The evi- Fees for patent applications and renewal of
dence suggests that increased foreign patenting patents and trademarks can be set to pro-
has a negative effect on growth in small countries, mote innovation and diffusion. Developing
a positive effect in middle-size countries and no countries can limit the scope of subject mat-
effect in larger countries. When attention is re- ter that can be patented and encourage
stricted to developing countries, foreign patenting rapid publication of patent applications, al-
has a positive effect on growth at high levels of lowing domestic firms to invent around the
intellectual property rights protection, high levels patent. Countries can set high standards for
of economic development, for relatively open the novelty requirements of patents, to pre-
economies and relatively large markets. This is vent routine discoveries from being pat-
consistent with the broad conclusions of the litera- ented.
ture that stronger intellectual property protection
• Technology diffusion. For most developing could establish trust funds to finance the training
countries, improved technologies will be im- of scientific and technical personnel to facilitate
ported. International technology transfer oc- the transfer of technologies that are particularly
curs through imports, FDI, licensing and important in the provision of public goods and to
communication and transport and maintain- Maskus (2004) argues that multilateral organiza-
ing macroeconomic stability, along with tions, particularly the World Trade Organization
open trade and investment policies, can en- (WTO), could increase the scope for monitoring
courage such flows, allowing countries im- developed country efforts in the transfer of tech-
proved access to foreign technology. nology and could add an evaluative mechanism
for the effectiveness and extent of technology
Role of multilateral organizations
transferred. Hoekman, Maskus and Saggi (2004)
Multilateral organizations can assist developing argue that the most powerful indirect incentive for
countries in meeting the terms of TRIPS and ob- technology transfer is for developed countries to
taining the maximum benefit from it. grant significant market access for products in
Maskus (2004) argues that capacity building in which poor countries have a comparative advan-
intellectual property rights should focus less on tage. Multilateral organizations, particularly the
the specification of protective laws and regulations WTO, have an obvious role to play here.
and more on the technical, judicial and legal ex- Source: Drawn from a background paper by
pertise underlying effective technology transfer. Falvey and Foster (2005).
Multilateral organizations can facilitate research
on the economic effects of intellectual property
There is widespread recognition that nations are so strongly interlinked that both the
benefits and the problems associated with technological change are also interrelated.
Major scientific and technological breakthroughs have an impact beyond the borders of
the state that produces the knowledge. Likewise, human problems that require the gen-
eration of new scientific and technological competencies are not confined to the coun-
try where they originate. Health, environment, communications, mobility and safety all
require the development of new knowledge that can potentially provide global benefits.
How do public and business players address these issues?
PUBLIC INSTITUTIONS
Public funding of research and education is grounded in the notion that these will de-
liver some advantages to the community. The advantages can be instrumental (defence,
environment, medical research) or contributions to the general advancement of knowl-
edge (astronomy, archaeology, basic research). In all cases, the government is commit-
ting public resources and so must be able to account for the benefits provided. The na-
ture of knowledge, however, makes it very difficult to single out a community of
beneficiaries. The citizens of any state benefit from knowledge that has been generated
18 While the number of publications generated by researchers in the business sector is increas-
ing, the bulk of publications are still the outcome of publicly funded research. And researchers
and engineers working in industry tend to publish their results in academic journals when they
are not looking for proprietary claims to the knowledge disclosed.
19 http://lysander.sourceoecd.org/vl=1798u729/cl=ig/nw=1/rpsv/scoreboard/a03.htm
INTERNATIONAL ORGANIZATIONS
All the considerations above show that both government and business players contrib-
ute to the international provision of knowledge, despite the fact that actions are con-
tinuous and relatively weak. The nature of knowledge allows some of its components to
be distributed as international public goods even in the absence of purpose-designed
institutions: governments may supply the good globally even when that is not their main
motivation, and corporations may do so even against their wishes. But because firms
tend to retain exclusive use of their knowledge, and governments are not necessarily
keen to share it with foreigners, the generation and distribution of knowledge are not
socially optimal.
The current controversy in the international regime of intellectual property rights, espe-
cially TRIPS, shows that the business interests in the international diffusion of knowl-
edge are rather different from the public ones. Nonetheless, many developed country
governments follow a two-way track: they protect the interests of their own national
Investing in knowledge provides enormous advantages for economic and social devel-
opment. In the long run, advantages will probably repay the costs and will be distributed
internationally and across generations.
But this long run is often too long, especially for the millions of people whose
hardships can be alleviated by technological knowledge already available or nearly avail-
able. The increasing interdependence of societies, the difficulty of retaining the results
of knowledge within national borders and the emergence of global challenges in fields
such as health, security and environment demonstrate the need for a strategy of global
governance that promotes increased coordination among national efforts and an en-
hanced role for international organizations that are dedicated to knowledge generation
and dissemination. Currently, most research activities are planned and implemented at
the national level without international coordination, even within the restricted club of
the most technologically advanced countries. Radical changes in policy attitudes will be
needed to foster investment in knowledge as an international public good.
This chapter has highlighted some of the special characteristics of knowledge as
a public good. Knowledge can be considered a pure public good since it is non-rival in
consumption and is often not excludable. But the generation of knowledge will not nec-
essarily benefit economic and social development unless it is actually put to use through
technological applications. Public policy should therefore focus not only on the produc-
tion of knowledge, but also on its distribution (see viewpoint 4.2 on creating and dis-
seminating knowledge).
First, the fact that profit-seeking agents finance, create and use a substantial
amount of knowledge implies that it is often made excludable through industrial se-
crecy, access codes or intellectual property legislation. These barriers can be lowered or
even removed through appropriate incentives. Public policy should resolve the di-
lemma of static and dynamic advantages of intellectual property rights: in the short run,
weakening intellectual property rights might increase the amount of freely available
knowledge, but in the long run it might reduce incentives to invest in knowledge, at least
the part financed by profit-seeking business.
Over the last 20 years, the proportion of business-funded R&D has increased,
while publicly funded R&D has remained stagnant or even declined. There is no evi-
dence that the growth of business funded R&D has occurred at the expense of the pub-
lic component. But to increase the amount of freely accessible knowledge will require a
greater financial effort from public sources. Reform of the system of business incentives
might also be effective. This could include incentives for the diffusion of innovations as
well as for the protection of innovation. Greater efforts at the regional level would also
be valuable (see viewpoint 4.3)
Second, freely accessible knowledge becomes useful only when prospective us-
ers have the necessary absorptive capacity (Abramovitz 1989; Bell and Pavitt 1997).
This has major implications for an international technology transfer strategy. Building
absorptive capacity requires time and investment: infrastructures, education, training
and R&D labs are needed to assimilate and take advantage of the existing stock of
knowledge. The policy implication is that concentrating on the supply side without tak-
ing the absorptive capacity of recipient agents (individuals, firms and even nations) into
account could lead to a waste of resources.
The gap between developing and developed increase in current aid budgets—if the aid were
countries in their formal ability to produce knowl- used more effectively, with a greater focus on the
edge (and in the actual production of knowledge) transfer of knowledge and the strengthening of
is larger than the gap in incomes per capita. The domestic knowledge capabilities, and were di-
good news is that the gaps in connectivity are not rected towards developing new international pub-
as great and are narrowing, at least in terms of lic good knowledge addressing some of the most
basic access. The best news is that the gaps in devastating problems developing countries face.
education are even smaller and are narrowing
even faster. Creating new international public goods
• While the average per capita income of the knowledge
high-income countries is 65 times that of the
There is ample scope for increasing the produc-
low-income countries and growing, the dif-
tion of international public good knowledge in
ference in research and development (R&D)
specific areas where there are good expectations
expenditure is estimated at 94 times greater
of high social returns. A recent analysis of 292
in high-income countries.
published studies shows that the median social
• The difference in the production of basic return to agricultural research was 48% a year
knowledge as measured by output in scien- and that the average return was 100%. For agri-
tific and journal articles is 42 times greater in cultural extension services the medium returns
high-income countries than in low-income were 63% and the average returns were 85%
countries. However, the difference in the (Barton 2004a in Alston et al. 2000). For medical
production and sale of commercially rele- research there have been fewer cost-benefit stud-
vant knowledge (as measured by royalties ies. However, there are some dramatic examples
and licensing fees) is much larger, probably of spectacular rates of return in some areas of
about 200 times greater. preventive medicine.
• The difference in phone connectivity and One way to subsidize the production of this
Internet users per thousand persons is just knowledge is to mobilize global funds, as was
23 times higher for high-income countries done to fund the green revolution. Initiatives along
and has been falling. But the number of these lines include the Global Environmental Fund
computers per thousand people is still 68 and extensions of the work of the Consultative
times higher. In education, as measured by Group on International Agricultural Research in
enrolment rates, the difference is just 2.3 tropical agriculture.
times greater for secondary education and
Another way is to use demand-pull mecha-
6.6 times greater for higher education in
nisms. These involve a commitment to purchase a
high-income countries. This difference has
new product, such as a new effective AIDS vac-
been narrowing over the past 10 years (the
cine, provided it is developed to certain perform-
differences were 2.7 times greater for sec-
ance parameters. A good example is the proposal
ondary education and 9.4 times greater for
to encourage R&D on an AIDS vaccine by com-
higher education).
mitments to purchase the vaccine once it is de-
The greater provision of global public goods, veloped. Variants of demand-pull are government
and of knowledge in particular, can help redress procurement contracts or prizes for the develop-
some of the growing inequality and tensions. ment of new technology.
While it is difficult to estimate the precise costs, it
Other mechanisms include building research
is clear that there is tremendous potential to in-
consortia among potential public developers or
crease the welfare of the developing world by
even among public and private developers who
making a concerted effort to provide knowledge
are working or could be convinced to work to-
as an international public good. It could also be
gether on some of the needs of developing coun-
argued that this could be achieved without much
tries. Potential problems would be coordination
Improving development policy knowledge as ing technology more fully to prevent and treat
opposed to specific technical or organizational HIV/AIDS and malaria would be among the most
knowledge also requires support of an interna- economically desirable and cost-effective inter-
tional public goods type. The rapid rate of in- ventions in developing countries (Barton 2004a
crease and dissemination of knowledge, and the citing Mills and Shillcutt 2004; the ranking of inter-
increase in globalization, are opening up some ventions in several sectors can be seen at
longer good enough to advise countries to follow ally, raising average local productivity across all
the historical patterns of developed countries, for sectors of a developing economy to the average
panies, non-governmental organizations and na- ternational institutions can play an important role
tional and local governments in developed and in collecting and distilling existing knowledge, and
developing countries all have a role here. improving access. At a basic level this means
making the information available. One example is
A third possibility is to reverse or even reduce
the Development Gateway, which uses the power
the strong drive towards intellectual property
of information and telecommunications technology
rights. There is some recognition that regimes
to provide a gateway to development knowl-
established as part of the Trade-Related Aspects
edge—including technical, organizational and
of Intellectual Property Rights Agreement may be
managerial, and policy knowledge. Other organi-
too onerous for the least developed countries.
zations, such as the United Nations Industrial
There is also some concern that the tendency
Development Organization and World Health Or-
towards the privatization of knowledge is harmful
ganization, have also developed websites to dis-
even for developed countries.
seminate existing knowledge.
This is clearly a contentious area. However, to
The problem is not only what information is
the extent that intellectual property rights regimes
available, but what it is relevant for, how to access
are made less strict and less binding, more
it and how to use it. This usually requires distilling
knowledge will be in the public domain and more
the knowledge to its essentials and providing a
will be available to transfer. The drawback is that
mechanism to facilitate its transfer. Even when
there may be a disincentive to initiatives to create
knowledge is in the private domain, it is still useful
new knowledge. Although this has been argued
to know what knowledge exists, what it can do
by many on theoretical grounds, there have been
and what it would cost to get access to it. In addi-
no clear empirical studies confirming this expecta-
tion, international organizations could buy up the
tion. The issue of the most appropriate intellectual
rights to relevant patents and then transfer the
property rights regime from a global perspective,
knowledge as part of development projects or as
rather than a narrow national perspective, de-
part of regular business.
serves further research. This is particularly impor-
tant now that the production and dissemination of
Supporting the development of domestic ca-
knowledge are increasingly global rather than
pacity for effective use
national.
The inability to use knowledge locally is proba-
Disseminating knowledge bly the most serious problem in knowledge trans-
fer. Overcoming this problem requires local institu-
Disseminating existing knowledge to meet the
tions, education and skills. International
needs of developing countries is probably more
institutions can help establish or strengthen the
important than creating new technical or policy
relevant institutions, providing technical assis-
cies are well placed to contribute to these efforts, Much more needs to be done to address asym-
to lead a major advocacy drive for knowledge for metries in global governance structures, which
economic development by getting governments constrain the opportunities for developing coun-
and especially the private sector to do more in this tries to benefit in an increasingly competitive in-
area. They can use their convening power to raise ternational system. This links with the other ele-
awareness of the problems and to illustrate what ments of this project on international public goods,
kinds of actions are working. including the trade system, the financial system
The UN agencies could also provide more sys- and the management of natural resources and the
of the economic development challenge and co- Source: Drawn from a background paper by
ordinate the actions of the many international Dahlman (2005).
players. These efforts could be structured around
six key actions:
Ideas and knowledge have always been impor- as a patent application, to release intellectual
tant to production and growth, but today their con- property rights by licensing, trade sale or forma-
tribution as formalized ideas and knowledge within tion of a spinout company. These three types of
production is central to the knowledge economy, knowledge integration are fundamental to an in-
where increasing amounts of production are posi- creasing amount of what is called “open innova-
tioned. Regional innovation systems are both a tion” and offer opportunities to innovative develop-
useful framework for studying economic and inno- ing country firms. Other examination knowledge
vative performance and functional tools for en- opportunities arise through clinical trials and pa-
hancing the innovation processes of firms. They tient testing of candidate products.
do this by knitting together knowledge flows and Incubation is extremely important in nurturing
the systems on which they rely, building trust and new businesses, in technology as in other sectors.
confidence in institutional reliability, and generat- Funding programmes may be influenced at the
ing institutional self-knowledge and collective dis- idea stage by multilateral assistance organi-
satisfaction with the status quo. A regional innova- zations, but if there is inadequate follow-up by
tion system comprises a set of public and private private or public programmes, new businesses
institutions that produces pervasive and systemic are likely to be stillborn. Even when there is a
effects to encourage firms within the region to relatively generous national funding programme
adopt common norms, expectations, values, atti- for incubators and associated infrastructure, with-
tudes and practices that nurture a culture of inno- out seed-funding for new businesses, such pro-
vation and enhance knowledge transfer proc- grammes are likely to be ineffective. Thus there
esses. A national system of innovation cannot should be appropriate multilevel governance of
adequately do this. incubator programmes with pump-priming from
Lessons from successful innovation support multilateral external assistance organizations.
services Then infrastructure on a scale beyond the re-
sources of regions should be supplied by national
Regional innovation systems are a powerful in-
programmes. Finally seed-funding must be estab-
strument for accelerating economic growth. In line
lished at regional, municipal and local levels
with new economic growth theory, they rest fun-
through associative public-private partnerships.
damentally on the notion of public goods provi-
sion, where market failure to support innovation is Innovation support is fundamentally a public
evident. They encourage collective entrepreneur- goods activity justified by a general failure of the
ship; exploit social capital advantages where market to come forward and anticipate a rate of
these exist and build networks where they do not; return on capital investment in incubator facilities.
and provide specialist, small-scale enterprise and There is virtually absolute market failure in the
innovation support services, regional financing provision of necessary finance for incubatee firms
and investment vehicles and labour market ad- in many cases, although some systems have per-
justment services. Producing innovation creates a formed better than others (Brazil, for example). A
three-way relationship of innovation, entrepre- case in which innovation advantage was systemi-
neurship and talent formation interacting system- cally constructed by linking excellent science and
atically over time, evolving as local and global technology (talent) to entrepreneurship (incuba-
conditions dictate. tion) and innovation (financing) in the absence of
both entrepreneurship and innovation resources is
Innovation is the commercialization of new
that of Israel. Moreover, Israel shows that public
knowledge. Knowledge may be generated inside
goods may be in advance of market thinking in the
a firm or a public goods organization practising
provision of systemically interacting innovation
“open science”, such as a university or major pub-
support, but that public goods may transform into
lic research institute. Exploitation of the discovery
private goods once a profitable return on invest-
or invention generally follows an intensive period
ment can be envisaged or demonstrated. The
of the application of examination knowledge, such
Knowledge exploration institutes may adapt to a neurship. Science policy ministries must interact
systemic innovation posture at the regional level positively with ministries of industry and employ-
in part by retraining management and research- ment to recognize the strains involved in organiza-
ers, engaging in public goods strategies of sub- tional transformation—and to avoid wasteful du-
national institutions or opening and recruiting new plication. The necessity for academic
and may be extremely important in any restructur- ment ministries to ensure that transformation of
ing to face mounting competition from China. research cultures towards market opportunities is
Spain’s ceramics cluster, by contrast, has defi- thoughtful and well planned. Policy-related fund-
ciencies in this aspect but strengths in the science ing for infrastructure and pump-priming (early
of ceramics. A forum and consensus approach stage stimulation by seed-funding to get initiatives
towards change in complex and unstable competi- going) is also key. Financing for incubation and
tive environments may be an advantage of con- seed-funding are best conducted at the regional
siderable value for correctly balancing the skills level with local fine-tuning regarding talent and
mix from the labour market. skills formation and the building of strong multi-
level interactions. Regional funding of specific
Business and industry associations can serve
initiatives for venture capital, entrepreneurship
their overall membership better when they are
and skills adaptation is also appropriate, as is
confederated or consolidated with one voice than
cofunding such activities with the private sector
when they are fragmented. In the case of suc-
wherever possible.
cessful real services units or centres, tailored to
meet customer and member needs, the absence Source: Drawn from a background paper by
of basic scientific research in the cluster may not Cooke (2005).
.
Since the amount of public expenditure devoted to R&D for global issues is likely to be
limited, a crucial aspect will be to identify to which fields of knowledge generation to
direct the investments. Can an international public good framework provide guidelines?
The fields considered important by broad agreement are usually those that are mutually
advantageous for current and future generations and that are less likely to be associated
with sectors where trade rivalry exists. Astronomy, space, theoretical physics, environ-
ment and health are ideal candidates and, not surprisingly, areas where active collabora-
tion and even permanent international research centres have already been established.
Despite an increase in cooperative international public programmes, the bulk of the
funding continues to be national in scope. How should the fields be selected?
Human necessities differ across geographical areas. Consider health research.
Poor countries undertake a tiny fraction of world health R&D, although they bear 90%
of the total disease burden (10/90 gap; see Global Forum for Health Research 2004).
The countries that carry out the other 90% of health R&D might have very different
priorities since many of the diseases affecting developing countries have already been
eradicated in developed countries.
A typical case is scientific research on vaccines. Knowledge leading to the identi-
fication of successful vaccines is very close to a pure international public good: vaccines
are costly to invent, but can be produced and transmitted at rather low cost,21 and they
can provide benefits globally and across generations. (There is an intergenerational ad-
vantage if the vaccines are available to future generations or if the disease is eradicated.)
A successful World Health Organization programme on smallpox eradication has gen-
erated advantages for both developed and developing countries (see Fenner et al.
1988). For example, it is estimated that the United States recovers its own share of in-
vestment for smallpox eradication every 26 days (Tenkorang and Conceição 2003).
With appropriate investment, vaccines can be developed for some of the major
fatal illnesses of our age, such as malaria, tuberculosis and AIDS. These three diseases
are responsible for some 5 million deaths a year. It has been estimated that an invest-
ment of $1.5 billion a year for 15 years could lead to the development of effective vac-
cines (Archibugi and Bizzarri 2004). Yet R&D investments are negligible, at $55 million
(malaria), $150 million (tuberculosis) and $400 million (AIDS) (Archibugi and Bizzarri
2004). The relatively higher investment in vaccines for AIDS is due to the fact that this
disease is a top priority for developed countries, while malaria and tuberculosis are not
a major concern because they have been largely eradicated.22 It is significant, however,
how that globalization is changing the outlook of developed countries as well: inward
migration is bringing tuberculosis back, and outward tourism is exposing people to ma-
laria. And now there is a risk of avian influenza. Vaccines are therefore an area in which
both developed and developing countries will have an advantage and an interest in in-
E
conomic activity can put pressure on ecosystems and degrade environmental
quality. Some environmental problems are global, making cooperation among
countries essential for dealing with them. Some national problems also result
from economic activities abroad. That is why an outlook broader than national is re-
quired.
This chapter reviews the relationship between the environment and develop-
ment and focuses on the environment as an international public good. It examines the
current institutional framework for tackling environmental problems and uses the limi-
tation of ozone-depleting substances (Montreal Protocol) and the mitigation of global
climate change (Kyoto Protocol) to illustrate the challenges of international provision of
environmental public goods. The chapter concludes with proposals for managing their
provision.
Green growth seeks to harmonize economic growth and environmental sustainability by pro-
moting “fundamental changes in the way societies produce and consume” (ESCAP 2006). It
calls for new concepts and systems to de-link economic growth and environmental degrada-
tion.
Green growth focuses on demand-side management and on the promotion of environmentally
sustainable decisions through market, economic and fiscal systems. Ecotaxes and other eco-
nomic instruments are recommended as a means of influencing decision-making for greater
environment sustainability at the individual, firm, community and government levels (see
viewpoint 5.1 for an example of an ecotax and viewpoint 5.2 on eco-effectiveness).
Source: ESCAP 2006.
By 2025 both China and India will be very large has a great interest in the character of expan-
economies. Estimates predict that China’s gross sion in these countries in the next two decades.
world product will be 7.6% (up from 3.5%) and In- Worldwide agreement on national greenhouse
dia’s 2.7% (up from 1.5%). Many Chinese and Indi- gas emission targets that are strong enough to
ans under the age of 50 in 2025 will have grown up limit growth in atmospheric carbon dioxide con-
in a period of rapid economic growth and increasing centrations is likely impossible, at least for sev-
prosperity, and the middle classes of both countries eral decades to come. It is hard to imagine an
will have grown enormously. effective formula for national targets that will be
Rapid growth and increased GDP imply a rising acceptable both to developed countries, such as
demand for energy, especially electricity. China and the United States, and to developing countries
India are both well endowed with coal, which is with aspirations for rapid growth, such as China
especially relevant for climate change, but both are and India (Cooper 2001). The targets of the
short of oil relative to their prospective needs. By Kyoto Protocol are keyed to a base year, 1990,
2025, China’s demand for oil will be more than twice which is unappealing to countries that desire
Japan’s and India’s will approach Japan’s. and expect rapid economic growth.
China is already the largest consumer of coal, ac- Another approach is needed if human sources
counting for a quarter of the world’s total, and its of climate change are to be addressed seriously.
use is expected to grow rapidly despite vigorous A leading alternative approach is to focus on
programs for introducing nuclear and hydropower concrete national commitments to action rather
and for importing liquefied natural gas. India ac- than on emission targets. One such action to
counts for about 7% of current world coal consump- deal with negative externalities from human
tion and its use of coal is also expected to grow action, favoured by many economists, is to tax
significantly, though less dramatically than it will in the offending activity. The idea would be to tax
China. carbon dioxide emissions from major sources
World carbon dioxide emissions are projected to around the world, particularly the burning of
increase 1.9% a year to 2025 (on the assumption of coal, oil and natural gas and the making of ce-
world economic growth of 3.0% a year). China’s ment, unless the carbon dioxide released from
carbon dioxide emissions are projected to grow such processes is prevented from entering the
3.3% a year, the highest rate in the world among atmosphere through sequestration. The even-
large countries or regions, with Brazil (3.1%) and tual rate of the tax would be calibrated to the
India (2.9%) not far behind. China’s share of world desired reduction in carbon dioxide emissions,
carbon dioxide emissions will increase from an al- although the initially agreed tax should be at a
ready significant 12% in 2000 to 18% in 2025, ex- level sufficient to attract serious attention to tax-
ceeding that of Western Europe by 2010 and rapidly avoiding emissions reduction.
approaching the US share of 22% in 2025. India’s The attraction of a carbon dioxide tax to China
share will reach 5%, making it the fourth largest and India would rest less in its contribution to
national emitter after Russia and putting it well avoiding climate change than in its contribution
ahead of Japan. China’s projected growth in emis- to reducing air pollution, which derives heavily
sions of 3.8 billion metric tons by 2025 far exceeds from burning coal and increasingly from automo-
the US projected growth of 2.4 billion tons, and tive emissions in the larger cities. Above all, a
India’s projected growth far exceeds Japan’s. In tax would be attractive as a source of revenue,
view of these trends, the problem of greenhouse greatly needed by the central governments of
gas emissions cannot be seriously addressed with- both countries. China and India are unlikely to
out engaging cooperation from China, India, Brazil impose stiff carbon taxes on their own, because
and other rapidly growing economies. The world of concerns about loss of international competi-
A uniform incremental tax on the major sources of countries could be granted a longer period of
carbon dioxide emissions would introduce an incen- time to introduce the tax.
tive, worldwide, to reduce carbon emissions. Re- Mitigating climate change will require the ac-
sponses to the tax would of course differ from coun- tive participation of rapidly growing energy-using
try to country. Where emissions can be reduced at a countries such as China and India. A target-
cost lower than the tax, reductions can be expected. based regime such as the Kyoto Protocol will
Where the cost of reducing emissions exceeds the not appeal to them. A regime based on common
tax, the tax will be paid. In either case the cost of action, such as imposition of a worldwide carbon
fossil fuels will be raised everywhere, proportional to tax, could have that appeal, mainly for the reve-
their carbon content, as they should be if emissions nue it would provide without any loss of interna-
are to be reduced. A uniform tax is economically tional competitiveness.
efficient, in that reductions will be greatest where Source: Cooper 2005.
the cost of such reductions is least. A universal tax
will also avoid geographic relocation of industries to
evade the tax—a potential weakness of the Kyoto
Protocol, with its limited geographic coverage.
“Efficiency is doing things right; effectiveness is nese are blended in the recycling process, their
doing the right things.” discrete value is lost forever, and creating new
Peter F. Drucker (2002) stockpiles is extremely costly, both economically
The principle of ecoefficiency promotes reducing, and ecologically.
minimizing and limiting the size of ecological foot- Ecoefficiency as a negative approach
prints. More specifically, ecoefficiency strategies
In the short-term, ecoefficiency strategies
focus on maintaining or increasing the value of eco-
have the potential for tangible reductions in the
nomic output while simultaneously decreasing the
ecological impact of industrial activities and pro-
impact of economic activity upon ecological systems
vide opportunities for significant cost reductions.
(Verfaillie and Bidwell 2000). Environmental sus-
But such strategies are insufficient for achieving
tainability, based on the principle of ecoefficiency,
economic and environmental objectives in the
has become a leading issue in economic develop-
long-term. Although ecoefficiency reduces re-
ment. The ultimate aim is maximization of economic
source consumption and pollution and may pro-
value with minimal ecological impact.
vide temporary economic advantages, it lacks
Ecoefficiency begins with the assumption of a lin- the long-term vision for establishing a truly posi-
ear flow of materials through industrial systems: raw tive relationship between industrial activity and
materials are extracted from the environment, trans- nature. Ecoefficiency strategies tend to address
formed into products, utilized, and eventually dis- the symptoms rather than the causes of ecologi-
posed of. Ecoefficiency approaches then seek to cal problems by setting goals and using prac-
minimize the volume, velocity and toxicity of this tices that sustain an unappealing compromise
“cradle-to-grave” dynamic, but at all levels of deci- between industry and the environment.
sion-making accept the ultimate and inevitable de-
Current corrective action programs are inher-
mise of materials as useful resources.
ently ecoefficient in that these programs seek
In the material realm, ecoefficiency can be said to quick fixes to improve the present situation.
encompass the concepts of dematerialization, in- However, decreasing the amount of extracted
creased resource productivity, reduced toxicity, raw materials and limiting the amount of toxic
increased recyclability (downcycling), extended emissions into the atmosphere do not solve the
product lifespan and cleaner production. Each of problem of pollution of the environment and
these strategies presupposes a system of produc- precious materials being wasted. These meth-
tion and consumption with a linear cradle-to-grave ods indirectly generate more problems because
flow of materials that inevitably transforms re- they establish a waste management practice
sources into waste. that is not beneficial to the relationship between
Strategies for toxicity reduction largely focus on economy and ecology. Moreover, legislation that
replacing the most hazardous materials with others provides incentives in this direction may hinder
that pose fewer problems to humans and ecological the development of new and healthier technolo-
systems throughout their lifespan or after disposal. gies, resulting in sub-optimal solutions.
Moreover, strategies for generating increased recy- Ecoeffective corrective action
clability and extended product lifespan seek to pro-
long the period until resources acquire the status of Typically, biodiversity is much higher in devel-
waste, for instance by increasing product durability oping economies than in highly developed
or reprocessing post-use material for use in lower economies. In this context, traditional economic
value applications. Though recycling strategies growth always means damage to the environ-
begin to approach ecoeffectiveness, the large ma- ment and loss of biodiversity.
jority of recycling actually constitutes downcycling The concept of ecoeffectiveness offers a posi-
because the recycling process reduces the quality tive alternative to traditional ecoefficiency ap-
of materials, making them suitable for use only in proaches, as it aims for the development of en-
lower value applications. Their lifespan has been vironmentally benign products and systems. In
prolonged, but their status as resources has not contrast to approaches of minimization and de-
been maintained. For example, when plastics get materialization, the concept of ecoeffectiveness
recycled into countertops, valuable materials are involves the transformation of products and as-
mixed and cannot be recycled again. From the sociated material flows in such a way that these
same perspective, mixing metals dilutes their value form a supportive relationship with ecological
and increases their ecological impact. When rare systems and future economic growth. The prin-
and valuable metals like copper, nickel and manga- cipal goal is not to minimize or delay the cradle-
Box 5.2. The role of international organizations in the provision of environmental pub-
lic goods
The United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), in its 2006 Annual Report Global
Partnership for Development, provides clear examples of international organizations enhanc-
ing the provision of environmental public goods in partnership with local governments and the
private sector and local communities.
For example, in Moldova the UNDP is helping to empower communities economically through
its Agenda 21 initiative. By involving citizens in decision-making and promoting public-private
partnerships, this effort integrates sustainable development principles into local authority poli-
cies.
Some small-scale projects can deliver big results. In Gaza projects funded by grants from the
Global Environment Facility helped women fruit producers acquire solar-powered machines to
dry fruits and herbs more quickly and efficiently. This environment-friendly initiative has en-
abled the women to expand their businesses and sell their produce in local markets.
UNIDO is supporting small and medium enterprises in their efforts to incorporate environ-
mental considerations in their products and production processes through building business
partnerships with large and small companies. It is cooperating with BASF, a transnational
chemical corporation, on a UN Global Compact project to establish a comprehensive eco-
efficiency analysis tool for small companies in developing countries, to be applied through the
network of National Cleaner Production Centres (viewpoint 5.3). Morocco has agreed to par-
ticipate in a pilot phase to test a customized version of the tool. If the tool proves useful, it will
be made available to small companies in more than 20 developing countries (UNIDO 2002a).
International organizations can also help governments strengthen regional cooperation on
environmental issues. For instance, UNDP established the Transboundary River Basin Initia-
tive, a platform for dialogue and consensus building for countries that share the same water
resources. In another example of regional cooperation supported by international organiza-
tions, UNIDO has been selected by the Multilateral Fund for the Implementation of the Mont-
real Protocol as the implementing agency for an investment project to assist the Chinese
23 Sectors accounting for most global subsidies—agriculture, fisheries, transport and energy—are
also those with the largest emission of greenhouse gas and other forms of pollutants.
Cleaner Production is a holistic and integrated initially appeared. End-of-pipe technology has
method for dealing with environmental issues. It frequently simply shifted waste or pollutants
recognises that most of our environmental prob- from one environmental medium to another, as
lems—such as global warming, toxic pollution and with air- and water-pollution control devices that
loss of biodiversity—are caused by the way and rate produced concentrated hazardous waste for
at which we use natural resources for production. leaking landfills (UNIDO 2002c).
The approach questions the very need for natural In the mid-1980s recycling of waste and en-
resource consumption and looks for other ways to ergy recovery gained momentum. But recycling
satisfy that need. Clean production systems use has proved insufficient, as it often suffers from
less energy and fewer natural resources. Resources limited or unpredictable markets for its products
flow through the production-consumption cycle at (UNIDO 2004). Since the beginning of the
slower rates. The approach also deals with the 1990s, concepts such as Cleaner Production,
transformation of products and associated resource pollution prevention, waste minimization and
flows in such a way that these form a supportive ecoefficiency represent an intellectual shift away
relationship with ecological system and future eco- from the issue of what to do with pollution to the
nomic growth. The approach also acknowledges the issue of why pollution is generated and how it
need for public and private participation in political can be prevented. These concepts all comprise
and economic decision-making. attempts to maintain the same level of output
while using fewer inputs and producing less
Developments in environmental action
waste, improving the efficiency of natural re-
Industrial activity is of major importance to eco- sources use and reducing pollution (UNIDO
nomic development, but it is also a cause of envi- 2002c).
ronmental degradation and pollution. In the course
In 1998 UNEP issued the International Decla-
of time, industrialised nations have responded to
ration on Cleaner Production. The goals of the
environmental pollution and waste in five character-
Declaration are to encourage support for the
istic ways:
adoption of Cleaner Production activities, inten-
• By not recognizing—or ignoring—the problem sify the commitment of the various actors in-
of environmental pollution. volved, promote international cooperation and
• By diluting or dispersing pollution, so that its spread awareness of the concept. More than
effects are less harmful or apparent. 1,700 regional and national parties have now
• By seeking to control pollution and wastes (the signed the Declaration (UNEP 2001).
end-of-pipe or pollution control approach). At the national level, most developed and
• By trying to develop and improve environ- some developing countries have introduced
mental technology that will help close the loops in environmental and other policies, strategies and
material flow streams during the production process instruments to support the application of cleaner
and facilitate reuse and recycling. production, resource efficiency and waste mini-
mization measures, as well as renewable en-
• By implementing Cleaner Production through
ergy. However, enforcement of these policies
the prevention of pollution and waste generation.
has often been problematic, especially in devel-
Conventional pollution control approaches, using oping countries.
end-of-pipe measures (after-the-event “react and
At company level, either as a result of the in-
treat”), have been used to treat polluting substances
ternational context or because of changes in
and waste by such methods as neutralisation and
their business strategies, many transnational
evaporation at the end of the production process.
corporations, have made public commitments to
But the level of treatment has often been limited
the principles of pollution prevention or other
and solutions have proved less effective than they
environmental principles such as those included
mental management involves reducing the amount Cleaner Production programmes are posi-
of inputs (energy, water and raw materials) per pro- tioned at the intersection of the Millennium De-
duction unit, eliminating toxic raw materials, mini- velopment Goals of environmental sustainability
mising pollutants or waste throughout the entire and poverty reduction. Although sustainable
product life cycle and incorporating environmental development requires much more comprehen-
concerns into the design and delivery of services. It sive cultural changes within industry, govern-
is seen as a superior alternative to traditional pollu- ments and communities, Cleaner Production
tion control systems for minimising environmental and preventive environmental management may
problems, because it saves resource inputs and provide a first step towards sustainability
reduces waste. (UNIDO 2002c).
• Cost-saving through reduced wastage of raw tiveness of the way natural resources are being
Public goods related to the environment can be classified by their nature (pure or im-
pure) and their geographic scope (global or regional). Restoring and protecting the
ozone layer and curbing global warming are examples of pure public goods that follow
summation technology in their provision. These public goods are also looked at as a
subset of negative externalities, which the market fails to internalise (Memedovic, 2006).
Impure environmental public goods include club goods, whose benefits can be
excludable to a certain degree (international protection of ecosystems in national and
transnational parks, for example)—and commons, which involve partial rivalry in their
consumption (the preservation of river fishing activities and efforts to preserve the
Amazon region are examples) (Sandler 2001). Without sensible policies these com-
monly owned resources risk depletion from overuse, because individuals do not ac-
count for the crowding externality that their consumption imposes on others. At times
regulations may exacerbate the problem if they provide perverse incentives to exploit
the commons at an even faster rate. For example, past actions to limit the length of a
fishing season have led to investment in fishing vessels that can land a greater harvest in
less time (faster vessels equipped with sonar, for example). Other regulations to curb
fishing efficiency have resulted in wasteful cost.
The main difficulty with the provision of most environmental public goods is a
lack of information on individual preferences for the good’s use (Cline 2004a). These
externalities can be corrected through various instruments:
• Multilateral organizations and treaties are usually needed for dealing with the un-
derprovision of pure and impure environmental public goods, like protecting the
ozone layer and curbing global warming, which follow the summation aggregation
technology in their provision. Other instruments can also be used ranging from
market-based instruments, to support for research development and to voluntary
mechanism. Market-based instruments are designed to include external implications
of an agent’s action in his decision-making. Possible means of market internalization
are a corrective tax (for negative externalities), or subsidy (for positive externalities)
(Azqueta and Ferreiro 1993; Sandler 2004b: 71).24
• Another market-based corrective instrument is assigning property rights to agents in
the bargaining process to maximise welfare. Quotas can be introduced allowing for
limited activity, which is consistent with the social optimum. Quotas can take the
form of permits that impose extra costs (such as pollution permits) and can be
traded. Pseudo markets for trading pollution permits, similar to the emissions trad-
ing scheme initiated under the Kyoto Protocol on Climate Change, could reduce
pollution and ensure a more efficient and fairer allocation (Sandor, Bettelheimand
and Swingland 2002).
• Support for research and development and for innovation is important for the de-
velopment of new long-term options and for the shift to a low-carbon economy. For
developing countries, this also assumes capacity building programmes in specific
science, engineering and technology areas and thus greater international coopera-
tion and collaboration.
For an overview of instruments used for promoting energy efficiency see UNIDO (2007).
In recent decades, environmental issues have moved to the highest levels of national
policymaking in many countries—either through the creation of a Ministry of Environ-
ment or other institutions and agencies dedicated to sustainable development. Local
governments also manage and provide environmental public goods, such as participat-
ing in decentralised environmental action, as defined by Agenda 21 (WRI 2003).
Local governments have more knowledge of some aspects of the natural envi-
ronment and of the agents involved in the production and use of environmental public
goods. Enabling local communities to manage their natural resources is crucial for deal-
ing with eradication of poverty. Recent initiatives such as the Equator Prize focus on
improving the abilities of local communities to foster sustainable development and to
link achieving economic development goals with environmentally friendly behaviour
(Timmer and Juma 2005).
Some public goods (water supply and utilities) are increasingly being provided
by private entities, mainly due to privatization processes (Heal 2001). Privatization can
stimulate cleaner production, as demonstrated by China, Brazil and India. A country’s
choice to use cleaner technologies (see viewpoint 5.3) could lead to cleaner production
systems in other countries, through demonstration effects (Heal 2001).
INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTIONS
Over the last 30 years the international community has been actively involved in design-
ing a supranational institutional network to deal with the international provision of pub-
lic goods (table 5.1). The institutional process started in 1972 with the United Nations
Conference on the Human Environment in Stockholm, the first world environmental
conference that laid the foundations for action at the international level. Since then, in-
ternational agreements have become the most frequently used instruments for interna-
tional regulation of the environment.
Some 300 international treaties have been drawn up, and countries have signed
and ratified about 60% of them. In the 1970s and 1980s, treaties were aimed at specific
problems, such as contamination, species preservation and conservation. In recent dec-
ades, new goals pertain to depletion of ozone layer, climate change, loss of biodiversity
and use of hazardous chemicals. One of the most important new aspects is the empha-
The Montreal Protocol deals with elimination of the use and production of ozone-
depleting substances (ODS), like chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs), halons, hydro-
chlorofluorocarbons (HCFCs), methyl chloroform, methyl bromide and carbon tetra-
chloride, which are used in industry, households and agriculture. These chemicals can
remain in the atmosphere for a very long time. The ozone layer is essential to life on
earth as it absorbs ultra-violet B-radiation from the sun, which at the earth’s surface
causes health hazards to human life (melanoma and non-melanoma skin cancers, more
eye cataracts, weakened immune systems, reduced plant yields) and damages the
aquatic animal and plant ecosystems.
The Montreal Protocol was signed on September 1987 by 130 parties account-
ing for more than 83% of the consumption of ODS at that time. Reduction goals in-
creased in subsequent revisions, as did the number of signatories, reaching 182 coun-
tries by June 2008. Amendments to the Montreal Protocol were made at conventions
held at London (1990), Copenhagen (1992), Montreal (1997) and Beijing (1999).
In 1990, a Multilateral Fund was set up to help developing countries that are
large consumers and producers of ODS to eliminate these substances in line with their
obligations under the Protocol and at an agreed schedule.25 With the assistance pro-
vided through the Multilateral Fund developing countries that produce CFCs are able
to achieve the Montreal Protocol targets and some of them are expected to meet their
production phase-out commitments at least a year in advance.
Notwithstanding its success, the 2006 assessment report by the World Meteoro-
logical Organization (WMO) indicated that even with full compliance with the Mont-
real Protocol by all parties, the depletion of ozone layer would not be a thing of the
past. It is expected that recovery of the ozone layer will not take place before the middle
of this century, mainly because of the long lifetimes of the ozone depleting substances
Concerns also remain about the full implementation of the Montreal Protocol
by all countries within the stipulated time schedule. This adherence to the phase out
schedule is important due to the precedent bad consequences of ozone layer depletion.
Since 1979, stratospheric ozone has decreased over the entire globe. The ozone layer is
between 3% and 6% below 1980 levels in mid-latitudes. The ozone layer over the Ant-
arctic has steadily weakened since measurements started in the early 1980s.26
The land area under the ozone-depleted atmosphere over Antarctica increased
steadily to more than 20 million sq. km in the early 1990s and has varied between 20
and 29 million sq. km since then. The levels dropped to record lows following the June
1991 volcanic eruption of Mount Pinatubo in the Philippines. In 2000, the area of the
ozone hole reached a record 29 million square kilometres. On 12 September 2000 the
largest and the deepest ozone hole was recorded, but it dissipated early in October.
While no hole has appeared elsewhere, the Arctic spring has seen the ozone layer over
25 Developing countries eligible for financial assistance are those with an annual per capita con-
sumption of ODS of less than 0.3 kg a year, as defined in Article 5 of the Protocol. They are
referred to as Article 5 countries.
26 UNEP/WMO, 2006, Scientific Assessment of Ozone Depletion
[http://pdftohtml.spiritofanime.com/pdf2html.php?url=http://www.unep.org/ozone/pdf/execsu
mm-sap2002.pdf]; Canada’s National Environment Indicator
[www.ec.gc.ca/soerree/English/indicator_series/new_issues.cfm?issue_id=5&tech_id=21].
27 ODP is a number that refers to the amount of ozone depletion caused by a substance. Scien-
tifically the ODP is the ratio of the impact of a chemical compared to the impact of a similar
mass of CFC-11 on the ozone.
28 The HCFC compounds are viewed as temporary replacements for the CFCs as they have
shorter atmospheric lifetimes than CFCs but they still contain chlorine and have the potential to
destroy stratospheric ozone.
The release of various greenhouse gases, notably carbon dioxide (CO2), methane CFCs,
and nitrous oxide (N2O) in the atmosphere contributes to changes in climate and global
29 Report of the Nineteenth Meeting of the Parties to the Montreal Protocol on Substances that
Deplete the Ozone Layer, UNEP/OzL.Pro.19/7, 21 September 2007,
[http://ozone.unep.org/Meeting_Documents/mop/index.shtml].
30 Velders, G.J.M., S.O. Andersen, J.S. Daniel, D.W. Fahey, M. McFarland, The importance
of the Montreal Protocol in protecting climate, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., 104, doi:
10.1073/pnas.0610328104, 2007.
31 There is also an important delay between ozone depletion and for development of skin cancer. The
maximum increase in skin cancer from ozone depletion is expected in 20-40 years.
32 The Kyoto Protocol also addresses hydrofluorocarbons (HFC), perfluorocarbons and sul-
phur hexafluoride.
[http://unfccc.int/resource/cd_roms/na1/ghg_inventories/english/8_glossary/Glossary.htm].
33 Van Vuuren et al (2006) estimate that currently non-carbon dioxide greenhouse gases
(methane, nitrous oxide, perfluorocarbons, hydrofluorocarbons and sulphur hexafluoride) con-
tribute to about a quarter of the global greenhouse gas emissions.
34 These figures come from Baumert and Pershing 2004. The estimates of land-use related
carbon fluxes, however, are very uncertain.
35 In 2002, of all developed countries only Luxembourg emitted more CO2 per capita than the
United States.
36 The average emissions on the world level were 3.93 metric tons per capita in 2002 (World
Bank 2006).
Table 5.2. Carbon dioxide emissions of countries with emissions higher than
1% of world emissions in 2004 (ranked by percent of world total)
Carbon Di- Percent-
oxide Emis- Carbon Diox- age
sions (CO2); ide Emissions Change Share in CO2
Thousand (CO2); Thou- from Rank World Emissions
Country or Area Metric Tons sand Metric 1990 - In Total (%) Per Capita
Name 1990 Tons 2004 2004 2004 2004 Average
United States 4,821,190 6,049,440 25.48 1 22.20 20.06
China 2,400,350 5,010,170 108.73 2 18.39 2.43
Russian Federa-
tion n.a. 1,524,990 -23.19 3 5.60 9.71
India 682,137 1,342,960 96.88 4 4.93 0.89
Japan 1,071,360 1,257,960 17.42 5 4.62 8.89
Germany 981,038 808,767 -17.56 6 2.97 9.94
Canada 416,086 639,403 53.67 7 2.35 17.64
United Kingdom 579,709 587,261 1.30 8 2.16 9.69
Korea, Republic
of 241,315 465,643 92.96 9 1.71 8.36
Italy 389,960 449,948 15.38 10 1.65 7.50
Mexico 413,512 438,021 5.93 11 1.61 3.63
South Africa 332,040 437,032 31.62 12 1.60 8.46
Iran (Islamic Re-
public of) 218,393 433,571 98.53 13 1.59 4.70
Indonesia 213,964 378,250 76.78 14 1.39 1.16
France 364,036 373,693 2.65 15 1.37 6.43
Brazil 209,671 331,795 58.25 16 1.22 1.77
Spain 212,274 330,497 55.69 17 1.21 7.16
Ukraine 330,039 -45.02 18 1.21 6.48
Australia 278,645 326,757 17.27 19 1.20 17.16
Saudi Arabia 254,949 308,393 20.96 20 1.13 12.77
Poland 347,776 307,238 -11.66 21 1.13 8.06
na is not available.
Source: UNIDO calculations based on CDIAC data; United Nations Common Database, United Nations
Statistics Division, 2006.
37 Based primarily on the work by Bodansky 2004 and Aldy et al. 2003.
38 This paragraph draws primarily on Aldy et al. 2003.
Besides Kyoto Protocol alternative policy instruments, such as carbon taxes, quotas and
property rights are also proposed for correcting the underprovision of this public good.
Carbon tax is the imposition of additional cost on each tonne of emissions. Those who
have to pay higher prices would seek alternatives. Thus, carbon taxes would provide
incentives for the reduction of emissions and also revenues for national governments.
At the international level, these revenues could be used for achieving development ob-
jectives, and a fair distribution would be guaranteed because the wealthiest countries
would pay most of the tax (Sandmo 2004).
Quotas involve some form of allocation, but would be unlikely to have the same
distributional effect (Cline 2004a). Quota allocations based on population, rather than
total energy use, would distribute quota rents to large economies with low income per
capita (for example, China and India), whereas the carbon tax approach would distrib-
ute the quota equivalents on a basis of economic strength and hence the ability to pay
the tax. An additional difficulty concerns the degree of uncertainty over the response of
carbon-based energy supply and price demand. The carbon market is a policy-driven
market. Decisions concerning framework conditions and operating guidelines, as well
as issues like National Allocation Plans, linking access to finance to clean development
mechanisms (CDM) and joint implementation (JI) and the future status of the Kyoto
Protocol, will all affect price fluctuation and market developments. Nevertheless, poli-
cies designed to prevent global warming—whether tax-based or through quotas—are
long-term strategies and should therefore be subject to periodic revisions.
Finally, an approach based on property rights has led to the creation of the
emission trading system, which could be adapted and extended into a worldwide mar-
ket for trading CO2 emission rights. The emission trading system includes two types of
policy frameworks, namely “cap and trade” and the offsets (or credit) trading system
allowing for trade in allowances and in credits. These frameworks can exist at interna-
tional, national and sub-national (regional) levels (Ward 2005).
Under the cap and trade framework, once the overall quantitative limit (a cap)
on the aggregate emissions for a group of emitters is determined over a period of time—
usually reached through negotiation—then the cap is divided into tradable emission
units (or allowances) among the emitters in the group, thus setting emission targets for
the emitter. If one emitter has emitted less than allowed and the other more than al-
lowed then the first emitter can trade its surpluses with the second. Efficiency is served
because those that value carbon emissions more will purchase emission rights from
those that value them less. In the process, net welfare is maximized. Each emitter will
be better off, and the objective is reached at lower costs.
The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS), a multi-nation, industry-based
cap and trade programme involving some 11,500 EU installations, started on 1 January 2005
and dominates the international carbon market. EU ETS covers some 12,000 installations,
mostly utility combustion plants, oil refineries, iron and steel plants, energy intensive industry,
such as cement, glass, lime, brick and ceramics production facilities, and the pulp and paper
industries. For these industries, emission trading has become a means of managing the fi-
nancial risks and opportunities in complying with greenhouse gas emission obligations. Com-
panies participating in the scheme can use credits obtained through JI and CDM projects. The
EU ETS not only provides the conditions for the cost-effective reduction of the CO2 emissions,
but also the incentives for business and industry to invest in countries covered by the JI and
the CDM mechanisms, such as Russia, Ukraine or Kazakhstan. This in turn leads to the
transfer of the new environmentally sound low emissions technologies and contributes to
achieving the national objective of sustainable industrial development in these countries.
The emission trading within the EU ETS and eventually the global trading (as envisaged in
the Kyoto Protocol) is a new issue for business and industry. Participation in emissions trad-
ing requires development of new skills and expertise at the company-level. UNIDO global fo-
rum activities focus on enhancing the understanding and operations of emissions trading and
its linkages with the project-based mechanisms of CDM and JI. It provides for expert discus-
sion and knowledge sharing among the participating countries that recently joined the EU and
some countries with economies in transition that are likely to become hosts of JI and CDM
projects.
The Kyoto Protocol includes both frameworks at the international level. Its Ar-
ticle 17 is an example of cap and trade framework. Under the Kyoto Protocol’s emis-
sions trading scheme, Annex I Parties,39 which have legally binding targets under the
protocol, can buy allowances (certified absence of carbon emissions) from Annex I
countries that have not reached their emission limits if they do not meet their reduction
commitments. JI and CDM further allow these countries to earn credits by investing in
Although ozone layer depletion and climate change are both global pure public
bads, global collective action to reduce them has met with drastically different success to
date.
Collective action to curb ozone depletion (Montreal Protocol) and efforts to re-
duce global warming (Kyoto Protocol) are examples of pure public goods, sharing the
same properties of publicness, that of the summation aggregation technology—the level
of their overall provision is a function of the cumulative contributions by individual con-
tributors. Yet their effects were not equally successful. According to Sandler (2004b),
The availability of Cooperative gains were achieved because the Governments were less informed of the cost-benefit of
information on the leading country governments, especially the climate change and of trying to mitigate it. Predictions
costs and benefits of United States, were more informed about the based on modelling exercises of what is going to
the specific cost-benefit analyses of reducing ozone-depleting happen to climate in the next 100 years are tricky. The
corrective action substances. The dominant strategy for the complexity of predications arises from many reinforcing
leading player, the United States, was to curb and counteracting factors at play, and various
CFCs based on the calculations. Other developed uncertainties are involved in this analysis. According to
countries followed suit. recent estimates, the economic costs of climate
change account for –3% of average global outputs
(Nordhaus 2006). The estimation of the costs of
mitigation in terms of global output ranges from 0.2%
to 1 % of GDP a year. (The Economist 2006). Most
calculations in the economics of climate change do not
take into account the possibility of eventual extreme
risks of catastrophic climate change and what happens
if those risks materialize. Such an approach, followed
in defence and financial stability, should be considered
as well.
Leadership The strong commitment and leadership of key Absence of leadership from key polluters. The world’s
industrial countries, particularly the United States, largest emitter of greenhouse gases, the United
were essential, as those countries were the States, is signatory to the Protocol but has not ratified
highest consumers of the most important ozone- it, making its requirements non-binding. Other major
depleting substances, CFCs. polluters, such as China and India, have ratified the
Treaty but are not obliged to reduce emissions under
the specifications of the current agreement, despite
being large greenhouse gas emitters.
How many countries Less uncertainty about the impacts on individual Costs of climate change are expected to be higher in
and activities would countries: all countries could suffer from ozone some regions than in others (for example, higher in
be affected by depletion. India than in Brazil), and the impact assessments of
underprovision? climate change on economic and social life and their
distribution, both temporal and geographical, have not
yet produced convincing conclusions.
Concentration of Concentration of interest and little political Significant uncertainties about global warming processes
interest and political pressure to oppose the treaty and its and their consequences keeping countries from making
pressure to oppose amendments. commitment. Mitigating climate change assumes
the agreement spending real money today in exchange for uncertain
benefits in the far future.
137
Table 5.4. Factors influencing the success of the environmental regime (continued)
138
Number of The impact of outcomes differs based on geographic Controlling greenhouse gases involves more players, mak-
participants suffering location. Countries at the higher latitudes are more ing the process of international cooperation more compli-
from underprovision at risk from ozone holes. cated in this area.
and number of
Mainly requires involvement of manufacturing Efforts may affect different industries in almost every coun-
participants
industries, especially chemical industries. try. Achieving reductions relates not only to manufacturing
contributing to the
underprovision but also to agricultural activities.
Larger contributors are nations with large rain forests (Bra-
zil and Indonesia) and agricultural countries with methane
and nitrous oxide emissions (China, India and the United
States).
High population growth in some countries also puts pres-
sure on the ability to curb greenhouse gas emissions
through increasing demand for food, shelter and energy.
Greenhouse gas emissions are wide-ranging and
changes require the involvement of millions of people,
requiring national government policy to influence
domestic behaviour.
Treaty flexibility, High flexibility and norms of good behaviour estab- Complicated collaborative processes.
norms, standards lished. The treaty mandates could be easily changed Special status given to developing countries, especially to
and enforcement when new circumstance appear (new substitutes, key emitters, will keep the industrial polluters from ratify-
mechanisms new information, or treaty–mandated reductions are ing the Kyoto Protocol.
exceeded).
Some cutbacks will have to be mandated to all countries,
The treaty framework united environmental, political with some allowed differentiation over time.
and commercial interests.
A treaty instrument for global warming needs to be de-
Special status given to developing countries (delayed signed that accounts for its unique aspects.
compliance) as minor producers of CFCs was feasi-
ble and sufficient to concentrate collective action on
major producers.
Early ratifiers persuaded others to sign the treaty
Intertemporal/ The reduction of CFCs under the Montreal Protocol The benefits from actions taken today will come in the dis-
generational will result in clear benefits for current generations as tant future, while the political and economic costs are
well. borne by the current generation. Climate change is not
expected to do much damage within next 50 years, so at
a normal discount rate mitigating climate change today
does not seem worthwhile. The effects of reducing green-
house gas emissions require a much longer time span to
take hold. Cutting emission gradually is a much cheaper
than doing it quickly.
The wide distribution of benefits across countries amplifies
the free rider problem.
Source: Sandler (2004b: 215–18; 225; 232–34; 257–59; 269); Braungart et al. 2005; Cooper 2005; Rock 2006, The Economist 2006; Memedovic, 2006;
Nordhause 2005.
The undersupply of environmental public goods has become a major issue on the in-
ternational agenda. Finding appropriate mechanisms to correct this deficiency is crucial,
both for mitigating environmental degradation and for supporting economic develop-
ment.
Although many other agents may contribute to the provision of environmental
public goods, the participation of national governments remains vital. Countries have
different abilities in assuming the commitments to sustainable development. In addi-
tion, actions by national governments may be insufficient, due to spillover effects that
reach beyond national borders. In this context, international collaboration gains special
relevance. Several suggestions for the international debate follow:
• Considering complementarities. Most environmental impacts from human activities
are intergenerational in character, with direct consequences for the management of
environmental public goods. Global problems such as depletion of the ozone layer
and climate change have consequences for both present-day societies and future
generations. Each of the mechanisms highlighted in this chapter—regulating, coop-
eration, establishing rights of exchange—represents measures for promoting action
on the international level. Therefore, their implementation may as well be comple-
mentary.
• Avoiding earlier mistakes. Developing countries, especially those at low incomes,
have fewer financial options and are more vulnerable to environmental problems.
Many of these countries also depend heavily on natural resources, making the con-
ditions of their environment crucial to their progress. Sustainable development re-
quires averting repetition of the polluting practices during the industrialisation of
developed countries. Governments should thus take notice of the ecological conse-
quences of their industrialisation efforts, and the international community should
provide strong incentives for developing countries to leapfrog the historical errors of
developed countries.
• Accommodating different needs. While greater international coordination could
help prevent opportunistic free rider behaviour, it is also essential that international
differences be considered from a principle of common but differentiated responsi-
bilities. Developing countries have specific concerns and priorities for the environ-
ment, especially in the realm of sustainable development. It is therefore important
that the agenda for international environmental public goods reflect primary con-
cerns of different countries and population groups in a balanced manner.
• Improving the coordination of global and regional efforts. The success of some in-
ternational agreements suggests the need to reinforce international treaties and con-
vince countries of making further commitments. At the same time, greater decen-
tralisation in the provision of environmental public goods should be considered.
Governments could support the development of capabilities in local entities with
closer ties and greater knowledge about specific aspects of the environment. It is
also important to strengthen information sharing and to foster an integrated ap-
proach for environmental problem-solving across disciplines and institutions.
• Moving to environmentally friendly production. Technological improvements can
promote economic dynamism and development and simultaneously lead to more
environmentally friendly production processes. The application of clean and effi-
T
raditionally, foreign assistance has provided private goods and social overhead
capital to recipient countries not only to reduce abject poverty but also to pro-
vide the necessary preconditions for sustained economic development. Social
overhead capital—schools, bridges, highways, law enforcement, communication systems,
waterways, irrigation systems, courts—often consists of national public goods for resi-
dents. This social overhead capital is necessary for markets to function; for example,
law enforcement is required to protect property rights, while courts are needed to adju-
dicate property right disagreements.
In giving foreign assistance, donor countries have been motivated by a combina-
tion of altruism and self-interest. Altruistic gifts are based on a desire to improve the
well-being of those less fortunate even when it means giving up some of the donor
country’s own savings or consumption. In contrast, assistance is founded on self-interest
if the donor stands to gain directly or indirectly from its actions. This self-interest may
manifest itself in aid that results in stronger allies, military bases, or better trading part-
ners, which was true for the Marshall Plan following World War II. The practice of
conditionality, whereby aid is tied to recipients abiding by certain stipulations—
introducing certain policy reforms or purchasing technical assistance from the donor
country, for example—is another instance of assistance being driven in part by the do-
nor’s interests. In recent years the practice of conditionality has lost support because it
may weaken recipient countries’ sense of ownership of their development plans. Such
practices may also inhibit recipients from developing their own expertise while paying
too much for donor-supplied services or inhibit development by imposing practices on
a recipient that are foreign to its culture or way of doing business.
Interest has been growing in the provision of foreign aid in the form of national and in-
ternational public goods. International public goods include goods whose benefits are
non-rival and non-excludable to two or more countries. For example, assisting a devel-
oping country to implement sounder financial practices reduces the likelihood that fi-
nancial crises will arise in that country and spread to other countries or hurt foreign in-
vestors with portfolio or foreign direct investments in the country. Similarly, assisting a
country to switch from chlorofluorocarbons to more ozone-benign substances benefits
all countries by limiting ozone-shield depletion. In fact, as these examples show, donor-
provided international public goods generate benefits that may assist the donor country
as well, thereby providing additional incentives to support aid. For aid-funded interna-
tional public goods, donor self-interest derives from the nature of the public good sup-
plied and not from explicit stipulations on recipient behaviour. Such benefit spillovers
may make this form of aid an easy sell to the donor country’s constituency.
Recent studies have documented an increase in foreign aid support of national
and international public goods. The World Bank (2001a: 110–13) estimated that $5
billion is directly spent annually on aid-assisted international public goods and another
This section highlights five main messages of the Report and prepares the way for a dis-
cussion of policy recommendations.
International public goods come in a variety of forms because they differ in their three
basic properties: non-rivalry of benefits, non-excludability of benefit recipients and the
technology of aggregation. The prognosis for successful collective action critically hinges
on these three properties. Some combinations of these properties imply that the goods
will be provided efficiently, with little need for intervention or explicit policy. For ex-
ample, weakest link public goods will be provided optimally with no outside guidance
when benefiting countries possess similar tastes and resource endowments (Sandler
2004b: 61–68).
When, however, both developing and developed countries are involved, devel-
oping countries will have fewer endowments and will be unable to afford the level of
provision for the weakest link public good considered adequate by developed countries.
This applies to actions to monitor and contain an infectious disease outbreak, for ex-
ample. Because the least action fixes the effective supply of a weakest link public good,
the rich nations then have a motive to shore up the weakest link suppliers through in-
kind or income transfers. The issue becomes how the developed countries confront the
free rider problem of wanting other rich countries to take the lead in shoring up the
weakest links. Multilateral organizations can coordinate these efforts as the World
It is primarily the properties of international public goods that dictate the corrections
required. Alternative property rights assignments or sharing rules—whether the catch in
a fishery is distributed among exploiters by effort or output—may address some open-
access commons concerns (Cornes and Sandler 1996: 283–90). In other cases taxes or
quotas are appropriate. The properties of international public goods also point to the
most appropriate institutional arrangement. For goods with readily monitored and ex-
cludable benefits, club arrangements can be used, so that countries can join private col-
lectives to obtain the public good, financed from congestion-internalizing tolls. For the
good to be efficiently financed through a toll arrangement, use of the good must give
rise to crowding or non-zero marginal cost. The arrangement cannot work efficiently if
the marginal cost from use is zero, because then the toll is zero. Clubs present a di-
lemma because developing countries may not be able to afford the payment and so
cannot gain access to essential development activities—for example, access to INTEL-
SAT and the satellite-based communication network. The solution is not to resort to
less efficient allocation mechanisms but to provide aid to fund developing countries’
membership.
For other international public goods the institutional decision may involve pay-
ment arrangements for benefit recipients. Thus, cost sharing among participants can
circumvent the free-riding problem, as has been used since 1974 to underwrite peace-
keeping missions by the United Nations. This organization also uses cost sharing to
support its operations through membership fees. The World Bank and the Interna-
tional Monetary Fund (IMF) give large stakeholders more voting privileges to increase
donor-specific benefits and provide private incentives to be generous to the many de-
velopment functions that these institutions supply. International organizations that cre-
This message concerns the four key international public goods highlighted in chapters
2–5. Each presents challenges and potential remedies to promote development.
Financial stability. Financial stability generally involves weakest link or weaker link in-
ternational public goods, with poor financial practices in developing countries hurting
these countries by turning away capital inflows that offer increased employment, tech-
nology transfers, aggregate demand and savings. Poor financial practices also create
negative spillovers for neighbouring and investing countries stemming from financial
losses. Neighbouring countries can also suffer by being associated—perhaps unfairly,
owing to propinquity—with nearby financial crises that lead to bank runs, with some
banks becoming insolvent owing to insufficient reserves.
Such financial governance failure can be corrected through best practices such
as those incorporated in the Basel Capital Accord, which was first adopted by the
Group of 10 (G-10) countries (Sandler 2004b: 9). Once developing countries adopted
the accord, they had little choice but to abide by it because to do otherwise would signal
risks to would-be investors. The IMF monitors adherence and supplies stop-gap liquid-
ity to developing countries to forestall crises. Thus there are clever ways to foster finan-
cial stability in developing countries that require little explicit intervention. The weakest
link nature of this international public good provides the right incentives for developed
countries to define better operating procedures and for developing countries to em-
brace them.
International trade regime. International trade regimes yield joint products with purely
public good outputs (more unrestricted commerce) and country-specific outputs (most
favoured nation status). The public goods outputs offer far-reaching gains, while the
country-specific outputs motivate countries to be part of the regime. The real issue is
how to achieve global free trade. As an interim measure regional trade blocs are likely
This section investigates several policy issues and proposals regarding international pub-
lic goods for development. These goods are associated with a host of policy concerns,
many of which have already been addressed in the Report. Some new ones are also
raised.
Given differing spillover ranges for international public goods, a crucial question con-
cerns the jurisdictional level at which these goods should be provided. The principle of
subsidiarity supports a match between the decision-making jurisdiction and the spillover
range of the public good. Thus, a national public good should be provided by a national
government, a regional public good should be supplied by a regional organization, and
an international public good should be supported by an international institution. By
matching the decision-making jurisdiction and the good’s economic interests, subsidiar-
ity seeks to foster allocative efficiency, whereby those affected by the public good cover
the marginal cost of its provision. When the coordinating jurisdiction extends beyond
the spillover domain, it is anticipated that some agents who do not benefit will be sub-
ject to fees or other financial burdens, thus resulting in oversupply. When the coordi-
nating jurisdiction is a subregion of the good’s spillover domain, then it is anticipated
that decision-makers will fail to adjust for benefits received by those beyond the jurisdic-
tional domain, so the public good is undersupplied.
Another argument in favour of subsidiarity is to curb transaction costs by limit-
ing participants to those with a stake in the associated activity. By emphasizing the es-
sential decision-makers, subsidiarity fosters repeated interactions and thus promotes
cooperation even in perverse situations where incentives are not usually aligned. Sub-
The empirical analysis of te Velde, Morrissey and Hewitt (2002) establishes that the
bulk of foreign assistance for public goods funds national public goods. This support
makes sense because these goods are necessary for development and are a prerequisite
for taking advantage of international public goods.
In recent papers Sandler (2005) and Sandler and Arce (2007) argue that re-
gional public goods for development are relatively neglected. Their argument is based
on a number of considerations. First, in contrast to international public goods, regional
public goods are unlikely to yield benefit spillovers to donor countries, thus limiting
their funding. Second, international institutions are better funded than their regional
counterparts, which is due to a culture of contributing to international bodies. Thus,
these bodies are well equipped to finance international public goods. Third, developing
There are some institutional design principles to highlight. When exclusion can be
practised and the international public good displays crowding, clubs are a low transac-
tion cost means for financing such a good. Even some regional club goods—such as
tunnels, bridges and waterways—can be privately provided by clubs. Foreign aid should
support access to communication, transportation and other clubs for developing coun-
tries so that they have the same advantages as rich countries.
Another design principle is to exploit novel forms of organizations so as to offer
the right incentives to member nations. When, for example, helping to finance regional
public goods, regional development banks should rely more on grants than on loans. A
country has little incentive to take on debt if the loan funds a regional public good with
spillovers to other countries not saddled with the debt. Thus, the division between loans
and grants must be geared to the mix of country-specific and regionwide benefits.
Institution engineering that augments country-specific joint products provides
incentives for countries to fund international public activities. Recipient-specific joint
products provide a sense of ownership, while donor-specific joint products motivate
generosity. Recent calls to take away quota-based voting in the IMF would eliminate a
motivating donor-specific benefit. Public-private partnerships offer an institutional form
that takes advantage of diverse participants’ comparative advantage. As such, partner-
ships economize on transaction costs while maximizing output. Institutions for funding
international public goods must also limit overlap of functions. Currently, international
institutions appear to be pursuing some of the same functions—the United Nations and
some of its specialized agencies, the World Bank and others have focused on promot-
ing a sustainable environment.
SECTOR CHOICE
In the late 1980s, following publication of the Brundtland Report (Brundtland 1987),
foreign aid to the environmental sector increased greatly and accounted for the largest
share of foreign assistance until the mid-1990s (Mascarenhas and Sandler 2005: 1102).
After the East Asian financial crisis of 1997 foreign assistance was redirected to govern-
ance and other capacity-building activities. During the late 1990s the health and knowl-
edge sectors also attracted more foreign assistance (Mascarenhas and Sandler 2005:
1101–03).
As best practices emerge, governance will correct itself in developing countries
through self-enforcing incentives, provided that these countries possess the requisite
capacity. As indicated earlier, if developing countries are to attract capital they have little
Anand (2004), te Velde, Morrissey and Hewitt (2002) and others raise the issue that
greater assistance given to international public goods will mean less support for tradi-
tional forms of aid if foreign assistance amounts do not increase. Some international
public goods have donor-specific benefits associated with them, providing an incentive
for rich countries to favour goods whose benefit spillovers further their own interests.
When combined with aid fatigue, this focus can have dire consequences for the well-
being of developing countries.
The irony is that crowding out traditional assistance creates negative externalities
for rich countries—for example, an unhealthy population serves as the perfect host for
infectious diseases. In addition, poverty inhibits recipient countries from providing the
international public goods sought after by rich countries. Multilateral organizations need
to build awareness in donor countries that support for international public goods
should not be in lieu of standard development support. Also, these organizations must
forge links with the new participants since, as already mentioned, their assistance may
have no crowding-out implications because their money is not coming from the public
sector of donor countries.
CONCLUDING REMARKS
International public goods for development will grow in importance over the coming
decades as globalization intensifies. This Report has shown that these goods come in
many varieties and affect all sectors of developing countries. Corrective policies hinge
on the goods’ properties. There is no single prescription; rather, different kinds of in-
ternational public goods require different kinds of policies and institutional arrange-
ments. The Report addresses the nature of these policies and institutions.
156 REFERENCES
Baldwin, R. E. 2004. “Key Challenges Facing the WTO.” In Mike Moore, ed., Doha
and Beyond: The Future of the Multilalteral Trading System. Cambridge, U.K.:
Cambridge University Press.
Barber, J. 1993. “Production, Consumption and World Summit for Sustainable Devel-
opment.” In L. Hens and B. Nath, eds., Environment, Development and Sus-
tainability. Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Barrett, S. 1996. “Fairness, Stewardship and Sustainable Development.” Ecological
Economics 19 (1): 11–17.
———. 2001. “Montreal contra Kyoto: la cooperación internacional y el medio ambiente
mundial.” In I. Kaul, I. Grunberg and M. A. Stern, eds., Bienes públicos mun-
diales: La cooperación internacional en el siglo XXI [Global Public Goods: In-
ternational Cooperation in the 21st Century]. Mexico City: Mexico: Oxford
University Press.
Barton, J. 2004. “Follow up Study on Knowledge Management.” International Task
Force on Global Public Goods, Stockholm.
Baumert, K., and J. Pershing. 2004. Climate Data: Insights and Observations. Prepared
for the Pew Centre on Global Climate Change, Arlington, Va.
Bell, M., and K. Pavitt. 1997. “Technological Accumulation and Industrial Growth:
Contrasts between Developed and Developing Countries.” In D. Archibugi and
J. Michie, eds., Technology, Globalisation and Economic Performance. Cam-
bridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Bergstrom, T. C., and R. P. Goodman. 1973. “Private Demand for Public Goods.”
American Economic Review 63: 280–96.
Bergstrom, T. C., L. Blume and H. Varian. 1986. “On the Private Provision of Public
Goods.” Journal of Public Economics 29 (1): 25–49.
Berkhout, P., H. G. Muskens, C. Jos and J. W. Velthuijsen. 2000. “Defining the Re-
bound Effect.” Energy Policy 28 (6–7): 425–32.
Berthélemy, J-C. 2005. “Sub-Saharan Africa and International Public Goods: The
Weakest Link or a De-linked Region?” Background paper prepared for the
UNIDO Project on Global Public Good for Economic Development. United
Nations Industrial Development Organization, Vienna.
Bertrand, M. 1985. “Some Reflections on the Reform of the United Nations.”
JIU/REP/95/9. United Nations, Joint Inspection Unit, Geneva.
Bhagwati, Jagdish. 1995. “Trade Liberalization and ‘Fair Trade’ Demands: Addressing
the Environmental and Labor Standards Issues.” World Economy 18 (6): 745-
59.
———. 1997. The Feuds over Free Trade. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Stud-
ies.
Birdsall N., and R. Z. Lawrence. 1999. “Deep Integration and Trade Agreements:
Good for Developing Countries?” In I. Kaul, M. Grunberg and A. Stern, eds.,
Global Public Goods: International Cooperation in the 21st Century. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Blackhurst, R., B. Lyakurwa, and A. Oyejide. 2001. “Options for Improving Africa's
Participation in the WTO.” In B. Hoekman and W. Martin, eds., Developing
Countries and the WTO: A Pro-active Agenda. Oxford: Blackwell.
158 REFERENCES
Caprio, G., and D. Klingebiel. 2002. “Episodes of Systemic and Borderline Banking
Crises.” World Bank Discussion Paper 428. World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Casella, A. 1996. “Free Trade and Evolving Standards.” In J. N. Bhagwati and R. E.
Hudec, eds., Fair Trade and Harmonisation: Prerequisites for Free Trade?
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Cashin, P., and C. Patillo. 2000. “Terms of Trade Shocks in Africa: Are They Short
Lived or Long Lived?” IMF Working Paper 00-72. International Monetary
Fund, Washington, D.C. [www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2000/wp0072.pdf].
Castellacci, F., and D. Archibugi. 2005. “The Technology Clubs in the World Econ-
omy.” Paper presented at the UNU-WIDER conference “The Future of De-
velopment Economics,” 17–18 June, Helsinki.
Cernat, L., S. Laird and A. Turrini. 2002. Back to Basics: Market Access Issues in the
Doha Agenda. Geneva: United Nation Conference on Trade and Develop-
ment.
Cerrex Ltd., UK. 2003. “Study of the Consequences of the Application of Sanitary and
Phytosanitary (SPS) Measures on ACP Countries.” Commissioned by the
Technical Centre for Agricultural and Rural Cooperation.
[http://agritrade.cta.int/CTA_SPS%20Study_EN.pdf].
Chandler, W., R. Schaeffer, Z. Dadi, P. R. Shukla, F. Tudela, O. Davidson and S. Al-
pan-Atamer. 2002. Climate Change Mitigation in Developing Countries: Brazil,
China, India, Mexico, South Africa, and Turkey. Prepared for the Pew Center
on Global Climate Change, Arlington, Va. [www.pewclimate.org/global-
warming-in-depth/all_reports/climate_change_mitigation/index.cfm].
Chang, R., and A. Velasco. 1998. “Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime”.
New York University, C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics, New York.
Charlton, A. H., and J. E. Stiglitz. 2004. “A Development-Friendly Prioritization of
Doha Round Proposals.” Working Paper Series. Columbia University, Initiative
for Policy Dialogue, Task Force on Trade, New York.
Charnovitz, S. 1986. “The Influence of International Labour Standards on the World
Trading Regime: A Historical Review.” International Labour Review 126: 565–
84.
———. 1998. “Linking Topics in Treaties.” University of Pennsylvania Journal of Inter-
national Economic Law 19 (2): 329–45.
Chelsea Green Publishing. 2004. “Limits to Growth.” Press release. White River Junc-
tion, Vt. [www.chelseagreen.com/2004/items/limitspaper/ForTheMedia]. May.
Childers, E., and B. Urquhart. 1994. Renewing the United Nations System. Uppsala,
Sweden: Dag Hammarskjold Foundation.
Clement, N. C., G. del Castillo Vera, J. Gerber, W. A. Kerr, A. J. MacFadyen, S.
Shedd, E. Zepeda and D. Alarcon. 1999. North American Economic Integra-
tion—Theory and Practice. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Press.
Cline, W. R. 2004a. “Climate Change.” In B. Lomborg, ed., Global Crises, Global So-
lutions. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
———. 2004b. Trade Policy and Global Poverty. Washington, D.C.: Institute for Interna-
tional Economics.
160 REFERENCES
Devlin, R., and A. Estevadeordal, A. 2002. “Trade and Cooperation: A Regional Public
Goods Approach.” Paper presented at the PECC Trade Forum on Developing
Patterns of Regional Trading Arrangements in the Asia-Pacific Region: Issues
and Implications, 11–12 November, Vancouver, Canada.
Dimaranan, B., T. Hertel and R. Keeney. 2003. “OECD Domestic Support and the
Developing Countries.” Paper for the UNU-WIDER project on the Impact of
the WTO on Low-Income Countries. Purdue University, Center for Global
Trade Analysis, West Lafayette, Indiana.
Dobson, W., and G. Hufbauer. 2001. World Capital Markets: Challenge to the G-10.
Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
Dollar, D. 1992. “Outward-Oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More
Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976–85.” Economic Development and Cul-
tural Change 40 (3): 523–44.
Drucker, P. F. 2002. The Effective Executive, 4th ed. New York: HarperCollins.
Eatwell, J., and E. Taylor. 2000. Global Finance at Risk: The Case for International
Regulation. New York: The New Press.
Edquist, C., ed. 1997. Systems of Innovation: Technologies, Institutions and Organiza-
tions. London: Pinter Publishers.
Edwards, M. 1999. The Future Positive: International Cooperation in the 21st Century.
London: Earthscan.
Edwards, M., and J. Gaventa, eds. 2001. Global Citizen. Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rien-
ner.
Edwards, S. 1998. “Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know?”
Economic Journal 108 (447): 383–98.
Eichengreen, B. 2004. “Financial Stability.” In B. Lomborg, ed., Global Crises, Global
Solutions. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Eichengreen, B., R. Asuman, and U. Panizza. 2002. “Original Sin: The Pain, the Mys-
tery, and the Road to Redemption.” Paper presented at the seminar “Currency
and Maturity Matchmaking: Redeeming Debt from Original Sin,” 21–22 No-
vember, Washington, D.C.
Eichengreen, B., A. Rose and C. Wyplosz. 1996. “Contagious Currency Crises.”
NBER Working Paper 5081. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
ESCAP (Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific). 2006. “Green
Growth at a Glance: The Way Forward for Asia and the Pacific.” United Na-
tions, Bangkok.
Estevadeordeal, A., B. Frantz and T. R. Nguyen, eds. 2004. Regional Public Goods:
From Theory to Practice. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American Development
Bank.
Esty, D. C. 2002. “The World Trade Organisation's Legitimacy Crisis.” World Trade
Review 1 (1): 7–22.
Evangelista, R. 1999. Knowledge and Investment: The Sources of Innovation in Indus-
try. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
162 REFERENCES
Freeman, C., and F. Louca. 2001. As Times Goes By: From the Industrial Revolution
to the Information Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Friedman, J., and J. Levinsohn. 2001. “The Distributional Impacts of Indonesia’s Fi-
nancial Crisis on Household Welfare: A ‘Rapid Response’ Methodology.”
NBER Working Paper 8564. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Fromuth, Peter J., ed. 1988. A Successor Vision: The United Nations of Tomorrow.
New York: United Nations Association of the United States of America.
Funke, M., and R. Ruhwedel. 2001. “Export Variety and Export Performance: Empiri-
cal Evidence from East Asia.” Journal of Asian Economics 12 (4): 493–505.
Gaisford, J. D., and W.A. Kerr. 2001. Economic Analysis for International Trade Ne-
gotiations. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Garcia-Bercero, I., and S. Amarasinha. 2001. “Moving the Trade and Competition
Debate Forward.” Journal of International Economic Law 4 (3): 481–506.
Garret, G. 1998. Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. New York: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press.
Global Forum for Health Research. 2004. The 10/90 Report on Health Research
2003–2004. Geneva.
Gomory, R. E., and W. Baumol. 2000. Global Trade and Conflicting National Inter-
ests. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Gorman, P. J. 2005. “Blowing Out the Candles on the Copyright Cake.” Pierce Gor-
man LLP. Beverly Hills, Calif.
[www.piercegorman.com/blowing_out_the_candles.html].
Granstrand, O. 1999. The Economics and Management of Intellectual Property. Chel-
tenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Griffith-Jones, S., and R. Gottschalk. 2004. “Cost of Currency Crises and Benefit of
International Financial Reform.” Working Paper. University of Sussex, Institute
of Development Studies, Brighton, UK.
Griffith-Jones, S., and J. A. Ocampo. 2004. “What Progress on International Financial
Reform? Why So Limited?” Prepared for the Expert Group on Development
Issues. Stockholm, Sweden.
Griffith-Jones, S., and S. Spratt. 2001. “The Pro-Cyclical Effects of the New Basel Ac-
cord.” In J. J. Teunissen, ed., New Challenges of Crisis Prevention: Addressing
Economic Imbalances in the North and Boom-Bust Cycles in the South. The
Hague: Forum and Debt and Development.
Grossman, G., and A. Krueger. 1993. “Environmental Impacts of a North American
Free Trade Agreement.” In P. Garber, ed., The Mexico-U.S. Free Trade
Agreement. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
———. 1995. “Economic Growth and the Environment.” Quarterly Journal of Econom-
ics 110: 353–77.
Guillaumont, P. 2002. “Nexos entre la Asistencia Oficial para el Desarrollo y los Bie-
nes Públicos Globales.” In I. Kaul, K. Le Goulven and M. Schnupf, eds., Fi-
nanciando bienes públicos globales: nuevos instrumentos y nuevos desafíos.
Paris: United Nations Development Programme.
164 REFERENCES
Hobday, M. 2003. “Innovation in Asian Industrialisation: A Gerschenkronian Perspec-
tive.” Oxford Development Studies 31 (3): 293–314.
Hoekman, B. 2002. “Strengthening the Global Trade Architecture for Development.”
Policy Research Working Paper 2757. World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Hoekman, B., and P. Holmes. 1999. “Competition Policy, Developing Countries and
the WTO.” World Economy 22 (6): 875-–93.
Hoekman, B., F. Ng and M. Olarreaga. 2000. “Tariff Peaks in the Quad and Develop-
ing Countries’ Exports.” World Bank, Development Research Group, Wash-
ington, D.C.
Hoekman, B., K. E. Maskus, K. Saggi. 2004. “Transfer of Technology to Developing
Countries: Unilateral and Mulilateral Policy Options.” Working Paper
PEC2004-0003. Institute of Behavioral Science, University of Colorado,
Bolder.
Holmes, P., Leonardo Iacovone, Rungroge Kamondetdacha, Lara Newson. 2005. “Ca-
pacity-Building to Meet International Standards as Public Goods.” Background
paper prepared for the UNIDO Project on Global Public Good for Economic
Development. United Nations Industrial Development Organization, Vienna.
Howarth, R. B. 1997. “Sustainability as Opportunity.” Land Economics 73 (4): 569–79
Hufbauer, G.C., B. Kotschwar and J.S. Wilson. 2002. “Trade Policy, Standards, and
Development in Central America.” Washington D.C., World Bank.
[http://www.sice.oas.org/geograph/standards/hufkotw.pdf]. Accessed 6 July
2005.
Hummels, D., and P. J. Klenow. 2002. “The Variety and Quality of a Nation’s Trade.”
NBER Working Paper 8712. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research. [http://papers.nber.org/papers/w8712.pdf].
Humphrey, J., and H. Schmitz. 2000. “Governance and Upgrading: Linking Industrial
Cluster and Global Value Chain Research.” Working Paper 120, Institute of
Development Studies, Sussex.
Humphrey, J., and H. Schmitz. 2002. “Developing Countries Firms in the World
Economy: Governance and Upgrading in Global Value Chains.” Report
61/2002. Institut für Entwicklung und Frieden, Duisburg.
Iammarino, S. 2005. “An Evolutionary Integrated View of Regional Systems of Innova-
tion: Concepts, Measures and Historical Perspectives.” European Planning
Studies 13 (4): 497–519.
IEA (International Energy Agency). 2007. Indicators for Industrial Energy Efficiency
and CO 2 Emissions: A Technology Perspective. Paris.
(www.iea.org/w/bookshop/b.aspx?new=5).
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 1998. Toward a Framework for Financial Stability.
Washington, D.C.
———. 1999. “Report of the Managing Director to the Interim Committee on Progress in
Strengthening the Architecture of the International Financial System.” Washing-
ton, D.C.
———. 2003. World Economic Outlook: April 2003; Growth and Institutions. Washing-
ton, D.C.
———. 2005. International Financial Statistics. Washington, D.C.
166 REFERENCES
tional Labor Organization. Knowledge Network Meeting on Governance for
Better Globalization, 22 November, New York.
Kaul, I., and P. Conceição, eds. 2006. The New Public Finance: Responding to Global
Challenges. New York: Oxford University Press.
Kaul, I., P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven and R. Mendoza, eds. 2003a. “How to Improve
the Provision of Global Public Goods.” In I. Kaul, P. Conceição, K. Le Goul-
ven and R. Mendoza, eds., Providing Global Public Goods: Managing Global-
ization. New York: Oxford University Press.
———. 2003b. Providing Global Public Goods: Managing Globalization. New York: Ox-
ford University Press.
Kaul, I., M. Faust, K. Le Goulven, G. Ryu and M. Schnupf. 2001. “Global Public
Goods: Taking the Concept Forward.” ODS Discussion Paper 17. United Na-
tions Development Programme, Office of Development Studies, New York.
Kaul, I., I. Grunberg and M. Stern, eds. 1999. Global Public Goods: International Co-
operation in the 21st Century. New York: Oxford University Press.
———, eds. 2001a. Bienes públicos mundiales: La cooperación internacional en el siglo
XXI [Global Public Goods: International Cooperation in the 21st Century].
Mexico City, Mexico: Oxford University Press.
———. 2001b. “Definición de bienes públicos mundiales.” In I. Kaul, I. Grunberg and
M. Stern, eds., Bienes públicos mundiales. La cooperación internacional en el
siglo XXI [Global Public Goods: International Cooperation in the 21st
Century]. Mexico City, Mexico: Oxford University Press
Kaul, I., and K. Le Goulven. 2003. “Financing Global Public Goods: A New Frontier
of Public Finance.” In I. Kaul, P. Conceiçao, K. Le Goulven and R. Mendoza,
eds., Providing Global Public Goods: Managing Globalization. New York: Ox-
ford University Press.
Kaul, I., K. Le Goulven and M. Schnupf, eds. 2002. Financiando bienes públicos glo-
bales: Nuevos instrumentos y nuevos desafíos. Paris: United Nations Develop-
ment Programme.
Kaul, I., and R. Mendoza. 2003. “Advancing the Concepts of Public Goods.” In I.
Kaul, P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven and R. Mendoza, eds. Providing Global
Public Goods: Managing Globalization. New York: Oxford University Press.
Keck, A., and P. Low. 2004. “Special and Differential Treatment in the WTO: Why,
When and How?” Staff Working Paper ERSD–2004-03, Economic Research
and Statistics Division, World Trade Organization, Geneva.
Kenen, P. B., J. R. Shafer, N. L. Wicks, and C. Wyplosz. 2004. International Eco-
nomic and Financial Cooperation: New Issues, New Actors, New Responses.
Geneva: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
Keohane, R. O. 1988. “International Institutions: Can Interdependence Work?” For-
eign Policy 110: 82–94.
Keohane, R. O., and J. S. Nye. 2001. “Between Centralisation and Fragmentation: The
Club Model of Multilateral Cooperation and Problems of Democratic Legiti-
macy.” Faculty Research Working Papers Series RWP01-004. Harvard Univer-
sity, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Cambridge, Mass.
168 REFERENCES
Levin, R., A. Klevorick, R. Nelson and S. Winter. 1987. “Appropriating the Returns
from Industrial Research and Development.” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 3: 783–831.
Levinsohn, J., S. Berry and J. Friedman. 1999. “Impacts of the Indonesian Economic
Crisis: Price Changes and the Poor.” NBER Working Paper Series 7194. Cam-
bridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Lundvall, B. A., ed. 1992. National Systems of Innovation. London: Pinter Publishers.
Lundvall, B. A., and B. Johnson. 1994. “The Learning Economy.” Journal of Industry
Studies 1: 23–42.
Magariños, C. A. 2005. Economic Development and UN Reform: A Proposal in the
Context of the Millennium Development Goals. Vienna: United Nations Indus-
trial Development Organization.
Maizels, A. 2000. The Manufactures Terms of Trade of Developing Countries with the
United States. Working Paper 36. Oxford University, Finance and Trade Policy
Centre, Oxford.
Manor, J. 2002. “Democratic Decentralization and the Issue of Inequity.” Paper pre-
pared for the World Resources Institute Conference on Decentralization and
the Environment, 18–22 February, Bellagio, Italy.
Mansfield, E., M. Schwartz and S. Wagner. 1981. “Imitation Costs and Patents: An
Empirical Study.” Economic Journal 91: 907–18.
Manuelyan Atinç, T., and M. Walton. 1998. Social Consequences of the East Asian
Financial Crisis. Washington, D.C.: World Bank
Marshall, T. H. 1998. Ciudadanía y clase social. Madrid: Alianza Editorial.
Martin, L. L. 1999. “The Political Economy of International Cooperation.” In I. Kaul,
I. Grunberg and M. Stern. Global Public Goods: International Cooperation in
the 21st Century. New York: Oxford University Press.
Martínez Nogueira, R. 2004. “Regional Public Goods, Governance and Capacity-
Building.” In A. Estevadeordeal, B. Frantz and T. R. Nguyen, eds., Regional
Public Goods: From Theory to Practice. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American
Development Bank.
Mascarenhas, R., and T. Sandler. 2005. “Donors’ Mechanisms for Financing Interna-
tional and National Public Goods: Loan or Grants?” World Economy 28 (8):
1095-1117.
Maskus, K. E. 2000. “Regulatory Standards in the WTO: Comparing Intellectual
Property Rights with Competition Policy, Environmental Protection and Core
Labor Standards.” Working Paper 00-1. University of Colorado, Boulder Insti-
tute for International Economics, Boulder, Colo.
———. 2004. “Encouraging International Technology Transfer.” UNCTAD/ICTSD Is-
sue Paper 7. Geneva. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development
and the International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development.
Maskus, K., E. Wilson and T. Otsuki. 1999. “Quantifying the Impact of Technical
Barriers to Trade: A Framework for Analysis.” Policy Research Working Paper
2512. World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Mattoo, A. 2001. “Discriminatory Consequences of Non-discriminatory Standards.”
Journal of Economic Integration 16 (1): 78–105.
170 REFERENCES
Mendoza, R. 2002. “Profile 1: International Financial Stability.” In Overseas Develop-
ment Institute, Profiling the Provision Status of Global Public Goods. New
York: United Nations Development Programme.
———. 2003. “The Multilateral Trade Regime: A Global Public Good for All?” In I.
Kaul, P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven and R. Mendoza, eds., Providing Global
Public Goods: Managing Globalization. New York: Oxford University Press.
Mendoza, R., and C. Bahadur. 2002. “Toward Free and Fair Trade: A Global Public
Good Perspective.” Challenge 45 (5): 21–62.
Michalopoulos, C. 2000. “The Role of Special and Differential Treatment for Develop-
ing Countries in GATT and WTO.” Policy Research Working Paper 2388.
World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Mills, A., and S. Shillcutt. 2004. “Communicable Diseases.” In Bjørn Lomborg, ed.,
Global Crises, Global Solutions. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Ministère des Affaires Étrangeres. 2002. “La production de biens publics mondiaux:
Un nouvel impératif pour la politique de coopération internationale de la
France?” Document de Travail. Paris.
Molero, J., and I. Alvarez. 2003. “The Impact of Multinational Enterprises Techno-
logical Strategies on National Systems of Innovation: Regularities and National
Differences.” In J. Cantwell and J. Molero, eds., Multinational Enterprises, In-
novative Strategies and Systems of Innovation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Morrisey, O. D., W. te Velde and A. Hewitt. 2002. “Defining International Public
Goods: Conceptual Issues.” In M. Ferroni and A. Mody, eds., International
Public Goods: Incentives, Measurement and Financing. Norwell, Mass.: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Moses, J. W., and B. Letnes. 2002. “The Economics Cost to International Labour Re-
strictions.” WIDER Conference. 27–28 September, Helsinki.
Mowery, D., and N. Rosenberg. 1979. “The Influence of Market Demand upon Inno-
vation: A Critical Review of Some Recent Empirical Studies.” Research Policy
8: 103–53.
Mundell, R. 2005. “International Money as a Public Good: The Case for a World Cur-
rency.” Background paper prepared for the UNIDO Project on Global Public
Good for Economic Development. United Nations Industrial Development
Organization, Vienna.
Murdoch, J., T. Sandler and K. Sargent. 1997. “A Tale of Two Collectives: Sulphur
versus Nitrogen Oxides Emission Reduction in Europe.” Economica 64 (2):
281–301.
Musgrave, R. A. 1959. The Theory of Public Finance: A Study in Public Economy.
New York: McGraw-Hill.
Musgrave, P. B., and R. A. Musgrave. 1980. Public Finance in Theory and Practice.
London: McGraw-Hill.
Namara, A., and X. Nsabagasani. 2003. “Decentralization and Wildlife Management:
Devolving or Shedding Responsibilities? Bwindi Impenetrable National Park,
Uganda.” Environmental Governance in Africa Working Paper 9. World Re-
sources Institute, Washington, D.C.
172 REFERENCES
Ostry, S. 2000. “WTO: Institutional Design for Better Governance, Efficiency, Equity
and Legitimacy; The Multilateral Trading System at the Millennium.” Harvard
University, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Cambridge, Mass.
———. 2002. “The Uruguay Round North-South Grand Bargain: Implications for Future
Negotiations.” In D. L. M. Kennedy and J. D. Southwick, eds., The Political
Economy of International Trade Law: Essays in Honour of Robert E. Hudec.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Oxfam International. 2002. Rigged Rules and Double Standards: Trade, Globalization
and the Fight against Poverty. Oxford.
Page, S., and M. Davenport. 1994. “World Trade Reform: Do Developing Countries
Gain or Lose?” Special report. Overseas Development Institute, London.
Panagariya, A. 1997. “Preferential Trading and the Myth of Natural Trading Partners.”
Japan and the World Economy 9: 471–89.
———. 1999. “TRIPS and the WTO: An Uneasy Marriage.” University of Maryland,
College Park, Md. [www.bsos.umd.edu/econ/Panagariya/song/tripswto2.pdf].
———. 2005a. “Preferential Trade Areas: An International ‘Public Bad’?” Background
paper prepared for the UNIDO Project on Global Public Good for Economic
Development. United Nations Industrial Development Organization, Vienna.
———. 2005b, “Trade and Labor Standards: A Trade Economist’s View.” Paper pre-
sented at the fourth meeting of the Inter-American Development Bank, Latin
American Faculty of Social Sciences, and Latin American Trade Network La-
bor Standards Discussion Group, 23–23 June, Rio de Janeiro.
Panos Institute. 2001. Food for All: Can Hunger Be Halved? London.
Pantana, P., M. Real and B. Resurreccion. 2001. “Officializing Strategies: Participatory
Processes and Gender in ADB’s Capacity-Building in Thailand’s Water Re-
sources Sector.” In Mekong Regional Environmental Governance: Perspectives
on Opportunities and Challenges. Papers from the Mekong Regional Environ-
mental Governance research and dialogue group. Resources Policy Support Ini-
tiative, Washington, D.C.
Pavitt, K. 1987. “On the Nature of Technology.” Reprinted in K. Pavitt [1999] Tech-
nology, Management and Systems of Innovation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward El-
gar.
Pearce, D. 1976. Environmental Economics. London: Longman.
Pearson, L. 1969. Partners in Development. Commission on International Develop-
ment. London: Pall Mall Press.
Pianta, M. 1995. “Technology and Growth in OECD Countries, 1970–1990.” Cam-
bridge Journal of Economics 19 (1): 175–88.
Pietrobelli, C. 2000. “Technology Transfer for Developing Countries.” In D. Schroeer
and M. Elena, eds., Technology Transfer. London: Ashgate.
Polanyi, M. 1958. Personal Knowledge: Towards a Post-Critical Philosophy. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
———. 1966. The Tacit Dimension. New York: Doubleday.
Population Coalition. 2005. “Limits to Growth: The 30 Year Update.” Redlands, Calif.
[www.popco.org/press/articles/2005-1-meadows.html].
174 REFERENCES
———. 2004. “Industrial Policy for the Twenty –First Century”, Paper prepared for
UNIDO.
———. 2004a. “The New Global Economy and Developing Countries: Making Open-
ness Work.” Policy Essay 24. Overseas Development Council, Washington,
D.C.Roffe, P. 2002. “Preliminary Note on the WTO Working Group on
Trade and Transfer of Technology.” Geneva: United National Conference on
Trade and Development.
———. 2006. “Industrial Development: Stylizied Facts and Policies”, paper prepared for
the UN-DESA publication Industrial Development for 21st Century.
Roffe, Pedro. 2002. “Preliminary note on the WTO Working Group on Trade and
Transfer of Technology.” United Nations Conference on Trade and Develop-
ment, Geneva.
Rogerson, A. 2005. “Aid Harmonisation and Alignment: Bridging the Gaps between
Reality and the Paris Reform Agenda.” Development Policy Review 23 (5):
531–52.
Rogerson, A., A. Hewitt and D. Waldenburg. 2004. “The International Aid System
2005–2010: Forces for and Against Change.” London: Overseas Development
Institute.
Rojas-Suárez, L. 2005. “Domestic Financial Regulations in Developing Countries: Can
They Effectively Limit the Impact of Capital Account Volatility?” Working Pa-
per 59. Center for Global Development, Washington, D.C.
Rosenberg, N. 1982. Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Rubio de Urquía, J. 2005. “Las negociaciones internacionales sobre cambio climático.”
Información Comercial Española 822.
Ruggie, J. G. 1975. “International Responses to Technology: Concepts and Trends.”
International Organization 29 (3): 557–84.
Russet, B. M., and J. D. Sullivan. 1971. “Collective Goods and International Organiza-
tion.” International Organization 25 (4): 845–65.
Rutherford, T. F., and D. G. Tarr. 2002. “Trade Liberalisation, Product Variety and
Growth in a Small Open Economy: A Quantitative Assessment.” Journal of In-
ternational Economics 56: 246–72.
Sachs, J., and A. Warner. 1995. “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integra-
tion.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1. Brookings Institution, Wash-
ington, D.C.
Sagasti, F., and K. Bezanson. 2001. Financing and Providing Global Public Goods: Ex-
pectations and Prospects. Study 2001:2. Stockholm: Sweden, Ministry for For-
eign Affairs.
Saggi, K. 2003. International Technology Transfer: National Policies, International Ne-
gotiations and Multilateral Disciplines. Report for the Commonwealth Secre-
tariat. London: Commonwealth Secretariat.
Samuelson, P. A. 1954. “The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure.” Review of Econom-
ics and Statistics 36: 387–89.
———. 1955. “A Diagrammatic Exposition of a Theory of Public Expenditure.” Review
of Economics and Statistics 37: 350–56.
176 REFERENCES
Sandor, R. L. 2002. “El comercio de emisiones: financiando los bienes públicos am-
bientales al menor costo.” In I. Kaul, K. Le Goulven and M. Schnupf, eds., Fi-
nanciando bienes públicos globales: Nuevos instrumentos y nuevos desafíos.
Paris: United Nations Development Programme.
Sandor, R. L., E. C. Bettelheimand and I. R. Swingland. 2002. “An Overview of a Free-
Market Approach to Climate Change and Conservation.” Philos Transact A
Math Phys Eng Sci 360 (1797): 1607–20.
Scherer, F. M., and D. Ross. 1990. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Per-
formance. Third ed. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Scherer, F. M., and J. Watal. 2001. “Post-TRIPS Options for Access to Patented Medi-
cines in Developing Countries.” Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School
of Government, Cambridge, Mass.
Schiff, M. 1997. “Small is Beautiful: Preferential Trade Agreements and the Impact of
Country Size, Market Share, Trade Policy and Smuggling.” Journal of Eco-
nomic Integration 12 (3): 359–87.
———. 2002. “Regional Integration and Development in Small States.” Policy Research
Working Paper 2797. World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Schmidt, R. 1999. A Feasible Foreign Exchange Transaction Tax. Ottawa: North-South
Institute.
Schmookler, J. 1966. Invention and Economic Growth. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University Press.
Schott, J., and J. Watal. 2000. “Decision-Making in the WTO”. Policy Brief 00-2. Insti-
tute for International Economics, Washington, D.C.
[www.iie.com/publications/pb/pb00-2.htm].
Scott, G. H. 1954. “The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The
Fishery.” Journal of Political Economy 62 (2): 124–42.
Scott, M. F. 1989. A New View of Economic Growth. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Scott, W., and S. Gough. 2003. Sustainable Development and Learning: Framing the
Issues. London and New York: RoutledgeFalmer.
Shafaeddin, M. 1994. “The Impact of Trade Liberalisation on Export and GDP
Growth in Least Developing Countries.” Discussion paper. United Nations
Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva.
———. 2000. “Free Trade or Fair Trade?” UNCTAD Secretariat Working Paper.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva.
[www.unctad.org/en/docs/dp_153.en.pdf].
Shiller, R. J. 2000. Irrational Exuberance. New York: Broadway.
———. 2002. Indexed Units of Account: Theory and Assessment of Historical Experi-
ence. NBER Working Paper 6356. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Shiva, V. 2001. Protect or Plunder? Understanding Intellectual Property Rights. Lon-
don: Zed Books.
Simon, H. A. 1957. Model of Man. New York: Wiley.
178 REFERENCES
Subramanian, A. 1995. “Putting Some Numbers on the TRIPS Pharmaceuticals De-
bate.” International Journal of Technology Management 10 (1/3): 252–69.
Suryahadi, A., S. Sumarto, Y. Suharso and L. Pritchett. 2000. “The Evolution of Pov-
erty in Indonesia, 1996–1999.” World Bank, Country Economics Department,
Washington, D.C.
Sutherland, P. D. 1998a. “Answering Globalization’s Challenges.” ODC Viewpoint.
Overseas Development Council, Washington, D.C.
———. 1998b. “Managing the International Economy in an Age of Globalisation.” The
1998 Per Jacobsson Lecture. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.
[www.imf.org/external/am/1998/perj.htm].
Tandon, Y. 1999. “The WTO: A Rich Man’s Club?” International Centre for Trade
and Sustainable Development, Geneva. [www.ictsd.org/dlogue/1999-02-
10/TANDON.pdf].
Tarullo, D. K. 2000. “Norms and Institutions in Global Competition Policy.” American
Journal of International Law 94 (3): 478–504.
Tenkorang D., and P. Conceição. 2003. “Beyond Communicable Disease Control:
Health in the Age of Globalization.” In I. Kaul, P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven
and R. Mendoza, eds., Providing Global Public Goods: Managing Globaliza-
tion. New York: Oxford University Press.
Te Velde, D. Forthcoming. “Financing International Public Goods.” In D. Njinkeu and
H. Cameron, eds. A Framework to Address Aid for Trade.” London: Overseas
Development Institute.
Te Velde, D. W., and O. Morrissey. 2005. “Supporting Industrial Development: Over-
coming Market Failures and Providing Public Goods.” Combating Marginaliza-
tion and Poverty through Industrial Development. Project 3. United Nations
Industrial Development Organization, Vienna.
Te Velde, D. W., A. Hewitt, and O. Morrissey. 2006. “Aid Financing of International
Public Goods: Recent Developments.” Background paper prepared for the
UNIDO Project on Global Public Good for Economic Development. United
Nations Industrial Development Organization, Vienna.
Te Velde, D. W., O. Morrissey, and A. Hewitt. 2002. ”Allocating Aid to International
Public Goods.” In M. Ferroni and A. Mody, eds., International Public Goods:
Incentives, Measurement and Financing. Norwell, Mass.: Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
The Economist. 2006. “A Survey of Climate Change.” 9 September.
Third World Network. 2001. “The Multilateral Trade System: A Development Per-
spective.” Background paper for the United Nations Development Programme
Project on Trade and Sustainable Human Development, New York.
Thurow, L. 1971. “The Income Distribution as a Public Good.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 85: 327–36.
Timmer, V., and C. Juma. 2005. “Biodiversity Conservation and Poverty Reduction
Come Together in the Tropics: Lessons Learned from the Equator Initiative.”
Environment 47 (4): 26–44.
180 REFERENCES
UNFCCC (United Nations Framework on Climate Change). 2004. The First Ten
Years. Bonn, Germany. [http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/publications/
first_ten_years_en.pdf].
UNIDO (United Nations Industrial Development Organization) 2002a. “Corporate
Social Responsibility: Implications for Small and Medium Enterprises in De-
veloping Countries.” UNIDO and the World Summit on Sustainable Devel-
opment, Vienna.
———. 2002b. Industrial Development Report 2002–2003: Competing through Innova-
tion and Learning. Vienna.
———. 2002c. “Manual on the Development of Cleaner Production Policies—
Approaches and Instruments.” Vienna.
———. 2004. Industrial Development Report 2004. Industrialization, Environment and
the Millennium Development Goals in Sub-Saharan Africa: The New Frontier
in the Fight against Poverty. Vienna.
———. 2005. “Public Goods for Economic Development: Market Efficiency & Integra-
tion, Science & Technology Environment & Energy and Global Financial Stabil-
ity” Issue and Background Paper,” by Olga Memedovic, UNIDO staff Member
UNIDO.
———. 2006. “Montreal Protocol on Ozone Depleting Substances (success story).” Vi-
enna. [www.unido.org/doc/3633].
———. 2007. “Policies for Promoting Industrial Energy Efficiency in Developing Coun-
tries and Transition Economies.” Background paper prepared for the UNIDO
Side Event on Sustainable Industrial Development, Commission for Sustainable
Development (CSD-15), by A. McKane, L. Price, and S. de la Rue du Can,
Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, Berkeley, Calif.
UN Millennium Project. 2005. Investing in Development: A Practical Plan to Achieve
the Millennium Development Goals. London: Earthscan.
Unnevehr, L., ed. 2003. “Food Safety in Food Security and Food Trade.” Washington
D.C., International Food Policy Research Institute.
US Department of Energy. 2004. International Energy Outlook 2004. Energy Informa-
tion Administration, Washington, D.C.
US National Science Foundation. 2002. Science and Engineering Indicators. Washing-
ton, D.C.: National Science Board.
Vela, S. 2005. “Marco teórico de la directiva de comercio de emisiones.” Información
Comercial Española 822.
Velders, G.J.M., S.O. Andersen, J.S. Daniel, D.W. Fahey, M. McFarland, 2007. The
Importance of the Montreal Protocol in Protecting Climate, National Academy
of Sciencies of the USA., 104, doi/10.1073/pnas.0610328104.
Verfaillie, H. A., and R. Birdwell. 2000. Measuring Eco-Efficiency: A Guide To Re-
porting Company Performance. World Business Council for Sustainable De-
velopment, Geneva.
Viotti, E. B. 2002. “National Learning Systems: A New Approach on Technological
Change in Late Industrializing Economies and Evidence from the Cases of Bra-
zil and South Korea.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 69 (7):
653–80.
182 REFERENCES
Zedillo, E. 2001. Report of the High-Level Panel on Financing for Development. New
York: United Nations.
———. 2006. “Can Doha Be Saved?” International Herald Tribune, 13–14 May, p 5.
Zoninsein, J. 1999. “Implications of the Evolving Global Structure for the UN system:
A View from the South.” In M. G. Schechter, ed., Innovation in Multilateral-
ism. New York: United Nations University Press.